Next Article in Journal
Remote Sensing Image Classification Based on Neural Networks Designed Using an Efficient Neural Architecture Search Methodology
Previous Article in Journal
CC-DETR: DETR with Hybrid Context and Multi-Scale Coordinate Convolution for Crowd Counting
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Using Game Theory to Explore the Multinational Supply Chain Production Inventory Models of Various Carbon Emission Policy Combinations

by
Jialiang Pan
1,
Kun-Shan Wu
2,*,
Chih-Te Yang
2,*,
Chi-Jie Lu
3 and
Shin Lu
4
1
School of Business and Management, Jiaxing Nanhu University, Jiaxing 314001, China
2
Department of Business Administration, Tamkang University, New Taipei City 251301, Taiwan
3
Graduate Institute of Business Administration, Fu Jen Catholic University, New Taipei City 24205, Taiwan
4
Department of Biomedical Imaging and Radiological Sciences, National Yang Ming Chiao Tung University, Taipei 11221, Taiwan
*
Authors to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Mathematics 2024, 12(10), 1564; https://doi.org/10.3390/math12101564
Submission received: 20 April 2024 / Revised: 12 May 2024 / Accepted: 14 May 2024 / Published: 17 May 2024
(This article belongs to the Section Engineering Mathematics)

Abstract

:
This study uses Stackelberg game theory, considering different combinations of carbon emission reduction policies and that high-carbon-emission enterprises may face various carbon emission reduction regulations, to explore the production inventory problems in a multinational supply chain system. The purpose is to determine the manufacturer’s optimal production, shipping, carbon reduction investment, and the retailer’s replenishment under the equilibrium for different carbon emission policy combinations. To develop the production inventory models, this study first develops the total profit and carbon emission functions of the supply chain members, respectively, and then obtains the optimal solutions and total profits of the manufacturer and the retailer under different carbon emission policy combinations through the mathematical analysis method. Further, this study used several numerical examples to solve and compare the proposed models. The results of numerical analysis show that regardless of the increase in carbon price or carbon tax, the manufacturer and retailer will adjust their decisions to reduce carbon emissions. Specifically, an increase in the carbon price contributes to an increase in the total profit of manufacturers, while an increase in the carbon tax reduces the total profit of manufacturers. This study also explores a sensitivity analysis on the main parameters and has yielded meaningful management insights. For instance, in cases where low-carbonization strategies are required, the manufacturer or retailer can effectively reduce the carbon emissions resulting from production or purchasing activities, thereby significantly reducing overall carbon emissions. It is believed that the results of this study can provide enterprises/supply chains with reference to their respective production, transportation, carbon reduction investment, and inventory decisions under carbon emission policies, as well as information on partner selection and how to adjust decisions under environmental changes.

1. Introduction

With the rise of Environment, Social, and Governance (ESG) issues and the rise of sustainability awareness, the goal of carbon neutrality has begun to be taken seriously, and various countries have developed their own carbon emission policies. ESG issues have attracted the attention of the government, enterprises, and academia since they appeared in the United Nations report in 2006, and have been widely used as an important indicator to measure the sustainability and social influence of enterprises. In 2015, the United Nations General Assembly further signed the Global Sustainability Development Goals (SDGs), which cover the environmental, economic, and social aspects, and are also the goals of continuous global efforts. In the above issues and sustainable development goals, environmental protection is regarded as one of the critical issues. According to The Global Risks Report 2023 [1], four of the top five risks in the world are related to global warming and extreme climate. All countries agree that carbon dioxide emissions are the main driving factor of global climate change, and its threat is increasing year by year. Greenhouse gas emissions (mainly carbon dioxide) lead to global warming [2], and then cause extreme weather such as heat waves, droughts, forest fires, rainstorms, floods and so on, which not only affect everyone’s life, but also bring serious losses of life and property. Therefore, green thinking such as environmental protection, carbon dioxide emission reduction, and alternative energy is no longer a slogan, and concepts such as green policy, green energy, and green supply chain have emerged one after another. In the supply chain system of the manufacturing industry, carbon emissions from sourcing, production, inventory, transportation, sales, and use of goods are important factors causing extreme climate. Since the Kyoto Protocol was signed by 84 countries in 2005 to mitigate carbon emissions, the governments of member countries have begun to actively promote some measures to limit greenhouse gas emissions [3]. Such developments include the creation of new alternative energy or renewable energy, the formulation of energy conservation and carbon reduction regulations, the advancement of carbon trading markets like the EU Emissions Exchange, the Chicago Climate Exchange, the Tianjin Emissions Exchange, and the implementation of carbon taxes. In 2015, the 21st Conference of the Parties to the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change in Brazil, France, also adopted a historic agreement, which became a new legally binding agreement on greenhouse gas reduction after the Kyoto Protocol. It can be seen that the control of greenhouse gas emissions is a new trend, and this control measure will inevitably affect the operation strategy of enterprises. With the rise of environmental awareness, in the face of multiple pressures from the government, customers, and other stakeholders, enterprises must also try to reduce the environmental and social impacts of their operations by reducing carbon emissions in addition to pursuing profits [4].
When facing the issue of carbon emission reduction, most enterprises focus on reducing carbon emissions through some physical processes, such as replacing equipment or facilities with lower energy efficiency, redesigning product packaging and regulation, or using low-pollution energy [5]. However, some scholars have found that enterprises can significantly reduce carbon emissions without significantly increasing costs through operational management, such as inventory management [6]. Therefore, many issues about carbon emission or carbon footprint management in inventory management have been discussed gradually. At first, some scholars incorporated carbon emission reduction policies, including restrictive carbon emissions, carbon taxes, carbon cap-and-trade, or carbon offsets into the economic order quantity (EOQ) or economic production quantity (EPQ) models, such as [7,8,9,10,11]. Wu et al. [12], Shen et al. [13], Rout et al. [14], Qi et al. [15], and Huang et al. [16] discussed the production inventory model including manufacturers and retailers from the perspective of supply chain integration. Astanti et al. [17] developed a vendor managed inventory model to analyze the correlation between carbon price and total carbon emissions. However, the above research literature assumes that supply chain members face the same carbon emission reduction policy. In practice, supply chain members may face different carbon emission reduction policies, especially considering a transnational supply chain from different countries. Cheng et al. [18] explored the combination of pre-sale and credit transactions, which affects the formulation of the best pricing and inventory model under different carbon tax policies, while Lu et al. [19] explored and compared supply chain production inventory issues for different combinations of carbon emission reduction policies. Shen et al. [20] proposed a supply chain competitive inventory model that considers both carbon trading and carbon tax as a mixed carbon emission reduction policy, which is suitable for industries with high carbon emissions.
In addition, when the managers of enterprises are engaged in decision making (including production, transportation, inventory, etc.), the situations they face are not independent, and may be affected by the choices of other decision-makers, that is, the decision-making situations are interactive. Therefore, how to explore the interaction between members about inventory and investment-related decisions in the supply chain system, to minimize the total inventory-related cost or maximize the total profit of each member, is also a topic worthy of discussion. Academically, many scholars have used the concept of game theory to explore the interactive decision making of inventory between manufacturers and retailers, and established a series of supply chain competitive inventory models. Most of them discuss the optimal decisions of buyers and sellers from the perspective of Stackelberg game theory, that is, considering one member of the supply chain as the leader and the other as the follower [21,22,23,24,25,26,27,28]. However, as far as we know, there is no literature using the concept of game theory to discuss the dependent inventory decision problem of supply chain members under different carbon emission policy combinations or mixed carbon emission policies.
Therefore, from the perspective of game theory, this study explores the production inventory of retailers and manufacturers in the supply chain under different carbon emission reduction policy combinations and mixed carbon emission reduction policies. In this study, the total profit and carbon emission functions of supply chain members are established, respectively. Then, we consider two carbon emission reduction policy combinations of carbon tax and carbon cap-and-trade. (1) The retailer faces carbon tax policy, and the manufacturer faces a mixed policy of carbon cap-and-trade and carbon tax at the same time; (2) the retailer faces a carbon cap-and-trade policy, and the manufacturer faces a mixed policy of carbon cap-and-trade and carbon tax at the same time. Exchange rate issues are also taken into account in the model. The problems to be solved in this study are as follows. First, how does the retailer determine the quantity of replenishment and the length of the cycle, and how does the manufacturer determine the quantity and frequency of delivery in the case that the members of the supply chain system make decisions that affect each other and have different carbon emission policies. Second, the sensitivity analysis of the optimal equilibrium decision, individual profit, and carbon emission quantity of the manufacturer and retailer is carried out by comparing different carbon emission reduction portfolio scenarios. Finally, the influence of the model parameters on the optimal equilibrium decision is discussed. In the aspect of model development, firstly, the profit and carbon emission functions of supply chain members are established. Then, under different carbon emission policy combinations, the Stackelberg game of a single leader and a single follower is considered, and the solution method of finding the optimal equilibrium solution value of the manufacturer and the retailer is developed for two different combination scenarios. Furthermore, this study illustrates the solution procedure through several more reasonable numerical examples and conducts sensitivity analysis on the main model numbers. It is hoped that some meaningful management implications can be obtained to provide a reference for enterprises to make relevant decisions.

2. Literature Review

The literature review of this study is mainly divided into two parts, including the consideration of carbon emission reduction policies and the use of game theory to explore the inventory problem, which are described as follows.

2.1. Inventory Model Considering Carbon Emission Reduction Policies

At the earliest, Hua et al. [7] developed an economic ordering quantity (EOQ) model taking into account the carbon cap-and-trade policy. Arslan and Turkay [8] also modified the traditional EOQ model based on carbon emission policies such as carbon tax, carbon cap-and-trade, and carbon offset. Chen et al. [5] further developed conditions that can reduce carbon emissions by adjusting order quantities. Since then, many scholars have considered various practical issues and explored how to optimize production and inventory strategies in company or supply chain management under various carbon emission reduction policy frameworks. Zhang and Xu [28] further explored the multi-item newsboy model under the carbon cap-and-trade and limited warehouse capacity. Battini et al. [10] incorporated the concept of carbon footprint management, established a Sustainable Economic Order Quantity (S-EOQ) model, and compared it with the traditional EOQ model. He et al. [9] addressed the issues of production lot sizing under cap-and-trade and carbon tax regulations based on the EOQ model. Hovelaque and Bironneau [11] followed Hua et al. [7] and developed a sustainable EOQ model in which demand is dependent on selling price and carbon emissions. Dye and Yang [29] developed a deteriorating inventory model with trade credit under carbon cap-and-trade and carbon offset regulations. Hua et al. [30] also established a sustainable inventory model for deteriorating items and considered the freshness-dependent demand. Recently, Cheng et al. [18] proposed a comprehensive inventory model including price-dependent demand, pre-sale incentives, advance sales, trade credit, and carbon tax policies based on the EOQ model. On the other hand, Ghosh et al. [31] first developed a production inventory model considering carbon cap from the perspective of supply chain integration with uncertain demand. Shen et al. [13] further targeted deteriorating items and established a production inventory model based on carbon tax policy. Under the trend of global carbon reduction initiatives, Mashud et al. [32], Paul et al. [33], Ruidas et al. [34], Pan et al. [35], and Huang et al. [16] tried to propose an EOQ/EPQ model or production inventory model with carbon emission reduction technology investment under various carbon emission reduction policies. Jauhari et al. [36] and Muthusamy et al. [37] further established a production inventory model to explore the impact of carbon taxes, green incentives, and green investments on improving supply chain carbon emissions.
Nevertheless, the above-mentioned production inventory models with carbon emission issues all considered that supply chain members face the same carbon emission reduction regulations. With the development trend of globalization, multi-national supply chains are commonly seen, which implies that the upstream and downstream members of the supply chain may come from different countries, and therefore may face different carbon emission reduction policies. In addition, Shen et al. [20] suggested that the government should adopt a differentiated hybrid carbon policy, especially for industries with high carbon emissions. Therefore, this study not only considers a multinational supply chain inventory management system with different carbon emission policy combinations, but also takes into account the hybrid carbon emission policy that high-carbon emission companies may face.

2.2. Inventory Model Using Game Theory

In order to explore the interaction between supply chain members in inventory-related decisions, Emmons and Gilbert [21] earlier used Stackelberg game theory to develop an inventory model considering a single supplier and single retailer and determined the supplier’s wholesale price and return price as well as the retailer’s order quantity. Following this, Chang et al. [22] discussed the supply chain inventory problem based on the Stackelberg game, where the seller, as a leader, determines the optimal replenishment period and the retailer, as a follower, determines the optimal ordering quantity. Chern et al. [23,24] and Jaggi et al. [25] applied the concepts of Stackelberg and Nash games, respectively, to establish supply chain inventory models with a permissible delay in payments. Wu et al. [12] further considered that demand is dependent on the period of delayed payment, and used the Stackelberg game to explore the interaction between delayed payment and ordering policy of the buyer and vendor. In addition, Lu et al. [26,27] considered carbon emission reduction investment options and used Stackelberg game theory to develop a sustainable production inventory model. Ma et al. [38] also took the carbon tax and government subsidies into consideration and used the Stackelberg game to make joint decisions among the manufacturer and retailer, and further developed the nested genetic algorithm to solve the model. Mahmoodi [39] and Mahdavisharif et al. [40] used Stackelberg game theory to establish a manufacturer–retailer supply chain inventory model for deteriorating items to determine the retail price and replenishment cycle. Xin al. [41] comparatively studied the purchasing strategies, pricing decisions and incentive mechanisms of different replenishment cycles, and derived the optimal decision on demand for green products based on the Stackelberg game. Recently, Choudhury al. [42] extended to a multilayer sustainable production inventory supply chain model with deteriorating items and pollution via Stackelberg game approach.
Although many studies have investigated various manufacturer–retailer supply chain inventory models, there is a research gap in the literature regarding the optimal equilibrium strategy for multinational supply chain members with both carbon emission policy combinations and mixed carbon emission policy. Based on the above, the main contributions of this study are as follows. First, the proposed model extends the production inventory problem to a multinational supply chain system carbon emission reduction investment under various carbon emission reduction policy combinations, thereby filling the research gap in previous literature. Second, this study uses game theory to explore the interaction of production, carbon reduction investments, and replenishment decisions between the manufacturer and retailer. Finally, this study uses numerical examples and sensitivity analysis to obtain some management insights and assist supply chain members in making decisions that can achieve both low-carbonization and maximum profit goals.

3. Notation and Assumptions

In order to set up the schema, we need the following notation, which is described as follows.
D:Demand rate
P:Production rate
A :Retailer’s order cost/time
S :Manufacturer’s setup cost/time
c :Manufacturer’s production cost/unit
v :Manufacturer’s supply price/unit
v :Retailer’s selling price/unit
h b :Retailer’s holding cost/unit/unit time
h v :Manufacturer’s holding cost/unit/unit time
C T :Ratailer’s fixed delivery cost/time
C t :Ratailer’s variable delivery cost/unit
A ^ :Retailer’s carbon emissions generated by ordering activities/time
S ^ :Manufacturer’s carbon emissions generated by setup activities/time
c ^ :Manufacturer’s carbon emissions generated by production activities/unit
v ^ :Retailer’s carbon emissions generated by purchasing activities/unit
h ^ b :Retailer’s carbon emissions generated by holding activities/unit/unit time
h ^ v :Manufacturer’s carbon emissions generated by holding activities/unit/unit time
C ^ T :Retailer’s fixed carbon emissions generated by delievery activies/time
C ^ t :Retailer’s carbon emissions generated by delievery activies/unit
C1:Carbon price in carbon trading market/unit
C2:Carbon tax/unit
ϖ ¯ b :Retailer’s total carbon emissions quota/unit time
ϖ ¯ v :Manufacturer’s total carbon emissions quota/unit time
T b :Retailer’s length of a replenishment cycle, a decision variable
T v :Manufacturer’s length of a production cycle, a decision variable
T s :Manufacturer’s length of production period within a production cycle, is a decision variable
n :Number of times the manufacturer ships items to a retailer in a production cycle, an integer decision variable
q :Amount of items shipped by the manufacturer to the retailer at one time during a production cycle, a decision variabe
Q :Retailer’s ordering quantity, a decision variabe
ξ :Investments to reduce carbon emissions, a decision variable
m ( ξ ) :Proportion of carbon emissions reduction, a function of ξ
Next, the main assumptions of the production inventory models discussed in this study are as follows:
  • A multinational supply chain system consisting of a single retailer and a single manufacturer from different countries is considered in which the retailer and the manufacturer face different carbon emission reduction policies. Further, the manufacturer may face hybrid carbon emission policies at the same time due to the characteristics of its high carbon emission industry.
  • This study explores a Stackelberg game in which the manufacturer is the leader and the retailer is the follower (see, for example, [23,26,38]).
  • The manufacturer’s production rate is finite and greater than the demand rate; otherwise, the supply chain system will always be out of stock.
  • In terms of delivery strategy, assuming the same as Shen et al. [13], the retailer signs a contract with the manufacturer that requires the manufacturer to ship orders to the retailer in installments of a fixed quantity each time, and the cost of shipping is borne by the retailer.
  • The retailer’s carbon emissions are related to the business activities of ordering, holding, transporting, and purchasing goods (please refer to [5,8,11]), while the manufacturer’s carbon emissions are related to operational activities such as material procurement, setup, production, and storage (please refer to [9]).
  • Carbon emissions can be reduced through technological investments shared by the manufacturer and the retailer, with the reduced carbon emission rate being m ( ξ ) , where 0 < m ξ < 1 and m ( ξ ) is an increasing function of the investment in carbon emission technology ξ . Further, the proportions of capital investments by the retailer and manufacturer in technology for reducing carbon emissions are α and 1 α , respectively, where 0 α 1 .
  • When considering carbon tax policy, the retailer or the manufacturer is levied based on their respective carbon emissions. That is, carbon tax is levied in the form of a unit tax which is the same as Cheng et al. [18], Shen et al. [20], Lu et al. [26], and so on.
  • Similar to Wu et al. [12], Shen et al. [13], and Lu et al. [26,27], neither the retailer nor the manufacturer is allowed to be out of stock.

4. Model Formulation and Solution

From the perspective of the Stackelberg game, this study explores the following different carbon emission reduction policies faced by a single manufacturer and a single retailer. (1) The retailer faces a carbon tax policy, while the manufacturer faces a mixed policy of carbon cap-and-trade and carbon tax; (2) retailers face a carbon cap-and-trade policy, while manufacturers face a mixed policy of carbon cap-and-trade and carbon tax, as well as their respective production, inventory, and carbon reduction investment issues. According to the above symbols and assumptions, firstly, the total profit and carbon emission functions of the seller and the manufacturer are established, respectively, which are described as follows.

4.1. Retailer’s Total Profit and Carbon Emissions

Based on the above notation and assumptions, the retailer’s total profit is equal to sales revenue minus ordering cost, purchase cost, holding cost, shipping cost, and investment in carbon emissions. Since the length of a replenishment cycle is T b , the retailer’s total profit per unit of time (denoted by T P b ( T b ,   ξ ) ) can be obtained as follows:
T P b ( T b ,   ξ ) = S a l e s   r e v e n u e O r d e r i n g   c o s t P u r c h a s e   c o s t H o l d i n g   c o s t S h i p p i n g   c o s t I n v e s t m e n t   i n   c a r b o n   e m i s s i o n s / T b   = p D T b A v D T b h b D T b 2 2 C T C t D T b α ξ / T b
Moreover, according to assumption (6), the carbon emission of the retailer will be related to the operational activities such as ordering, purchase of goods, storage, and delivery, so the retailer’s total carbon emissions per unit time (denoted by E b ( T b ,   ξ ) ) can be obtained as follows:
E b T b ,   ξ = [ 1 m ξ ] C a r b o n   e m i s s i o n s   g e n e r a t e d   b y   o r d e r i n g   a c t i v i t i e s + C a r b o n   e m i s s i o n s   g e n e r a t e d   b y   p u r c h a s e   a c t i v i t i e s + C a r b o n   e m i s s i o n s   g e n e r a t e d   b y   s h i p p i n g   a c t i v i t i e s + C a r b o n   e m i s s i o n s   g e n e r a t e d   b y   h o l d i n g   a c t i v i t i e s / T b   = [ 1 m ξ ] A ^ + v ^ D T b + h ^ b D T b 2 2 + C ^ T + C ^ t D T b / T b .

4.2. Manufacturer’s Total Profit and Carbon Emissions

The manufacturer’s total profit is equal to sales revenue minus setup costs, production costs, and holding costs; since the length of a production cycle is T v = T p + ( n 1 ) T b , the manufacturer’s total profit per unit of time (denoted by T P v ( T v , T s ,   ξ ,   n ) ) can be obtained as follows:
T P v ( T v , T s ,   ξ ,   n ) = S a l e s   r e v e n u e S e t u p   c o s t P r o d u c t i o n   c o s t H o l d i n g   c o s t I n v e s t m e n t   i n   c a r b o n   e m i s s i o n s / T v   = v n D T b S c P T s h v n D 2 T b 2 2 2 n P + n 1 D ( 1 α ) ξ / T v .
Similarly, according to assumption (6), the carbon emissions of the manufacturer will be related to operational activities such as material procurement, installation, production, and storage, so the total carbon emissions per unit time of the manufacturer (denoted by E v ( T v , T s ,   ξ ,   n ) ) can be obtained as follows:
E v ( T v , T s ,   ξ ,   n ) = [ 1 m ξ ] C a r b o n   e m i s s i o n s   g e n e r a t e d   b y   s e t u p   a c t i v i t i e s + C a r b o n   e m i s s i o n s   g e n e r a t e d   b y   p r o d u c t i o n   a c t i v i t i e s + C a r b o n   e m i s s i o n s   g e n e r a t e d   b y   h o l d i n g   a c t i v i t i e s / T v   = [ 1 m ξ ] { S ^ + c ^ P T s + h ^ v n D 2 T b 2 2 2 n P + n 1 D } / T v .
Because of the length of time the manufacturer is engaged in production in a production cycle T s = n D T b / P , and the length of the production cycle T v = D T b / P + ( n 1 ) T b , T P v ( T v , T s ,   ξ ,   n ) and E v ( T v , T s ,   ξ ,   n ) can be reduced, respectively, to T P v ( T b ,   ξ , n ) and E v ( T b ,   ξ ,   n ) .
Next, considering the following situations: (I) retailers facing a carbon tax policy and manufacturers facing a mixed policy of carbon cap-and-trade and carbon tax, (II) where the retailer faces a cap-and-trade policy and the manufacturer faces a mixed policy of cap-and-trade and carbon tax. The purpose of this study is to determine the manufacturer’s production, delivery, and investing strategies and the retailer’s replenishment strategy, respectively, so as to maximize the individual total profit at equilibrium. If the enterprise retailer or manufacturer belongs to a country that has established a carbon cap-and-trade mechanism, its total carbon emission quota will be ω b or ω b . When its carbon emissions exceed or fall below the quota, it will be traded at price C 1 through the carbon trading market to sell or obtain additional rights. Relatively speaking, if the country where the supply chain members belong adopts a carbon tax policy, their government agencies will induce them to consider environmental costs through additional carbon taxes. To simplify the model, this study considers that the tax schedule is linear, that is, companies pay C 2 per unit of carbon emissions [5].
For the above two situations, this study will calculate the total profit per unit time of the retailer and the manufacturer, respectively, under the carbon emission policies (denoted by Π b I T b ,   ξ , Π b I I T b ,   ξ , and Π v T b ,   ξ ,   n , respectively) as follows:
Π b I T b ,   ξ = T P b T b ,   ξ C 1 [ E b T b ,   ξ ϖ ¯ b ]   = 1 T b [ p D T b { A + C 1 [ 1 m ξ ] A ^ } { v + C 1 [ 1 m ξ ] v ^ } T b   h b + C 1 1 m ξ h ^ b D T b 2 2 { C T + C 1 1 m ξ C ^ T } { C t +   C 1 1 m ξ C ^ t } D T b ] + C 1 ϖ ¯ b ,
Π b I I T b ,   ξ = T P b T b ,   ξ C 2 E b T b ,   ξ   = 1 T b [ p D T b { A + C 2 1 m ξ A ^ } { v + C 2 [ 1 m ξ ] v ^ } T b   h b + C 2 1 m ξ h ^ b D T b 2 2 { C T + C 2 1 m ξ C ^ T } { C t +   C 2 1 m ξ C ^ t } D T b ]
Π v T b ,   ξ ,   n = T P v T b ,   ξ ,   n C 1 E v T b ,   ξ ,   n ϖ ¯ v C 2 E v T b ,   ξ ,   n   = 1 ( D T b / P ) + ( n 1 ) T b { v n D T b { S + ( C 1 + C 2 ) 1 m ξ S ^ } { c + ( C 1         + C 2 ) 1 m ξ c ^ } n D T b         { h v + ( C 1 + C 2 ) 1 m ξ h ^ v } n D 2 T b 2 2 2 n P + n 1 D }         + C 1 ϖ ¯ v
In view of the above different scenarios, this study intends to solve the problem from the perspective of a Stackelberg game, with the main purpose of seeking the manufacturer’s optimal production, delivery, investing policies, and the retailer’s optimal ordering policy to achieve game equilibrium under different carbon emission policy combinations, so as to maximize their respective total profit functions. The description of the Stackelberg game is as follows.

4.3. Stackelberg Game and Equilibrium

Consider a Stackelberg game with two players involved, the manufacturer and the retailer, in which the manufacturer is a leader, and the retailer is a follower. Suppose the manufacturer’s strategy is ( x , y ) and the retailer’s strategy is z. The two sides face the profit functions of f A ( x , y ,   z ) and f B ( x , y ,   z ) , respectively, where ( x , y ,   z ) A × B . A and B is defined as the set of strategies that the manufacturer and the retailer can take and A × B is defined as the set of all reasonable decisions. The purpose is to find a solution ( x , y , z ) A × B that maximizes the manufacturer’s and the retailer’s profit functions ( f A ( x , y , z ) and f B ( x , y , z ) ). Based on the fact that the manufacturer is the leader, the retailer is the follower, and the manufacturer’s and the retailer’s strategies are ( x , y ) and z, the manufacturer’s goal is to maximize f A ( x , y ,   z ) and the retailer’s goal is to maximize f B ( x , y ,   z ) for any given ( x , y ) . Accordingly, ( x * , y * ,   z * ) represents Stackelberg equilibrium if it satisfies the following conditions (Lu et al. [26,27]):
f A ( x * , y * ,   z * ) = sup f A ( x , y , Z ( x , y ) ) , x A , Z ( x , y ) = max f B ( x , y , z ) , y B ,
The process of solving the Stackelberg equilibrium is explained as follows. First, the retailer (i.e., the follower) finds its value of T b to maximize its own profit, which is a function of ξ ( T b ( ξ ) ). Then the manufacturer (i.e., the leader) determined the optimal values of ( n , ξ ) based on the value of T b ( ξ ) . Once the optimal values of ( n , ξ ) are determined, the optimal value of T b is obtained, thereby achieving the Stackelberg equilibrium. Due to the complexity of the model and the fact that n is an integer, it is difficult to find the close form of ( n , ξ ) and check the concavity of the manufacturer’s profit function directly. Alternatively, this study develops a simple algorithm (Algorithm 1) to obtain the solutions for the manufacturer and the retailer under a Stackelberg equilibrium.
Algorithm 1. The process of finding the optimal equilibrium solution.
Step 1.
Solve Π b I T b ,   ξ T b = 0 or Π b I I T b ,   ξ T b = 0 to find the optimal value of T b (say T b I ( ξ ) or T b I I ( ξ ) which is function of ξ ) and then substitute T b ( ξ ) into (7) to obtain Π v T b ,   ξ ,   n T b = T b I ( ξ ) or Π v T b ,   ξ ,   n T b = T b I I ( ξ ) .
Step 2.
Let n = 1.
Step 3.
Find the value of ξ (say ξ ( n ) I or ξ ( n ) I I ) by setting Π v T b , ξ , n T b = T b I ξ ξ = 0 or Π v T b , ξ , n T b = T b I I ξ ξ = 0 .
Step 4.
Substitute ξ ( n ) I or ξ ( n ) I I into (7) to obtain Π v T b , ξ ( n ) I , n T b = T b I ( ξ ( n ) I ) or Π v T b , ξ ( n ) I I , n T b = T b I I ( ξ ( n ) I I ) .
Step 5.
Set n = n + 1 , and repeat Step 3 to get Π v T b , ξ ( n + 1 ) I , n + 1 T b = T b I ( ξ ( n + 1 ) I ) or Π v T b , ξ ( n + 1 ) I I , n + 1 T b = T b I I ( ξ ( n + 1 ) I I ) .
Step 6.
If Π v T b , ξ ( n + 1 ) I , n + 1 T b = T b I ( ξ ( n + 1 ) I ) < Π v T b , ξ ( n ) I , n T b = T b I ( ξ ( n ) I ) or Π v T b , ξ ( n + 1 ) I I , n + 1 T b = T b I I ( ξ ( n + 1 ) I I ) < Π v T b , ξ ( n ) I I , n T b = T b I I ( ξ ( n ) I I ) , then Π v T b , ξ * , n * T b = T b ( ξ * ) = Π v T b , ξ ( n ) I , n T b = T b I ( ξ ( n ) I ) or Π v T b , ξ ( n ) I I , n T b = T b I I ( ξ ( n ) I I ) and hence ( ξ * , n * ) = ( ξ n I , n ) or ( ξ n I I , n ) is the optimal solution for the vendor. Otherwise, return to Step 5.
Step 7.
Substitute ( n * , ξ * ) into Π b I T b , ξ T b = 0 or Π b I I T b , ξ T b = 0 and solve it to find the optimal value of T b * = T b ( ξ * ) .
Once the equilibrium solution ( T b * , ξ * , n * ) is obtained, we can determine the total profits and the amount of carbon emissions produced by the retailer and the manufacturer E b T b * , ξ * and E v T b * , ξ * , n * . Further, the corresponding maximum profits can be calculated as Π b I T b * , ξ * or Π b I I T b * , ξ * and Π v T b * , ξ * , n * .

5. Numerical Analysis

5.1. Numerical Examples

This section considers a multi-national supply chain system and uses several numerical examples, drawing partly from previous literature, such as Ghosh et al. [43] and Lu et al. [26,27], and partly utilizing reasonable values to verify the proposed production inventory models. The relevant parameter values are described in Table 1 as follows.
Based on the above-mentioned calculation method and the mathematical software Mathematica 7.0, we illustrate the solution processes and results for the two different situations.
Situation I: The retailer faces a carbon tax policy, and the manufacturer faces a mixed policy of carbon cap-and-trade and carbon tax.
In this situation, when the Stackelberg equilibrium is reached, the optimal number of times for the manufacturer to ship the item to the retailer n * = 4 and the optimal carbon reduction investment amount ξ * = $568.715. The optimal replenishment cycle length of the retailer T b * = 0.6295 years and optimal order quantity Q * = 5035.64 units. At this time, the optimal carbon emission quantity and total profit of the manufacturer and the retailer to achieve Stackelberg equilibrium are E b * = 1500.64 kg, E v * = 1050.17 kg, Π b I * = $102,877, and Π v I * = $13,781. The solving process for Situation I is illustrated in Table 2 below.
Scenario II: The retailer faces a cap-and-trade policy, and the manufacturer faces a mixed policy of cap-and-trade and a carbon tax.
In this situation, when the Stackelberg equilibrium is reached, the optimal number of times for the manufacturer to ship the item to the retailer n * = 4 and the optimal carbon reduction investment amount ξ * = $568.315. The optimal replenishment cycle length of the retailer T b * = 0.6201 years and optimal order quantity Q * = 4960.91 units. At this time, the optimal carbon emission quantity and total profit of the manufacturer and the retailer to achieve Stackelberg equilibrium are E b * = 1500.87 kg, E v * = 1050.33 kg, Π b I I * = $90,877.1, and Π v I * = $13,779. Similarly, the solving process for Situation II is illustrated in Table 3 below.
Next, we will compare the carbon emissions and total profits of the two situations under the Stackelberg equilibrium. The following tables show comparisons of the optimal carbon emissions and total profits of Situation I and Situation II considering different carbon price, C 1 , and carbon tax, C 2 (see Table 4 and Table 5).
From the results of Table 4 and Table 5, it can be found that the carbon emissions of retailers and manufacturers will decrease regardless of the increase in carbon price or carbon tax. In terms of total profit, when the carbon price increases, the total profit of manufacturers will increase; conversely, the total profit of manufacturers will decrease as the carbon tax increases. As to the retailer, if the carbon tax is increased, its total profit will be reduced, aligning with previous related studies. However, the difference is that the retailer’s optimal total profit will first decrease and then increase in Situation I, while in Situation II, the retailer’s optimal total profit will decrease as the carbon price increases. Further, through comparison, it is found that the carbon emissions of the manufacturer and the retailer in Situation II are higher than those in Situation I, while the total profits of the manufacturer and the retailer in Situation I are higher than those in Situation II.

5.2. Sensitivity Analysis

To comprehend the impact of the changes in the parameters of the production inventory model of the supply chain system on the decision making, carbon emissions, and total profit among its members, this study conducts a sensitivity analysis of the model’s parameters. It integrates and elaborates on the numerical analysis results to furnish a reference for the manufacturer and the retailer, aiding them in decision making to adapt to external environmental changes. Given the extensive number of model parameters, this study will be divided into two groups: those related to total profit and those related to carbon emissions. The sensitivity analysis results of each parameter are displayed in Table 6 and Table 7.
Based on Table 6, the following numerical analysis results can be obtained:
(1)
When the market demand rate increases, the retailer’s optimal order quantity and the manufacturer’s optimal carbon emission reduction investment will increase, and the retailer’s optimal replenishment cycle will decrease. This increase will also lead to an increase in the carbon emissions and total profit of the retailer, as well as the carbon emissions of the manufacturer. Nevertheless, the total profit of the manufacturer will initially decrease and then increase as the demand rate rises.
(2)
When the manufacturer’s production rate increases, the retailer’s optimal replenishment cycle and order quantity will decrease, and the manufacturer’s optimal carbon reduction investment will also decrease. At this time, both the retailer’s carbon emissions and the manufacturer’s carbon emissions will increase. The manufacturer’s total profit will decrease as its production rate increases, while the retailer’s total profit will remain unaffected by this change.
(3)
When the retailer’s ordering cost, the retailer’s fixed delivery cost, or the manufacturer’s setup cost increases, the retailer’s optimal replenishment cycle and order quantity will increase, and the manufacturer’s optimal carbon emission reduction investment will also increase. This will result in both retailers’ carbon emissions and manufacturers’ carbon emissions being reduced. As generally recognized, an increase in the retailer’s ordering cost or fixed delivery cost will reduce its total profit, while changes in the manufacturer’s setup cost will not affect the retailer’s total profit. Interestingly, the manufacturer’s total profit increases as the retailer’s ordering cost or fixed delivery cost increases.
(4)
With an increase in the manufacturer’s production cost, the retailer’s optimal replenishment cycle and order quantity will decrease, and the manufacturer’s optimal carbon emission reduction investment will also decrease. Consequently, the retailer’s carbon emissions will increase and the manufacturer’s carbon emissions will decrease; the manufacturer’s total profit will decrease as production costs increase. Moreover, generally speaking, the retailer’s total profit will not be affected by changes in the manufacturer’s production costs if the manufacturer does not adjust its shipping strategy. However, when the production cost increases to a certain level (for example, c = 18 in Table 6), the retailer’s profits will then decrease.
(5)
When the manufacturer’s supply price increases, the retailer’s optimal replenishment cycle and order quantity will increase, and the manufacturer’s optimal carbon emission reduction investment will also increase. This causes the retailer’s carbon emissions to decrease, and the manufacturer’s carbon emissions to increase. Further, with the increase in the manufacturer’s supply price, the retailer’s total profit will decrease, while the manufacturer’s total profit will increase.
(6)
Regarding the impact of changes in holding costs, whether the holding cost of the retailer or the manufacturer increases, the retailer’s optimal replenishment cycle and order quantity will decrease, and the manufacturer’s optimal carbon emission reduction investment will also decrease. Likewise, this results in increased carbon emissions for both the retailer and the manufacturer. However, the change in the retailer’s or manufacturer’s holding cost has different impacts on their total profits. That is, the total profits of the retailer and manufacturer will decrease as the retailer’s holding cost increases. However, although the manufacturer’s total profit will decrease as the manufacturer’s holding cost increases, once the manufacturer’s holding cost increases to a certain level (for example, h v = 0.36 in Table 6), the retailer’s profit will decrease accordingly.
(7)
When the retailer’s variable delivery cost increases or selling price decreases, the retailer’s total profit decreases, yet it does not impact the retailer’s optimal replenishment cycle and order quantity, the manufacturer’s optimal carbon emission reduction investment, the retailer’s and the manufacturer’s carbon emission, and the manufacturer’s total profit within the supply chain system, where the manufacturer acts as the leader.
According to Table 7, the following numerical analysis results can be obtained:
(1)
As the carbon emissions generated by retailers’ ordering activities or the fixed carbon emissions generated by retailers’ delivery activities increase, the retailer’s optimal replenishment cycle and order quantity will increase, and the manufacturer’s optimal carbon emission reduction investment will also increase. This will lead to an increase in the retailer’s carbon emissions but a decrease in those of the manufacturer. Consequently, the retailer’s total profit will diminish, whereas the manufacturer’s total profit will increase.
(2)
When the carbon emissions generated by the manufacturer’s setup activities increase, the retailer’s optimal replenishment cycle and order quantity will increase, and the manufacturer’s optimal carbon emission reduction investment will also increase. This will cause the manufacturer’s carbon emissions to increase, but the retailer’s carbon emissions will decrease and the total profit of the manufacturer will decrease, while the retailer’s profit will increase accordingly.
(3)
As the carbon emissions generated by the manufacturer’s production activities increase, the retailer’s optimal replenishment cycle and order quantity will increase, and the manufacturer’s optimal carbon emission reduction investment will also increase. This causes the manufacturer’s carbon emissions to increase, but the retailer’s carbon emissions will increase first and then decrease. The manufacturer’s total profit decreases as the carbon emissions generated by the manufacturer’s production activities increases, while the retailer’s profit increases. Furthermore, changes in carbon emissions caused by production activities (for example, c ^ = 0.96 ) may affect the manufacturer’s shipping strategy.
(4)
As the carbon emissions generated by retailers’ purchase activities or the variable carbon emissions generated by retailers’ delivery activities increase, only the retailer’s carbon emissions will increase, but its total profit will decrease, which will not affect the retailer’s optimal replenishment cycle and order quantity, nor the manufacturer’s optimal carbon emission reduction investment, total carbon emissions, and total profit.
(5)
When the unit carbon emission of the retailer’s or manufacturer’s holding activities increases, the retailer’s optimal replenishment cycle and order quantity will decrease, and the manufacturer’s optimal carbon emission reduction investment will also decrease. This results in higher carbon emissions for the retailer and the manufacturer but decreases their total profits.

6. Conclusions

This study mainly focused on production inventory problems of the manufacturers with high carbon emissions, addressing a mixed carbon emission policy of carbon cap-and-trade and carbon tax simultaneously, and explored different situations where the retailer may face carbon emission policies. Additionally, by considering a Stackelberg game in which the manufacturer is the leader and the retailer is the follower, this study determined the optimal production, shipping, carbon reduction investment, and replenishment for both parties under the equilibrium for different carbon emission policy combinations. In order to verify the model and explain the solution process, this study used several numerical examples to solve and compare the proposed models. Through comparison with numerical examples, it can be concluded that regardless of the increase in carbon price or carbon tax, the retailer and the manufacturer will adjust their optimal decisions to reduce carbon emissions. In terms of the manufacturer’s total profit, an increase in carbon price will help increase the manufacturer’s total profit, while an increase in carbon tax will reduce its total profit, which is similar to previous research, such as [13,14,18]. What differs from previous results is the impact on retailer’s total profit; this study shows that it will first decrease and then increase as the carbon price increases but will increase with the increase in the carbon tax under the carbon cap-and-trade policy. In contrast, under the carbon tax policy, regardless of the carbon price or the carbon tax increases, the retailer’s total profit will decrease.
In addition, to provide manufacturers and retailers with a decision-making reference in response to changes in the external environment, this study conducted a sensitivity analysis on the main parameters of the proposed model and obtained some meaningful management insights. For example, compared with previous studies that believe that an increase in demand rate can increase manufacturers’ total profit [26,27], the findings of this study indicated that the total profit of the manufacturer will initially decrease and then increase as the demand rate rises when considering a supply chain system in which a manufacturer is the leader. Moreover, an increased manufacturer production rate does help the manufacturer reduce carbon emissions, but its total profit will also be reduced because the retailer reduces optimal order quantity. Finally, most previous related studies (see, for example, [13,14,18,19,20,30,35]) only presented the impact of changes in carbon emission parameters on the optimal solution, carbon emissions, and total profits. This study further compared the sensitivities of these parameters and obtained that the sensitivity of the manufacturer’s carbon emissions generated by production activities is relatively high, while the sensitivity of the retailer’s carbon emissions generated by purchasing activities is relatively high. That is to say, when low-carbonization strategies are necessary, the retailer or manufacturer that can effectively reduce the carbon emissions generated by these activities will significantly reduce entire carbon emissions.
Several future research directions can be considered. First of all, this model only considers the fixed market demand rate faced by the retailer. However, in reality, the demand for some commodities may be dependent on price, inventory level, low-carbon investment, etc.; thus, the variable demand rate can be taken into account in the future. Moreover, there may be multiple retailers or multiple channels in modern supply chain systems, so the proposed model can be extended to include production inventory problems involving multiple retailers or multiple channels. Furthermore, in this case, the algorithm developed in this study may not be applicable, so meta-heuristic algorithms can be considered to solve the model and compare the results [44]. This study can also take several practical scenarios, such as allowing shortages, trade credit, quantity discounts, or other carbon emission policies, into account.

Author Contributions

J.P.: Conceptualization, methodology, formal analysis, writing—original draft preparation; K.-S.W.: Conceptualization, methodology, writing—original draft preparation; C.-T.Y.: Methodology, formal analysis, software, writing—original draft preparation; C.-J.L.: Validation, writing—review and editing; S.L.: Writing—original draft preparation. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Data Availability Statement

The datasets used and/or analyzed during the current study are available from the corresponding author on reasonable request at [email protected].

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflicts of interest.

References

  1. The Global Risks Report 2023 18th Edition INSIGHT REPORT. Available online: https://www3.weforum.org/docs/WEF_Global_Risks_Report_2023.pdf (accessed on 7 May 2024).
  2. Mishra, U.; Wu, J.Z.; Sarkar, B. Optimum sustainable inventory management with backorder and deterioration under controllable carbon emissions. J. Clean. Prod. 2021, 279, 123699. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Sepehri, A.; Mishra, U.; Sarkar, B. A sustainable production-inventory model with imperfect quality under preservation technology and quality improvement investment. J. Clean. Prod. 2021, 310, 127332. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Bouchery, Y.; Ghaffari, A.; Jemai, Z.; Dallery, Y. Including sustainability criteria into inventory models. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2012, 222, 229–240. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Chen, X.; Benjaafar, S.; Elomri, A. The carbon-constrained EOQ. Oper. Res. Lett. 2013, 41, 172–179. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Benjaafar, S.; Li, Y.; Daskin, M. Carbon footprint and the management of supply chain: Insights from simple models. IEEE Trans. Autom. Sci. Eng. 2013, 10, 99–116. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Hua, G.; Cheng, T.C.E.; Wang, S. Managing carbon footprints in inventory management. J. Prod. Econ. 2011, 132, 178–185. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Arslan, M.C.; Turkay, M. EOQ revisited with sustainability considerations. Found. Comput. Decis. Sci. 2013, 38, 223–249. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. He, P.; Zhang, W.; Xu, X.; Bian, Y. Production lot-sizing and carbon emissions under cap-and-trade and carbon tax regulations. J. Clean. Prod. 2015, 103, 241–248. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Battini, D.; Persona, A.; Sgarbossa, F. A sustainable EOQ model: Theoretical formulation and applications. J. Prod. Econ. 2014, 149, 145–153. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Hovelaque, V.; Bironneau, L. The carbon-constrained EOQ model with carbon emission dependent demand. J. Prod. Econ. 2015, 164, 285–291. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Wu, C.; Zhao, Q.; Xi, M. A retailer-supplier supply chain model with trade credit default risk in a supplier-Stackelberg game. Comput. Ind. Eng. 2017, 112, 568–575. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Shen, Y.J.; Shen, K.F.; Yang, C.T. A Production-Inventory Model for Deteriorating Items with Collaborative Preservation Technology Investment Under Carbon Tax. Sustainability 2019, 11, 5027. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Rout, C.; Paul, A.; Kumar, R.S.; Chakraborty, D.; Goswami, A. Cooperative sustainable supply chain for deteriorating item and imperfect production under different carbon emission regulations. J. Clean. Prod. 2020, 272, 122170. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Qi, Q.; Wang, J.; Bai, Q. Pricing decision of a two-echelon supply chain with one supplier and two retailers under a carbon cap regulation. J. Clean. Prod. 2017, 151, 286–302. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Huang, Y.S.; Fang, C.C.; Lin, Y.A. Inventory management in supply chains with consideration of logistics, green investment and different carbon emissions policies. Comput. Ind. Eng. 2020, 139, 106207. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Astanti, R.D.; Daryanto, Y.; Dewa, P.K. Low-carbon supply chain model under a vendor-managed inventory partnership and carbon cap-and-trade policy. J. Open Innov. Technol. Mark. Complex. 2022, 8, 30. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Cheng, M.C.; Lo, H.C.; Yang, C.T. Optimizing Pricing, Pre-Sale Incentive, and Inventory Decisions with Advance Sales and Trade Credit under Carbon Tax Policy. Mathematics 2023, 11, 2534. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Lu, C.J.; Gu, M.; Lee, T.S.; Yang, C.T. Impact of carbon emission policy combinations on the optimal production-inventory decisions for deteriorating items. Expert Syst. Appl. 2022, 201, 117234. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Shen, L.; Lin, F.; Cheng, T.C.E. Low-carbon transition models of high carbon supply chains under the mixed carbon cap-and-trade and carbon tax policy in the Carbon Neutrality Era. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2022, 19, 11150. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Emmons, H.; Gilbert, S.M. The role of returns policies in pricing and inventory decisions for catalogue goods. Manag. Sci. 1988, 44, 276–283. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Chang, L.F.; Huang, C.Y.; Zhen, L.U. The study on supply chain Stackelberg game problem. Chin. J. Manag. Sci. 2002, 10, 48–52. [Google Scholar]
  23. Chern, M.S.; Pan, Q.; Teng, J.T.; Chan, Y.L.; Chen, S.C. Stackelberg solution in a vendor–buyer supply chain model with permissible delay in payments. J. Prod. Econ. 2013, 144, 397–404. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Chern, M.S.; Chan, Y.L.; Teng, J.T.; Goyal, S.K. Nash equilibrium solution in a vendor–buyer supply chain model with permissible delay in payments. Comput. Ind. Eng. 2014, 70, 116–123. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Jaggi, C.K.; Gupta, M.; Kausar, A.; Tiwari, S. Inventory and credit decisions for deteriorating items with displayed stock dependent demand in two-echelon supply chain using Stackelberg and Nash equilibrium solution. Ann. Oper. Res. 2019, 274, 309–329. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Lu, C.J.; Lee, T.S.; Gu, M.; Yang, C.T. A multistage sustainable production–inventory model with carbon emission reduction and price-dependent demand under Stackelberg game. Appl. Sci. 2020, 10, 4878. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Lu, C.J.; Yang, C.T.; Yen, H.F. Stackelberg game approach for sustainable production-inventory model with collaborative investment in technology for reducing carbon emissions. J. Clean. Prod. 2020, 270, 121963. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Zhang, B.; Xu, L. Multi-item production planning with carbon cap and trade mechanism. J. Prod. Econ. 2013, 144, 118–127. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Dye, C.Y.; Yang, C.T. Sustainable trade credit and replenishment decisions with credit-linked demand under carbon emission constraints. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2015, 244, 187–200. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Hua, G.W.; Cheng, T.C.E.; Zhang, Y.; Zhang, J.L.; Wang, S.Y. Carbon-constrained perishable inventory management with freshness-dependent demand. Int. J. Simul. Model. 2016, 15, 542–552. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Ghosh, A.; Jha, J.K.; Sarmah, S.P. Optimal lot-sizing under strict carbon cap policy considering stochastic demand. Appl. Math. Model. 2017, 44, 688–704. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Mashud, A.H.M.; Pervin, M.; Mishra, U.; Daryanto, Y.; Tseng, M.L.; Lim, M.K. A sustainable inventory model with controllable carbon emissions in green-warehouse farms. J. Clean. Prod. 2021, 298, 126777. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Paul, A.; Pervin, M.; Roy, S.K.; Maculan, N.; Weber, G.W. A green inventory model with the effect of carbon taxation. Ann. Oper. Res. 2022, 309, 233–248. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Ruidas, S.; Seikh, M.R.; Nayak, P.K. A production inventory model with interval-valued carbon emission parameters under price-sensitive demand. Comput. Ind. Eng. 2021, 154, 107154. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Pan, J.; Chiu, C.Y.; Wu, K.S.; Yen, H.F.; Wang, Y.W. Sustainable production–inventory model in technical cooperation on investment to reduce carbon emissions. Processes 2020, 8, 1438. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Jauhari, W.A.; Wangsa, I.D.; Hishamuddin, H.; Rizky, N. A sustainable vendor-buyer inventory model with incentives, green investment and energy usage under stochastic demand. Cogent Bus. Manag. 2023, 10, 2158609. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Muthusamy, P.; Murugesan, V.; Selvaraj, V. Optimal production–inventory decision with shortage for deterioration item and effect of carbon emission policy combination with green technology. Environ. Dev. Sustain. 2023, 1–66. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Ma, S.; Zhang, L.L.; Cai, X. Optimizing joint technology selection, production planning and pricing decisions under emission tax: A Stackelberg game model and nested genetic algorithm. Expert Syst. Appl. 2024, 238, 122085. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Mahmoodi, A. Pricing and inventory decisions in a manufacturer-Stackelberg supply chain with deteriorating items. Kybernetes 2021, 50, 2347–2366. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Mahdavisharif, M.; Kazemi, M.; Jahani, H.; Bagheri, F. Pricing and inventory policy for non-instantaneous deteriorating items in vendor-managed inventory systems: A Stackelberg game theory approach. Int. J. Syst. Sci.-Oper. Logist. 2022, 10, 2038715. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Xin, C.; Zhou, Y.; Sun, M.; Chen, X. Strategic inventory and dynamic pricing for a two-echelon green product supply chain. J. Clean. Prod. 2022, 363, 132422. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Choudhury, M.; De, S.K.; Mahata, G.C. A pollution-sensitive multistage production-inventory model for deteriorating items considering expiration date under Stackelberg game approach. Environ. Dev. Sustain. 2023, 25, 11847–11884. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Ghosh, A.; Sarmah, S.P.; Jha, J.K. Collaborative model for a two-echelon supply chain with uncertain demand under carbon tax policy. Sādhanā 2018, 43, 144. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Manna, A.K.; Das, S.; Shaikh, A.A.; Bhunia, A.K.; Moon, I. Carbon emission controlled investment and warranty policy based production inventory model via meta-heuristic algorithms. Comput. Ind. Eng. 2023, 177, 109001. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Table 1. The values of all parameters used in the proposed model.
Table 1. The values of all parameters used in the proposed model.
ParameterValue
Demand rate2000 units/year
Production rate6000 units/year
Retailer’s ordering costUSD 200/order
Manufacturer’s setup costUSD 500/setup
Manufacturer’s production costUSD 15/unit
Manufacturer’s supply priceUSD 25/unit
Retailer’s selling priceUSD 80/unit
Retailer’s holding costUSD 0.5/unit/year
Manufacturer’s holding costUSD 0.3/unit/year
Ratailer’s fixed delivery costUSD 50/shipment
Ratailer’s variable delivery costUSD 3/unit
Retailer’s carbon emissions generated by ordering activities50 kg/order
Manufacturer’s carbon emissions generated by setup activities150 kg/setup
Manufacturer’s carbon emissions generated by production activities0.8 kg/unit
Retailer’s carbon emissions generated by purchasing activities1 kg/unit
Retailer’s carbon emissions generated by holding activities0.05 kg/unit/year
Manufacturer’s carbon emissions generated by holding activities0.03 kg/unit/year
Retailer’s fixed carbon emissions generated by delievery activies3 kg/time
Retailer’s carbon emissions generated by delievery activies/unit0.05 kg/unit
Carbon price in carbon trading market/unitUSD 10/unit
Carbon taxUSD 8/unit
Retailer’s total carbon emissions quota 1500 kg/year
Manufacturer’s total carbon emissions quota1500 kg/year
Proportion of carbon emissions reduction 1 3 ( 1 e 0.01 ξ )
Table 2. Solution process of the proposed model (Situation I).
Table 2. Solution process of the proposed model (Situation I).
n T b ξ q Q E b E v Π b I Π v
10.6243458.2951248.651248.651505.88927.97102,84312,154
20.6271518.4711254.212508.421502.35996.16102,86813,390
30.6286550.3021257.183771.551501.171028.67102,87413,726
40.6295568.7151258.915035.641500.641050.17102,87713,781←
50.6299579.2421259.906299.491500.371066.82102,87813,712
60.6302584.7611260.427562.501500.241080.92102,87813,577
Note: The symbol “←” represents the optimal equilibrium solution.
Table 3. Solution process of the proposed model (Scenario II).
Table 3. Solution process of the proposed model (Scenario II).
n T b ξ q Q E b E v Π b I I Π v
1 0.6146460.6001229.141229.141505.95929.7390,856.112,103
20.6176520.1311235.242470.481502.51997.0090,873.313,366
30.6192551.0181238.443715.311501.371029.1090,877.113,715
40.6201568.3151240.234960.911500.871050.3390,878.113,779←
50.6206577.6891241.206206.001500.631066.7790,878.413,716
60.6208582.1141241.667449.961500.521080.6990,878.513,588
Note: The symbol “←” represents the optimal equilibrium solution.
Table 4. Comparison of optimal carbon emissions and total profit under various carbon prices.
Table 4. Comparison of optimal carbon emissions and total profit under various carbon prices.
C 1 Situation ISituation II
E b E v Π b I Π v E b E v Π b I I Π v
81501.221050.57102,877.412,8801501.221050.5790,877.412,880
91500.911050.36102,876.913,3301501.041050.4490,877.813,329
101500.641050.17102,876.713,7811500.871050.3390,878.113,779
111500.391050.00102,876.814,2321500.721050.2290,878.314,228
121500.181049.86102,877.114,6831500.581050.1390,878.514,678
Table 5. Comparison of optimal carbon emissions and total profits under various carbon taxes.
Table 5. Comparison of optimal carbon emissions and total profits under various carbon taxes.
C 2 Situation ISituation II
E b E v Π b I Π v E b E v Π b I I Π v
6.41500.911050.36102,875.615,4611501.391050.6993,28015,457
7.21500.771050.26102,876.214,6211501.121050.5092,07914,618
81500.641050.17102,876.713,7811500.871050.3390,87813,779
8.81500.521050.09102,877.112,9411500.651050.1789,67812,939
9.61500.411050.01102,877.412,1011500.451050.0488,47812,100
Table 6. Optimal solution under changes in parameters related to total profit.
Table 6. Optimal solution under changes in parameters related to total profit.
ParameterValue n * T b * ξ * q * Q * E b * E v * Π b I * Π v *
D 160040.7031557.1151125.034500.121210.05860.9885,10213,778
180040.6632563.1931193.824775.261355.49956.4593,98613,775
200040.6295568.7151258.915035.641500.641050.17102,87713,781
220040.6004573.7841320.855283.421645.531142.21111,77213,794
240040.5750578.4821380.075520.281790.201232.65120,67313,813
P 480040.62952570.0481259.045036.141500.601028.43102,87713,867
540040.62948569.3041258.975035.861500.621040.40102,87713,819
600040.62946568.7151258.915035.641500.641050.17102,87713,781
660040.62943568.2361258.875035.461500.651058.28102,87713,749
720040.62941567.8391258.835035.311500.661065.13102,87713,722
A 16040.6100567.1521220.064880.251501.171050.53102,94113,776
18040.6198567.9311239.644958.551500.891050.34102,90913,779
20040.6295568.7151258.915035.641500.641050.17102,87713,781
22040.6389569.5011277.895111.571500.411050.02102,84513,783
24040.6483570.2881296.605186.391500.221049.89102,81413,784
S 40040.62942567.8541258.835035.321500.661050.18102,87713,818
45040.62944568.2831258.875035.481500.651050.18102,87713,799
50040.62946568.7151258.915035.641500.641050.17102,87713,781
55040.62948569.148 1258.955035.801500.621050.16102,87713,763
60040.62950569.5831258.995035.971500.611050.15102,87713,744
c 1250.62995579.2421259.906299.491500.371066.82102,87819,337
13.540.62946568.7151258.915035.641500.641050.17102,87716,550
1540.62946568.7151258.915035.641500.641050.17102,87713,781
16.530.62859550.3021257.183771.551501.171028.67102,87411,026
1830.62859550.3021257.183771.551501.171028.67102,8748326
v 2030.62859550.3021257.183771.551501.171028.67112,8744726
22.530.62859550.3021257.183771.551501.171028.67107,8749226
2540.62946568.7151258.915035.641500.641050.17102,87713,781
27.540.62946568.7151258.915035.641500.641050.17102,87713,781
3050.62995579.2421259.906299.491500.371066.8292,87823,087
h b 0.440.6712572.2951342.30 5369.201499.841049.62103,00713,786
0.4540.6493570.4851298.615194.441500.201049.87102,94113,784
0.540.6295568.7151258.915035.641500.641050.17102,87713,781
0.5540.6113566.9871222.634890.511501.141050.51102,81413,776
0.640.5947565.3031189.304757.201501.691050.88102,75413,770
h v 0.2440.62955570.6521259.095036.371500.581050.13102,87713,862
0.2740.62950569.6791259.005036.001500.611050.15102,87713,822
0.340.62946568.7151258.915035.641500.641050.17102,87713,781
0.3340.62941567.7601258.825035.281500.661050.19102,87713,740
0.3640.62937566.8151258.73 5034.931500.691050.20102,87613,700
C t 2.440.6295568.7151258.915035.641500.641050.17104,07713,781
2.740.6295568.7151258.915035.641500.641050.17103,47713,781
340.6295568.7151258.915035.641500.641050.17102,87713,781
3.340.6295568.7151258.915035.641500.641050.17102,27713,781
3.640.6295568.7151258.915035.641500.641050.17101,67713,781
C T 4040.6247568.3221249.314997.241500.761050.25102,89313,779.7
4540.6271568.5181254.125016.481500.701050.21102,88513,780.3
5040.6295568.7151258.915035.641500.641050.17102,87713,780.8
5540.6318568.9111263.685054.731500.581050.13102,86913,781.3
6040.6342569.1081268.445073.751500.521050.09102,86113,781.8
p 6440.6295568.7151258.915035.641500.641050.1770,87713,781
7240.6295568.7151258.915035.641500.641050.1786,87713,781
8040.6295568.7151258.915035.641500.641050.17102,87713,781
8840.6295568.7151258.915035.641500.641050.17118,87713,781
9640.6295568.7151258.915035.641500.641050.17134,87713,781
Table 7. Optimal solution under changes in parameters related to carbon emissions.
Table 7. Optimal solution under changes in parameters related to carbon emissions.
ParameterValue n * T b * ξ * q * Q * E b * E v * Π b I * Π v *
A ^ 4040.5967566.1951193.354773.411490.411050.82102,98513,771
4540.6133567.4361226.574906.271495.631050.46102,93013,777
5040.6295568.7151258.915035.641500.641050.17102,87713,781
5540.6452570.0171290.445161.771505.461049.93102,82413,784
6040.6606571.3301321.225284.891510.111049.74102,77313,785
S ^ 12040.62928564.9341258.565034.221500.741042.89102,876.313,913
13540.62937566.8131258.735034.931500.691046.53102,876.513,847
15040.62946568.7151258.915035.641500.641050.17102,876.713,781
16540.62955570.6391259.095036.361500.591053.81102,876.813,715
18040.62964572.5881259.275037.091500.541057.44102,877.013,649
c ^ 0.6440.6285547.6571256.945027.751501.25853.27102,874.117,332
0.7240.6290558.7331257.975031.901500.91951.72102,875.615,556
0.840.6295568.7151258.915035.641500.641050.17102,876.713,781
0.8840.6299577.7981259.765039.051500.411148.62102,877.412,006
0.9630.6294567.6961258.813776.441500.661220.63102,876.610,264
v ^ 0.840.6295568.7151258.915035.641233.521050.17105,54813,781
0.940.6295568.7151258.915035.641367.081050.17104,21213,781
140.6295568.7151258.915035.641500.641050.17102,87713,781
1.140.6295568.7151258.915035.641634.191050.17101,54113,781
1.240.6295568.7151258.915035.641767.751050.17100,20513,781
h ^ b 0.0440.6564571.0751312.795251.171491.301049.78102,96313,785
0.04540.6425569.8811285.015140.031496.051049.97102,91913,783
0.0540.6295568.7151258.915035.641500.641050.17102,87713,781
0.05540.6172567.5741234.334937.331505.091050.39102,83513,778
0.0640.6056566.4591211.144844.551509.401050.63102,79413,774
h ^ v 0.02440.62954570.5231259.085036.321500.591044.7102,876.8413,879
0.0740.62950569.6131258.995035.981500.611047.44102,876.7513,830
0.0340.62946568.7151258.915035.641500.641050.17102,876.6713,781
0.03340.62941567.8301258.835035.311500.661052.90102,876.5813,732
0.03640.62937566.9571258.755034.981500.681055.63102,876.5013,683
C ^ t 0.0540.6295568.7151258.915035.641487.281050.17103,01013,781
0.0540.6295568.7151258.915035.641493.961050.17102,94313,781
0.0540.6295568.7151258.915035.641500.641050.17102,87713,781
0.0540.6295568.7151258.915035.641507.311050.17102,81013,781
0.0540.6295568.7151258.915035.641513.991050.17102,74313,781
C ^ T 2.440.6275568.5601255.075020.291500.041050.20102,88313,780.4
2.740.6285568.6371256.995027.971500.341050.18102,88013,780.6
340.6295568.7151258.915035.641500.641050.17102,87713,780.8
3.340.6304568.7921260.825043.301500.931050.15102,87313,781.0
3.640.6314568.8701262.745050.941501.221050.14102,87013,781.2
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Pan, J.; Wu, K.-S.; Yang, C.-T.; Lu, C.-J.; Lu, S. Using Game Theory to Explore the Multinational Supply Chain Production Inventory Models of Various Carbon Emission Policy Combinations. Mathematics 2024, 12, 1564. https://doi.org/10.3390/math12101564

AMA Style

Pan J, Wu K-S, Yang C-T, Lu C-J, Lu S. Using Game Theory to Explore the Multinational Supply Chain Production Inventory Models of Various Carbon Emission Policy Combinations. Mathematics. 2024; 12(10):1564. https://doi.org/10.3390/math12101564

Chicago/Turabian Style

Pan, Jialiang, Kun-Shan Wu, Chih-Te Yang, Chi-Jie Lu, and Shin Lu. 2024. "Using Game Theory to Explore the Multinational Supply Chain Production Inventory Models of Various Carbon Emission Policy Combinations" Mathematics 12, no. 10: 1564. https://doi.org/10.3390/math12101564

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop