Next Article in Journal
Key Vulnerable Nodes Discovery Based on Bayesian Attack Subgraphs and Improved Fuzzy C-Means Clustering
Previous Article in Journal
Age-Related Macular Degeneration Detection in Retinal Fundus Images by a Deep Convolutional Neural Network
Previous Article in Special Issue
BV Solutions to Evolution Inclusion with a Time and Space Dependent Maximal Monotone Operator
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Vector Equilibrium Problems—A Unified Approach and Applications

“Octav Mayer” Institute of Mathematics, Romanian Academy, Iaşi Branch, Bd. Carol I, No. 11, 700506 Iaşi, Romania
Mathematics 2024, 12(10), 1448; https://doi.org/10.3390/math12101448
Submission received: 26 March 2024 / Revised: 3 May 2024 / Accepted: 4 May 2024 / Published: 8 May 2024
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Set-Valued Analysis, 3rd Edition)

Abstract

:
We present existing results and properties for the solutions of some vector equilibrium problems with set-valued functions in the case of a vector space ordered by a cone with some “interiority” properties. Some applications concerning the existence of equilibrium for abstract economies and vector optimization problems are given.

1. Introduction

Begining with Blum and Oettli [1], who introduced an equilibrium problem as a generalization for the well-known Ky Fan inequalities, some vector equilibrium problems (VEPs) have been studied in the literature (see for instance [2,3,4,5,6,7,8,9]) as a tool which unifies the vector variational problem, vector complementary problem, vector optimization problem, vector saddle points problem, Nash equilibrium problem, and fixed point problem.
These problems was formulated with real or vector functions and multifunctions under various assumptions (concerning for example the presence or the absence of the convexity, the monotonicity, or the lower semicontinuity) and interesting results are obtained for the nonemptiness of the solutions set and its properties (see [10,11,12,13,14,15,16]).
Often, for the vector case, the results for VEPs are presented in spaces ordered by a nonempty, convex, pointed cone with a nonempty interior (see [7,17,18]). The framework considered here is a general one which includes both the case of cones with a nonempty and empty interior. In this context, some properties for VEPs with functions are given in [3,19,20] and some of these results can be found as particular cases of those in this paper for VEPs with set valued maps.
It is a theoretical approach to these problems that will be used as a mathematical support for the study of applications from the final sections.
We present in this paper a unified study for some vector equilibrium problems presented in Section 2 for set-valued functions (or multifunctions) with values in a vector space ordered by a cone with some “interiority property” (such as a nonempty interior or quasi interior or relative quasi interior). Section 3 presents some existence results for the solutions set of this problem. Section 4 gives properties for these solutions sets, such as the connectedness and the continuity. The Section 5 and Section 6 provide some applications of VEPs regarding the existence of equilibrium in abstract economies and the vector optimization problems.

2. Preliminaries

Let ( X , τ X , ( Y , τ Y ) , ( Z , τ Z ) be locally convex spaces, A X , B Y be nonempty convex compact sets, W Z be a convex set, and let K , Z + Z be nonempty, convex, pointed cones. We denote by Z * the topological dual space of Z, Z + * is the dual cone, i.e., Z + * = { z * Z * z * ( z ) 0 , z Z + } and Z # = { z * Z + * z * ( z ) > 0 , z Z + { 0 } } is the quasi-interior of the dual cone. A base for the cone Z + is a subset B Z + such that for each z Z + , there exists λ I R + and b B such that z = λ b . For example, if the interior of Z + is nonempty, the set { z * Z + * z * ( z ) = 1 } is a w * -compact base for the dual cone, where z is an element from the interior of Z + .
The interior (respectively, the closure, the boundary, and the complementary) of a set A will be denoted by int A (respectively, cl A , Fr A and A c ). We write x n τ x if the sequence ( x n ) n I N is convergent to x for the τ locally convex topology of the spaces. If there is no confusion, we omit τ . Furthermore, conv A and cone A will denote the convex, respectively, the conic hull of A. The relative interior of Z + denoted ri Z + is the interior of Z + relative to the closed affine hull of Z + . The quasi (respectively, the intrinsec) relative interior of Z + denoted qri Z + (respectively, iri Z + ) is the set of z Z + for which cl cone ( Z + z ) (respectively, cone ( Z + z ) ) is a linear subspace of Z. P ( Z ) ( respectively, P c ( Z ) ) will denote the family of all nonempty subsets of Z (respectively, the family of all nonempty convex subsets of Z). For an element x X , V ( x ) will denote a fundamental system of neighborhoods for x.
Let F : X P ( Z ) be a set valued map (or multifunction, also denoted by F : A Z ). The domain of F (denoted dom F ) is dom F = { x X F ( x ) } and the graph of F (denoted Gr F ) is the set Gr F = { ( x , z ) X × Z x dom F , z F ( x ) } . A multifunction F : A Z ( A dom F ) is lower semicontinuous (l.s.c.) at x 0 A if for all z F ( x 0 ) and V V ( z ) , U V ( x 0 ) , such that F ( U A ) V . The multifunction F is upper semicontinuous (u.s.c.) at x 0 A if for any neighborhood V V ( 0 ) , there is U V ( x 0 ) such that F ( U A ) F ( x 0 ) + V . The multifunction F is Z + -lower semicontinuous at x 0 A if for all V V ( 0 ) there exists U V ( x 0 ) such that F ( U A ) F ( x 0 ) + V Z + . The multifunction F is quasi-lower semicontinuous (respectively quasi-convex) if the level sets N α = { x A F ( x ) α Z + } are closed (respectively, convex).
We say that the multifunction F is K-concave if for each x 1 , x 2 A and λ [ 0 , 1 ] we have F ( λ x 1 + ( 1 λ ) x 2 ) λ F ( x 1 ) + ( 1 λ ) F ( x 2 ) + K and λ F ( x 1 ) + ( 1 λ ) F ( x 2 ) F ( λ x 1 + ( 1 λ ) x 2 ) K . The multifunction F is K-convex if and only if F is K concave. We say F is K-convexlike if F ( A ) + K is convex and F has K-closed values if F ( x ) + K is closed for each x A . The multifunction F is closed if the graph Gr F is closed. We note by cl F the multifunction defined by cl F ( x ) = cl ( F ( x ) ) , x X and by co F the multifunction defined by co F ( x ) = conv ( F ( x ) ) , x X .
For A n , A Z we set Li A n = { x Z n I N , x n A n , x n τ x } and Ls A n = { x Z ( n k ) k I N x n k A n k , k I N x n k τ x } . We say that A is the τ -Painlevé–Kuratowski limit of A n (and we write A n τ P K A ) if Ls A n A Li A n .
Let us consider K : A X , T : A B , F : A × X × T ( A ) Z with nonempty values. We adopt the notations from [5]:
r 1 ( U , V ) U V r ¯ 1 ( U , V ) U V =
r 2 ( U , V ) U V r ¯ 2 ( U , V ) U V
Let us remark that r ¯ 1 ( U , V ) r 2 ( U , V c ) and r 1 ( U , V ) r ¯ 2 ( U , V c ) .
The vector equilibrium problem ( V E P 1 ) r i W , i = 1 , 2 will be:
( V E P 1 ) r i W find x ¯ A K ( x ¯ ) such that y K ( x ¯ ) , t ¯ T ( x ¯ ) ; r i ( F ( x ¯ , y , t ¯ ) , W ) .
The vector equilibrium problem ( V E P 2 ) r i W , i = 1 , 2 will be:
( V E P 2 ) r i W find x ¯ A K ( x ¯ ) such that t ¯ T ( x ¯ ) , y K ( x ¯ ) ; r i ( F ( x ¯ , y , t ¯ ) , W ) .
Let X = Y , K ( x ¯ ) = A , T ( x ) = { x } . For different types of W, we get some vector equilibrium problems studied in the literature:
  • W = int Z + , then ( V E P ) r 1 W is ( W V E P ) from [6];
  • W = Z \ int Z + , then ( V E P ) r ¯ 1 W is ( S V E P ) from [9].
  • W = qri Z + , then ( V E P ) r 1 W is ( Q V E P ) from [3]
  • W = comp ( int Z + ) i ε , then ( V E P ) r i W is ( Q E P ) r i ε from [5].
  • W = ε e + int Z + , then ( V E P ) r 1 W is ( W V E P ) ε from [21] and ( V E P ) r ¯ 2 W is ( G V E P ) from [22].

3. The Existence of the Solutions Set

For the existence of the solutions for ( V E P 1 ) r i W , let us denote:
E y i , W = { ( x , t ) x A , t T ( x ) , r i ( F ( x , y , t ) , W ) }
N y i , W = { x A t T ( x ) , r i ( F ( x , y , t ) , W ) } = Pr X E y i , W
N ¯ t , x i , W = { y K ( x ) r ¯ i ( F ( x , y , t ) , W ) }
Theorem 1
([23]). Let X be a Hausdorff topological space, A X be a nonempty compact convex set and ϕ : A X be a multifunction with nonempty convex values. Assume that for each x A , ϕ 1 ( x ) is open in A. Then, there exists x ¯ A , x ¯ ϕ ( x ¯ ) .
The following theorem generalizes Theorem 2.1 [5] and Theorem 13 [3], which may be reobtained as particular cases from the theorem, as is specified in Remark 1.
Theorem 2. 
Let us suppose:
(i) 
x A , t T ( x ) , N ¯ t , x i , W is convex and x t T ( x ) N ¯ t , x i , W ;
(ii) 
y A , N y i , W is closed;
(iii) 
cl K ( · ) is u.s.c. and K ( x ) is convex x A , A K ( x ) .
Furthermore, y A , K 1 ( y ) is open in A.
Then, ( V E P 1 ) r i W has a solution.
Proof. 
For x A set:
P ( x ) = { y A t T ( x ) , r ¯ i ( F ( x , y , t ) , W ) }
E = { y A y cl K ( y ) }
For each x A , (i) implies that P ( x ) is convex and (iii) implies that E is a closed set. For all y A , A P 1 ( y ) = { x A t T ( x ) , r i ( F ( x , y , t ) , W ) } and following (ii) P 1 ( y ) is open in A. Let Q : A A , Q ( x ) = K ( x ) P ( x ) if x E and Q ( x ) = A K ( x ) if x A E . We observe that Q ( x ) is convex for all x A . Furthermore, for all y A :
Q 1 ( y ) = { x E x K 1 ( y ) P 1 ( y ) } { x A E x K 1 ( y ) } =
= K 1 ( y ) [ P 1 ( A E ) ]
Therefore, A Q 1 ( y ) = A K 1 ( y ) [ ( A P 1 ( y ) ) E ] . Since K 1 ( y ) and P 1 ( y ) are open in A, this implies that Q 1 ( y ) is open in A for all y A . Hypothesis (i) implies that x P ( x ) , and thus, x Q ( x ) for all x A . Theorem 1 gives us x ¯ A such that Q ( x ¯ ) = . Since A K ( x ¯ ) , x ¯ E , K ( x ¯ ) P ( x ¯ ) = . Thus, x ¯ A c l K ( x ¯ ) , y P ( x ¯ ) , y K ( x ¯ ) , i.e, there exists t ¯ T ( x ¯ ) such that r i ( F ( x ¯ , y , t ¯ ) , W ) . We conclude that ( V E P 1 ) r i W has a solution. □
Remark 1. 
If F is a real single valued map, W = ε + I R + , K ( x ) = A and T ( x ) = { x } , then N ¯ t , x i , W is N x , the ε-set level, which (i) means that f ( x , · ) is quasi-convex and (ii) means that f ( · , y ) is quasi upper semicontinuous.
For the existence of the solutions for ( V E P 2 ) r i W , we denote:
E y i , W = { ( x , t ) x A , t T ( x ) , r i ( F ( x , y , t ) , W ) }
N ¯ t , x i , W = { y K ( x ) r ¯ i ( F ( x , y , t ) , W ) }
Theorem 3. 
Let us suppose:
(i) 
x A , t T ( x ) , N ¯ t , x i , W is convex and x ( x , t ) A × T ( x ) N ¯ t , x i , W ;
(ii) 
y A , E y i , W is closed and y A E y i , W is closed;
(iii) 
cl K ( · ) is u.s.c. and K ( x ) is convex x A , A K ( x ) .
Furthermore, y A , K 1 ( y ) is open in A.
Then, ( V E P 2 ) r i W has a solution.
Proof. 
The proof is similar to Theorem 1. □
The following result gives another type of existence theorem that relaxes the requests concerning the multifunction but impose additional conditions on the cone.
Theorem 4. 
Let us consider the following conditions:
(i) 
F ( A , b ) + Z + is convex for each b;
(ii) 
cl ( Z + Z + ) = Z and K = qri Z + { 0 } ;
(iii) 
K = qi Z + { 0 } ;
(iv) 
W qri ( cone F ( A , b ) + K ) = .
If ( i ) , ( ii ) , ( iv ) or ( i ) , ( iii ) , ( iv ) hold, then ( V E P ) r 1 W K { 0 } and ( V E P ) r ¯ 2 W K { 0 } have a solution.
Proof. 
Let us suppose that ( V E P ) r 1 W qri Z + has no solution. Thus, for each a A , there exists b A such that F ( a , b ) W qri Z + . Thus, w F ( A , b ) + qri Z + , which implies that w cone F ( A , b ) + qri Z + . Since F ( A , b ) + Z + is convex for each b, then cone F ( A , b ) + qri Z + is also convex.
(iii) implies that there exists z * Z + * { 0 } such that z * ( f ) z * ( w ) for all f F ( A , b ) , w W . However, there exists w W , f F ( a , b ) ( w qri Z + ) and follows (ii) we have z * ( f ) > z * ( w ) , which is false. Similarly, we obtain the other conclusion. □

4. Properties for the Solutions Set

In what follows, we consider K ( x ) = A , K = qi Z + { 0 } or K = qri Z + { 0 } , where W is a convex set and F has K-convex values. For z * Z + * { 0 } , z * ( qi Z + ) = I R + { 0 } and for z * Z + # , z * ( qri Z + ) = I R + { 0 } .
We denote:
S F ( V E P ) r ¯ 1 W K = { x A x is solution for ( V E P ) r ¯ 1 W K } ;
S F ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 W K = { x A y A , t T ( x ) , z * F ( x , y , t ) z * ( W K ) = } .
If there is no confusion, we simply denote S ( V E P ) r ¯ 1 W K and S ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 W K .
The following theorem generalizes the similar result for VEP with functions from [6].
Theorem 5. 
If K = qi Z + { 0 } , then:
z * Z + * { 0 } S ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 W K S ( V E P ) r ¯ 1 W K
z * Z + * { 0 } S ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 W K { 0 } = S ( V E P ) r ¯ 1 W K { 0 } .
If K = qri Z + { 0 } or K = qi Z + { 0 } , W is a convex compact set and F has K-closed values; moreover, we have
z * Z + * { 0 } S ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 W K = S ( V E P ) r ¯ 1 W K
and:
z * Z + * { 0 } S ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 W K { 0 } = S ( V E P ) r ¯ 1 W K { 0 } .
Proof. 
The first inclusion does hold obviously.
Let x S ; this implies that y A , t T ( x ) , F ( x , y , t ) ( W K ) = . Since F ( x , y , t ) + K and W K are convex sets, there exists z * Z * such that inf z * ( u ) sup z * ( v ) for u F + K and v W K . Obviously, z * Z + * { 0 } , and thus, z * F ( x , y , t ) ( z * ( W ) I R + { 0 } ) = . We deduce that z * F ( x , y , t ) z * ( W K { 0 } ) = , which implies:
S ( V E P ) r ¯ 1 W K z * Z + * { 0 } S ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 W K { 0 } .
The converse is obvious, and thus, the last equality from the conclusion follows. For the case when W is compact, the inequality from the separation theorem is strict and the conclusion follows similar. □
We denote:
S F ( V E P ) r 1 W K = { x A x is solution for ( V E P ) r 1 W K }
S F ( V E P ) z * , r 1 W K = { x A y A , t T ( x ) , z * F ( x , y , t ) z * ( W K ) } .
If there is no confusion, we denote simply: S ( V E P ) r 1 W K and S ( V E P ) z * , r 1 W K .
Theorem 6. 
If K = qi Z + , then:
S ( V E P ) r 1 W K { 0 } = z * Z + * { 0 } S ( V E P ) z * , r 1 W K { 0 }
S ( V E P ) r 1 W K z * Z + * { 0 } S ( V E P ) z * , r 1 W K
If K = qri Z + , or K = qi Z + , W is a convex compact set and F has K-closed values, we have:
S ( V E P ) r 1 W K { 0 } = z * Z + * { 0 } S ( V E P ) z * , r 1 W K { 0 } a n d
S ( V E P ) r 1 W K = z * Z + * { 0 } S ( V E P ) z * , r 1 W K .
Proof. 
Let x S . For all y B , there exists t T ( x ) such that F ( x , y , t ) ( W K { 0 } ) . This fact implies that for all z * Z + * { 0 } , we have z * F ( x , y , t ) z * ( W K { 0 } ) .
For the converse, let us suppose that z * F ( x , y , t ) z * ( W K { 0 } ) and F ( x , y , t ) ( W K { 0 } ) = . We find z * Z + * { 0 } such that inf z * ( u ) sup z * ( v ) for u F + K and v W K . Since ( z * F ( x , y , t ) ) z * ( W K ) will exists v W K { 0 } , u F ( x , y , t ) , w W such that z * ( u ) = z * ( v ) < z * ( w ) sup z * ( W K ) inf z * F ( x , y , t ) is false. The other inclusion does hold obviously. The case when W is compact follows similar to the previous theorem.
We denote:
S F ( V E P ) r 2 W K = { x A x is solution for ( V E P ) r 2 W K }
S F ( V E P ) z * , r 2 W K = { x A y A , t T ( x ) , z * F ( x , y , t ) z * ( W K ) } .
If there is no confusion, we denote simply S ( V E P ) r 2 W K and S ( V E P ) z * , r 2 W K . □
Theorem 7. 
If K = qi Z + ; qri Z + , then:
S ( V E P ) r 2 cl ( W K ) = z * Z + * { 0 } S ( V E P ) z * , r 2 cl ( W K )
Proof. 
Let x S . For all y A , there exists t T ( x ) , such that F ( x , y , t ) cl ( W K ) . Obviously, z * F ( x , y , t ) z * ( cl ( W K ) ) for all z * Z + * { 0 } . Now, let us suppose that there exists α F ( x , y , t ) and α cl ( W K ) . We find z * Z + * { 0 } such that sup { z * ( v ) , v W K } < z * ( α ) sup { z * ( v ) , v W K } is false.
We denote:
S F ( V E P ) r ¯ 2 W K = { x A x is solution for ( V E P ) r ¯ 2 W K }
S F ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 2 W K = { x A y A , t T ( x ) , z * F ( x , y , t ) z * ( W K ) } .
If there is no confusion, we denote simply S ( V E P ) r ¯ 2 W K and S ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 2 W K . □
Theorem 8. 
If K = qi Z + ; qri Z + , then:
S ( V E P ) r ¯ 2 cl ( W K ) = z * Z + * { 0 } S z * ( V E P ) r ¯ 2 cl ( W K )
Proof. 
Let x S . For all y A , there exists t T ( x ) , such that F ( x , y , t ) cl ( W K ) . Thus, there exists α F ( x , y , t ) and α cl ( W K ) . We find z * Z + * { 0 } such that z * ( α ) > sup { z * ( v ) , v W K } , which implies z * F ( x , y , t ) z * ( W K ) . The converse follows obviously and the equality does hold. □
Connectedness for the solutions sets. In the following, we consider K ( x ) = A , x A , and T ( x ) = { x } .
Theorem 9. 
Let us suppose that K = qi Z + { 0 } or K = qri Z + { 0 } , F ( x , · ) has K-convex values for each x A and F ( · , y ) is K-concave, for each y A . Then, for all z * Z + * { 0 } , S ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 W K and S ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 W K { 0 } are convex.
If K = qi Z + { 0 } and in addition we suppose that there exists α W such that cl ( W K ) = cl ( α K ) and S ( ( V E P ) r ¯ 1 ( α + qi Z + ) c ) , then the solutions set S ( ( V E P ) r ¯ 1 W K { 0 } ) is connected.
If W is a convex compact set and F has K-closed values, then S ( ( V E P ) r ¯ 1 W K ) is connected.
Proof. 
Let x 1 , x 2 S ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 W K . We have:
z * F ( x 1 , y ) ( z * ( W ) I R + ) = , y A ,
z * F ( x 2 , y ) ( z * ( W ) I R + ) = , y A .
These relations are equivalent with
z * F ( x 1 , y ) sup z * ( W ) + I R + { 0 } , , respectively
z * F ( x 2 , y ) sup z * ( W ) + I R + { 0 } .
Since F is K-concave, for each λ [ 0 , 1 ] we have:
F ( λ x 1 + ( 1 λ ) x 2 , y ) λ F ( x 1 , y ) + ( 1 λ ) F ( x 2 , y ) + K .
Also, we have z * F ( λ x 1 + ( 1 λ ) x 2 , y ) λ z * F ( x 1 , y ) + ( 1 λ ) z * F ( x 2 , y ) + I R + sup z * ( W ) + I R + { 0 } for z * Z + * { 0 } , which means that λ x 1 + ( 1 λ ) x 2 S ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 W K , and thus, S ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 W K is convex.
In the additional hypothesis, for all z * Z + * { 0 } , we have sup z * ( W ) = z * ( α ) and S ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 ( α + qi Z + ) c S ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 W K S ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 W K { 0 } . We deduce that S ( ( V E P ) r ¯ 1 W K { 0 } ) is connected. Similarly, we get the conclusion for the case when W is compact. □
Corollary 1. 
Let us suppose that K = qi Z + { 0 } , W is a convex compact set such that there exists α W , which satisfies cl ( W K ) = cl ( α K ) , F ( x , · ) has K-convex values for each x A , F ( · , y ) is K-concave, for each y A , F has K-closed values, and F ( x , y ) α + qi Z + for all y A ; then, S ( ( V E P ) r ¯ 1 W K ) is connected.
The following theorem is similar.
Theorem 10. 
Let us suppose that K = qi Z + { 0 } or K = qri Z + { 0 } , F ( x , · ) has K-convex values for each x A and F ( · , y ) is K-convex, for each y A . Then, for all z * Z + * , S ( V E P ) z * , r 1 W K and S ( V E P ) z * , r 1 W K { 0 } are convex.
If K = qi Z + { 0 } and S ( V E P ) r 1 W K { 0 } is nonempty, then S ( V E P ) r 1 W K { 0 } is connected. If, in addition, we consider W a convex compact set and F has K-closed values, then S ( V E P ) r 1 W K is connected.
Using Theorems 29 and 35, we get the following two theorems.
Theorem 11. 
Let K = qi Z + { 0 } or K = qri Z + { 0 } and suppose that F ( x , · ) has K-convex values, for each x A and F ( · , y ) is K-convex, for each y A . Then, for all z * Z + * , S ( V E P ) z * , r 2 cl ( W K ) are convex. If S ( V E P ) r 2 cl ( W K ) is nonempty, then S ( V E P ) r 2 cl ( W K ) is connected.
Theorem 12. 
Let us suppose that K = qi Z + { 0 } or K = qri Z + { 0 } , F ( x , · ) has K-convex values, for each x A and F ( · , y ) is K-concave, for each y A . Then, for all z * Z + * , S ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 2 cl ( W K ) are convex.
If K = qi Z + { 0 } and in addition we suppose that α W such that cl ( W K ) = cl ( α K ) and S ( V E P ) r ¯ 2 ( α + qi Z + ) c , then S ( ( V E P ) r ¯ 2 cl ( W K ) ) is connected.
For K = qi Z + { 0 } , the following theorem gives the link between the solutions set S ( V E P ) r i W Z + { 0 } and the solutions set S ( V E P ) z * , r i W K { 0 } . Let us remark that if z * Z + # , the scalar problem ( V E P ) z * , r i W K { 0 } is equivalent to the scalar problem ( V E P ) z * , r i W Z + { 0 } .
Theorem 13. 
Let us suppose that K = qi Z + { 0 } , Z + # and F ( x , · ) has K-convex values, for each x A . Then:
z * Z + # S ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 W K { 0 } S ( V E P ) r ¯ 1 W Z + { 0 } z * Z + * { 0 } S ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 W K { 0 }
z * Z + * { 0 } S ( V E P ) z * , r 1 W Z + { 0 } S ( V E P ) W Z + { 0 } z * Z + # S ( V E P ) z * , r 1 W K { 0 } .
For the following relations, we may have K = qi Z + { 0 } or K = qri Z + { 0 } .
z * Z + * { 0 } S ( V E P ) z * , r 2 W K { 0 } S ( V E P ) r 2 W Z + { 0 } z * Z + # S ( V E P ) z * , r 2 W K { 0 }
z * Z + # S ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 2 cl ( W K { 0 } ) S ( V E P ) r ¯ 2 cl ( W Z + { 0 } ) z * Z + * { 0 } S ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 2 cl ( W K { 0 } ) .
Continuity properties for the solutions sets.
In the following, we generalize the corresponding results from [22] given for VEP with functions. Then, we say that a set sequence ( W n ) n I N P c ( X ) is weakly Painlevé–Kuratowski convergent to W (and we write W n w P K W ) if lim n + sup z * ( W n ) = sup z * ( W ) , z * Z + * { 0 } .
I.
The continuity with respect to “W”.
Theorem 14. 
Let z * Z + * { 0 } and suppose that F ( · , y ) is K-concave for each y A and S ( V E P ) z * , r 1 { 0 } K . Then, the following multifunction:
F : { W K W P c ( X ) , sup z * ( W ) > 0 } S ( V E P ) z * , r 1 W K
is l.s.c. with respect to the weak Painlevé–Kuratowski convergence.
Remark 2. 
S ( V E P ) z * , r 1 { 0 } K does hold if S ( V E P ) r 1 { 0 } K .
Proof of the Theorem 14. 
Let us suppose that S is not l.s.c. at W 0 . Then, there exists x 0 S ( V E P ) z * , r 1 W 0 K , V V ( 0 ) , W n K w P K W 0 K such that:
( x 0 + V ) S ( V E P ) z * , r 1 W n K = , n I N .
Let us denote sup z * ( W n ) = ε n for n I N . We observe that ε n ε 0 implies that S ( V E P ) z * , r 1 W n K S ( V E P ) z * , r 1 W 0 K , which implies that ( x 0 + V ) S ( V E P ) z * , r 1 W 0 K is empty, which is false. Thus, for each n, ε n < ε 0 .
Let x S ( V E P ) z * , r 1 K . Since lim ε n = ε 0 , there exists n 0 I N such that ε 0 ε n 0 > 0 and ε n 0 ε 0 x 0 + ε 0 ε n 0 ε 0 x x 0 + V . We have z * F ( x 0 , y ) sup z * ( W 0 ) + I R + , for all y A , z * F ( x , y ) I R + , y A and F ( · , y ) is K-concave, which implies:
z * F ( ε n 0 ε 0 x 0 + ε 0 ε n 0 ε 0 x , y ) ε n 0 + I R + , y A .
Hence ( x 0 + V ) S ( V E P ) z * , r 1 W n 0 K , which is false. □
Similarly, we obtain the following theorems.
Theorem 15. 
Let z * Z + * { 0 } and suppose that F ( · , y ) is K-convex for each y A and S ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 { 0 } K . Then, the following multifunction:
F : { W K W P c ( X ) , sup z * ( W ) > 0 } S ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 W K
is l.s.c. with respect to the weak Painlevé–Kuratowski convergence.
Theorem 16. 
Let z * Z + * { 0 } and suppose that F ( · , y ) is K-convex for each y A and S ( V E P ) z * , r 2 { 0 } K . Then, the multifunction:
F : { W K W P c ( X ) , sup z * ( W ) > 0 } S ( V E P ) z * , r 2 W K
is l.s.c. with respect to the weak Painlevé–Kuratowski convergence.
Theorem 17. 
Let z * Z + * { 0 } and suppose that F ( · , y ) is K-concave for each y A and S ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 2 { 0 } K . Then, the multifunction:
F : { W K W P c ( X ) , sup z * ( W ) > 0 } S ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 2 W K
is l.s.c. with respect to the weak Painlevé–Kuratowski convergence.
II.
The continuity with respect to z * .
Theorem 18. 
Let us suppose that A is a convex set, Z is a normed space, F ( · , y ) is K concave, F ( A , A ) is a bounded subset of Z, and S ( V E P ) r 1 { 0 } K is nonempty. Then, for a constant c > 0 , the multifunction:
G : { z * Z + * sup z * ( W 0 ) = c } S ( V E P ) z * , r 1 W 0 K
is l.s.c. with respect to the norm topology.
Proof. 
Since S ( V E P ) r 1 { 0 } K , we get S ( V E P ) z * , r 1 { 0 } K , z * Z + * { 0 } . Let us suppose that G is not l.s.c. at z 0 * . Thus, x 0 S ( V E P ) z * , r 1 { 0 } K and V V ( 0 ) , z n * z 0 * , z n * Z + * such that:
( x 0 + V ) S ( V E P ) z n * , r 1 W 0 K = , n I N .
Since F is l.s.c. at W 0 , we find W 1 { W W = W K ; sup z * ( W ) > 0 } such that:
( x 0 + V ) S ( V E P ) z 0 * , r 1 W 1 K .
Let x ( x 0 + V ) S ( V E P ) z 0 * , r 1 W 1 K . We prove that there exists n 0 I N such that x ( x 0 + V ) S ( V E P ) z n 0 * , r 1 W 0 K , which is false.
Let n 0 such that z n 0 * z 0 * < sup z 0 * ( W 1 ) sup z 0 * ( W 0 ) sup { z , z F ( A , A ) } = μ . Since x S ( V E P ) z 0 * , r 1 W 1 K , we have z 0 * F ( x , y ) sup z 0 * ( W 1 ) + I R + . For each z F ( A , A ) we have | z n 0 ( z ) z 0 * ( z ) | μ sup { z , z F ( A , A ) } = α = sup z 0 * ( W 1 ) sup z 0 * ( W 0 ) . We get z n 0 * F ( x , y ) z 0 * F ( x , y ) + [ α , α ] sup z * ( W 1 ) + [ α , α ] + I R + sup z 0 * ( W 0 ) + I R + sup z n 0 * ( W 0 ) + I R + . Hence, x ( x 0 + V ) S ( V E P ) z n 0 * , r 1 W 0 K , which is false. □
In the same manner, we can prove the following theorems.
Theorem 19. 
Let us suppose that A is a convex set,  F ( · , y ) is K concave, F ( A , A ) is a bounded subset of Z, and S ( V E P ) r ¯ 2 { 0 } K . Then, the multifunction G : { z * Z + * sup z * ( W 0 ) = c } S ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 2 W 0 K is l.s.c. with respect to the norm topology.
Theorem 20. 
Let us suppose that A is a convex set, F ( · , y ) is K convex, F ( A , A ) is a bounded subset of Z, and S ( V E P ) r ¯ 1 { 0 } K . Then, the multifunction G : { z * Z + * sup z * ( W 0 ) = c } S ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 W 0 K is l.s.c. with respect to the norm topology.
Theorem 21. 
Let us suppose that A is a convex set, F ( · , y ) is K convex, F ( A , A ) is a bounded subset of Z, and S ( V E P ) r 2 { 0 } K . Then, the multifunction G : { z * Z + * sup z * ( W 0 ) = c } S ( V E P ) z * , r 2 W 0 K is l.s.c. with respect to the norm topology.
Remark 3. 
The assumptions from the previous theorems provide the following proprieties:
(i) 
If W n K w P K W 0 K , then S ( V E P ) z * , r i W 0 K Li S ( V E P ) z * , r i W n K ;
(ii) 
If W n K w P K W 0 K , then S ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ i W 0 K Li S ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ i W n K ;
(iii) 
If z n * z 0 * 0 , then S ( V E P ) z 0 * , r i W 0 K Li S ( V E P ) z n * , r i W 0 K ;
(iv) 
If z n * z 0 * 0 , then S ( V E P ) z 0 * , r ¯ i W 0 K Li S ( V E P ) z n * , r ¯ i W 0 K .
Now, we are able to present the connectedness result for the solutions set S ( V E P ) r ¯ 1 cl ( W Z + { 0 } ) . Let us denote M * = { z * Z + * sup z * ( W 0 ) = c > 0 } and M # = { z * Z + # sup z * ( W 0 ) = c > 0 } .
Theorem 22. 
Let us suppose that A is a convex set,  Z + # and F ( x , · ) has K-convex values for each x A , F ( · , y ) is K concave for each y A , F ( A , A ) Z is bounded and S ( V E P ) r 1 { 0 } K . Then, S ( V E P ) r ¯ 1 W K { 0 } and S ( V E P ) r ¯ 2 cl ( W K { 0 } ) are connected sets for K = Z + or K = qri Z + { 0 } .
Proof. 
Following Theorem 13, we have:
z * Z + # S ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 W K { 0 } S ( V E P ) r ¯ 1 W Z + { 0 } z * Z + * { 0 } S ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 W K { 0 } .
Let x be an element in S ( V E P ) r ¯ 1 W Z + { 0 } ; there exists z * Z + * { 0 } such that x S ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 W K { 0 } . If we consider u * = c z * sup z * ( W ) we have sup u * ( W ) = c and x S ( V E P ) u * , r ¯ 1 W K { 0 } . Thus:
z * M # S ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 W K { 0 } S ( V E P ) r ¯ 1 W Z + { 0 } z * M * S ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 W K { 0 }
Following Theorem 18, we have:
z * M * S ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 W K { 0 } = cl ( z * M # S ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 W K { 0 } ) .
Since S ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 W K { 0 } is convex and S ( V E P ) r 1 { 0 } K S ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 W K { 0 } for each z * , we obtain that z * M # S ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 W K { 0 } and S ( V E P ) r ¯ 1 W Z + { 0 } are connected sets. Similarly, we obtain the connectedness of S ( V E P ) r ¯ 2 cl ( W Z + { 0 } ) . □
Using the results from this section, the following theorems give the link between the sequence of the solutions sets for a sequence of multifunctions and the solutions set for the limit of this sequence. Let F n , F : A × A Z ; we say that F n is weakly continuous Painlevé–Kuratowski convergent to F and we write F n w c P K F if for x n x , z * F n ( x n , A ) is Painlevé–Kuratowski convergent to z * F ( x , A ) for each z * Z + * { 0 } .
Theorem 23. 
For n I N , let F n w c P K F and W n K { 0 } is weakly Painlevé–Kuratowski convergent to W { 0 } . Then, the following inclusion:
Li S F n ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 W n K { 0 } S F ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 W K { 0 }
does hold for K { 0 } { qi Z + , int Z + } (if nonempty) and z * Z + * { 0 } , respectively, for K { 0 } { qri Z + , Z + } and z * Z + # { 0 } .
If in addition we have K = qi Z + { 0 } , Z + # , and F ( x , · ) is K-convexlike on A, for each x A , F ( · , y ) is K concave and for each y A , F ( A , A ) is a bounded subset of Z and S ( V E P ) r 1 K , then we have:
Li S F n ( V E P ) W n C { 0 } S F ( V E P ) r ¯ 1 W K { 0 } ,
for C { qi Z + { 0 } , qri Z + { 0 } , Z + } .
Proof. 
Obviously, if K { 0 } = qi Z + or K { 0 } = int Z + and z * Z + * { 0 } (respectively, if K { 0 } = qri Z + , or Z + and z * Z + # ) and x S F ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 W K { 0 } , then 0 M I N sup z * ( W ) z * F ( x , A ) .
The hypothesis from the theorem and Proposition 3.1 [21] ensure that if x n S F n ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 W n K { 0 } and x n x , then:
Ls M I N sup z * ( W n ) z * F n ( x n , A ) M I N sup z * ( W ) z * F ( x , A )
which implies that 0 M I N sup z * ( W ) z * F ( x , A ) and x S F ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 W K { 0 } . Thus:
Li S F n ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 W n K { 0 } S F ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 W K { 0 } .
For the second part of the theorem, let us remark that we also have:
Ls S F n ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 W n K { 0 } S F ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 W K { 0 }
and
Li z * Z + * { 0 } S F n ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 W n K { 0 } z * Z + * { 0 } Ls S F n ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 W n K { 0 }
z * Z + * { 0 } S F ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 W K { 0 } .
Thus, for K { 0 } = qi Z + or K { 0 } = int Z + , we have:
Li S F n ( V E P ) W n K { 0 } S F ( V E P ) r ¯ 1 W K { 0 } .
Since Li A n = Li cl ( A n ) , the inclusions A n B n cl ( A n ) implies that Li A n = Li B n . Following Theorem 22 and the inclusion:
Li z * M # S F n ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 W n K { 0 } z * M # S F ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 W K { 0 }
we get:
Li S F n ( V E P ) W n Z + { 0 } S F ( V E P ) r ¯ 1 W Z + { 0 }
and:
Li S F n ( V E P ) W n qri Z + S F ( V E P ) r ¯ 1 W qri Z + .
Remark 4. 
Similarly, we obtain the previous theorem for the solutions set with respect to r ¯ 2 . Furthermore, if we take F n = F , Theorems 14 and 23 give that if F ( · , y ) is K-concave for each y A and S ( V E P ) z * , r 1 { 0 } K for K = qi Z + { 0 } , z * Z + * { 0 } then:
Li S F ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 W n K { 0 } = S F ( V E P ) z * , r ¯ 1 W K { 0 } .
This equality also holds if K = qri Z + { 0 } or K = Z + and z * Z + # .
Closing conditions for the solutions set.
Theorem 24. 
Let F : A × A Z and let W Z and K such that ( W K { 0 } ) c is closed. If F is lower semicontinuous then S ( V E P ) r ¯ 1 W K { 0 } is closed. If F is upper semicontinuous and F has compact values then S ( V E P ) r ¯ 2 W K { 0 } is closed.
Proof. 
Let ( x n ) n S ( V E P ) r ¯ 1 W K { 0 } and x n x . If F is lower semicontinuous, since F ( x , y , t ) Li F ( x n , y , t ) ( W K { 0 } ) c , we get that x S ( V E P ) r ¯ 1 W K { 0 } .
If F is upper semicontinuous, for all α n F ( x n , y , t ) ( W K { 0 } ) c there exists α F ( x , y , t ) and ( α n k ) k a subsequence of α n such that α n k α . Since ( W K { 0 } ) c is closed we get α F ( x , y , t ) ( W K { 0 } ) c , which implies that x S ( V E P ) r ¯ 2 W K { 0 } . □

5. Applications for Abstract Economies

An abstract economy is a family of ordered triples Γ = ( X i , A i , P i ) i I where:
  • I is countable set of agents;
  • X i Z is a nonempty set of actions for agent i, X = i I X i ;
  • A i : X X i is the constraint correspondence of agent i;
  • P i : X X i is the preference correspondence of agent i.
An equilibrium of Γ is a point x * X such that i I , x i * cl A i ( x * ) and P i ( x * ) A i ( x * ) = . Let us denote ψ i ( x ) = A i ( x ) P i ( x ) for all x X .
Let us recall some notions which will be useful for our results.
Definition 1. 
 
(i) 
A multifunction F : X Z has lower open section (shortly los), if for any z Z , the set { x X z F ( x ) } is open in Z. The multifunction F has upper open section (uos) if for all x X , the set F ( x ) is open in Z.
(ii) 
The multifunction F is L -majorized if there exists a multifunction F ˜ such that F ˜ has los, x conv F ˜ ( x ) and F ( x ) F ˜ ( x ) , x X .
The following notions generalize the “open lower sections” (ols) multifunctions and are motivated by the equilibrium existence theorem for abstract economies where the preference and the constraint multifunctions are not continuous.
Definition 2
([24]). The multifunction F : X Z has the “continuous inclusion property” (CIP) at x if there exist an open neighborhood U x of x and a nonempty multifunction H x : U x Z such that F x ( u ) F ( u ) for any u U x and co H x has closed graph.
Definition 3
([25]). Let M , S : A X ; the multifunction S is M-majorized if there exists a multifunction S ˜ such that S ( x ) S ˜ ( x ) M ( x ) , for all x A , S ˜ has the CIP property for each x dom S and x co S ˜ ( x ) .
We denote by M ( S ) the set of multifunctions M : A X such that S is M-majorized. A multifunction S : A X is M-majorized if M ( S ) .
The following theorem from [26] gives an existence result for the equilibrium of an abstract economy.
Theorem 25
([26]). Let Γ = ( X i , A i , P i ) i I be an abstract economy such that for each i I :
(i) 
X i is a nonempty compact convex metrizable subset of Z;
(ii) 
A i has nonempty convex values;
(iii) 
The correspondence cl A i is upper semicontinuous;
(iv) 
A i has open lower section;
(v) 
P i has open lower section;
(vi) 
x i co ψ i ( x ) for all x X .
Then, Γ has an equilibrium.
This theorem can be obtained from the Theorem 2 by taking the following particular sets and multifunctions: A = X i , T ( x ) = { x } , K ( x ) = A i ( x ) , F ( x , y ) = y if y P i ( x ) and F ( x , y ) = if y P i ( x ) . The sets N t , x i , W = ψ i ( x ) , and N y i , W = ( P i 1 ( y ) ) c = { x A t T ( x ) , r i ( F ( x , y , t ) , W ) } . Thus, (ii), (iii), and (iv) are equivalent with (iii) from Theorem 2; (v) is equivalent with (ii); and the condition (vi) is equivalent with (i) from the same theorem. Furthermore, we remark that the hypothesis “metrizable” can be omitted.
Theorem 25 generalizes the following result from [27], which in turn was generalized in [24].
Theorem 26
([27]). Let Γ = ( X i , A i , P i ) i I be an abstract economy such that for each i I :
(i) 
X i is a nonempty compact convex subset of I R n ;
(ii) 
A i has nonempty convex compact values;
(iii) 
A i is a continuous correspondence;
(iv) 
P i has an open graph;
(v) 
x i co ψ i ( x ) for all x X .
Then, Γ has an equilibrium.
The following theorem gives a generalization for the case of functions with the CIP property.
Theorem 27
([24]). Let Γ = ( X i , A i , P i ) i I be an abstract economy such that for each i I :
(i) 
X i is a nonempty compact convex metrizable subset of a Hausdorff locally convex space;
(ii) 
A i has nonempty convex values;
(iii) 
The correspondence cl A i is upper semicontinuous;
(iv) 
ψ has CIP at each x X with ψ i ( x ) ;
(v) 
x i co ψ i ( x ) for all x X .
Then, Γ has an equilibrium.
This theorem is based on the following fixed-point theorem.
Theorem 28
([24]). Let X be a nonempty compact convex metrizable subset of a Hausdorff locally convex space and ψ : X X be a correspondence which is nonempty convex valued and has the CIP property. Then, there exists a point x * X such that x * ψ ( x * ) .
Theorem 27 suggests a generalization for the existence theorem for the (VEPs) with multifunctions with the CIP property. The result concerning the existence of equilibrium for the abstract economies may be obtained as a particular case.
Lemma 1. 
Let G , H : A A , E A be a closed set and for each x A , G ( x ) H ( x ) and G has the CIP property at x dom G . Then, the multifunction Q : A A , Q ( x ) = G ( x ) for x E and Q ( x ) = H ( x ) if x A E has the CIP property at x dom Q .
Theorem 29. 
Let X be a Hausdorff topological space and A X be a nonempty compact convex set, and we suppose:
(i) 
co Φ has CIP at each x X with Φ ( x ) , where Φ : A X is given by Φ ( x ) = { y A cl K ( x ) t T ( x ) , r ¯ i ( F ( x , y , t ) , W ) } ;
(ii) 
x co Φ ( x ) , for all x X ;
(iii) 
cl K ( · ) is u.s.c. x A , A cl K ( x ) , K ( x ) is convex x A .
Then, ( V E P 1 ) r i W has a solution.
Proof. 
Let E = { y A y cl K ( y ) } and Q : A A be a multifunction given by Q ( x ) = co Φ ( x ) if x E and Q ( x ) = A cl K ( x ) for x A E . We observe that E is closed since cl K is u.s.c. and for each x A , Q ( x ) is convex, x Q ( x ) and lemma implies that Q has CIP. Following Theorem 35 we get x ¯ A such that Q ( x ¯ ) = . Since A cl K ( x ) for all x A we get x ¯ E , and thus, co Φ ( x ¯ ) = . The conclusion follows now obviously. □
Let us remark that if A = X i , T ( x ) = { x } , K ( x ) = A i ( x ) , F ( x , y ) = y if y P i ( x ) and F ( x , y ) = if y P i ( x ) , then Φ = ψ and this theorem becomes Theorem 27 of Yannelis and He for abstract economies.
Furthermore, let us remark that Φ ( x ) = t T ( x ) N ¯ t , x i , W and N y i , W = ( Φ 1 ( y ) ) c from Theorem 2; the assumptions of Theorem 2 provide that Φ has los, and thus, Φ and co Φ have CIP.
The existence Theorem 29 may be generalized for M -majorized multifunctions as follows.
Theorem 30. 
Let X be a Hausdorff topological space, A X be a nonempty compact convex set and we suppose:
(i) 
Φ : A X , Φ = { y A cl K ( x ) t T ( x ) , r ¯ i ( F ( x , y , t ) , W ) } is M -majorized and A cl K ( · ) M ( Φ ) ;
(ii) 
cl K ( · ) is u.s.c.; x A , A cl K ( x ) , K ( x ) is convex; x A .
Then, ( V E P 1 ) r i W has a solution.
Proof. 
Let us denote by Φ ˜ the multifunction which has the CIP property for each x dom S , x co S ˜ ( x ) and Φ ( x ) Φ ˜ ( x ) A cl K ( x ) . The proof is similar to that of Theorem 29 by replacing Φ with Φ ˜ . □
For the case of a noncompact set of actions, we have from [28] the following theorem for the existence of an equilibrium for an abstract economy.
Theorem 31
([28]). Let Γ = ( X i , A i , P i ) i I be an abstract economy such that for each i I :
(i) 
X i is a nonempty convex metrizable subset of Z;
(ii) 
A i ( x ) is a nonempty convex set for all x X ;
(iii) 
The correspondence cl A i is upper semicontinuous and cl A i ( x ) is compact for all x X ;
(iv) 
A i has an open lower section;
(v) 
P i has an open lower section;
(vi) 
x i co ψ i ( x ) for all x X .
(vii) 
There exists C i X i , nonempty, compact, convex sets such that:
A i ( C ) D i , where C = i I C i , D i X i is compact and convex;
A i ( x ) Z i , x X i × Z i , Z i = cl co ( D i C i ) ;
x i Z i C i , x i X i , there exists y i A i ( x ) Z i P i ( x ) .
Then, Γ has an equilibrium.
In what follows, we present a similar result for the case of correspondence with the CIP property which extends to noncompact case Theorem 2 from [24].
Theorem 32. 
Let Γ = ( X i , A i , P i ) i I be an abstract economy such that for each i I
(i) 
X i is a nonempty convex metrizable subset of Z;
(ii) 
A i ( x ) is a nonempty convex set for all x X ;
(iii) 
The correspondence cl A i is upper semicontinuous and cl A i ( x ) is compact for all x X ;
(iv) 
ψ i has CIP;
(v) 
x i co ψ i ( x ) for all x X .
(vi) 
There exists C i X i , nonempty, compact, convex sets such that:
A i ( C ) D i , where C = × i I C i , D i X i is compact and convex;
A i ( x ) Z i , x X i × Z i , Z i = cl co ( D i C i ) ;
x i Z i C i , x i X i , there exists y i A i ( x ) Z i P i ( x ) .
Then, Γ has an equilibrium.
Proof. 
Let T = i I Z i and for each i I , K i : T Z i , K i ( x ) = A i ( x ) Z i , x T . Since cl A i has closed graph, T , Z i are compact sets, then cl K i has closed graph, compact values, and thus, cl K i is u.s.c.
We remark that K i ( x ) = A i ( x ) , x i C i and K i ( x ) = A i ( x ) Z i , otherwise. Let Gr P ˜ i = cl Gr P i . We remark that ψ ˜ i ( x ) = K i P ˜ i ( x ) = A i ( x ) P ˜ i ( x ) Z i has a closed graphic, which implies that ψ ˜ i has the CIP property.
The abstract economy Γ ˜ : ( Z i , K i , P ˜ i T ) i I satisfies the conditions from Theorem 2 [24], and thus, there exists x ¯ cl K i ( x ¯ ) and P ˜ i ( x ¯ ) K i ( x ) = which yields P i ( x ¯ ) K i ( x ¯ ) = , and thus, x ¯ C i , cl K i ( x ¯ ) = cl A i ( x ¯ ) . We conclude x ¯ cl A i ( x ¯ ) , P i ( x ¯ ) A i ( x ¯ ) = , and thus, x ¯ is an equilibrium for Γ . □
In what follows, we present some results concerning the existence for the Walrasian equilibrium in a vector exchange economy.
A vector exchange economy, E is a family ( X i , P i , e i ) i I such that I is a finite set of agents and for every i I :
  • X i Z + is the consumption set of agent i and X = i I X i ;
  • An element x i X i will be called an allocation for agent il;
  • P i : X X i is the preference correspondence of agent i;
  • e i X i is the initial endowment of agent i.
We suppose that Z + * has a compact base B + * .
The budget set of agent i is B i ( z * ) = { x i X i z * ( x i ) z * ( e i ) } for z * B + * . For z * B + * , x X , i I , let ψ i ( z * , x ) = B i ( z * ) P i ( x ) , the set of allocations in the budget set of agent i at price z * that he prefers to x.
A free disposal Walrasian equilibrium for the exchange economy E is ( z ¯ * , x ¯ ) B + * × X such that:
  • For each i I , x ¯ i B i ( z ¯ * ) and ψ i ( z ¯ * , x ¯ ) = ;
  • i I x ¯ i i I e i .
Theorem 33. 
Let E be an exchange economy satisfying the following assumptions for each i I :
(i) 
X i is a nonempty compact convex subset of Z + ;
(ii) 
For all ( z * , x ) ( B + * × X ) dom ψ i , x i co ψ i ( z * , x ) and ψ is M -majorized at ( z * , x ) .
Then, E has a free disposal Walrasian equilibrium.
Proof. 
Let I 0 = I { 0 } and for each i I , z * B + * , x X , let:
A i ( z * , x ) = B + * × B i ( z * )
P ˜ i ( z * , x ) = B + * × P i ( x )
and for A 0 ( z * , x ) = B + * × X :
P ˜ 0 ( z * , x ) = { q * B + * q i * ( i I ( x i e i ) ) > z * ( i I ( x i e i ) ) } × X .
Since i I 0 , A i are nonempty convex valued, u.s.c. on B + * × X . For i I , ψ ˜ i ( z * , x ) = A i ( z * , x ) P ˜ i ( z * , x ) = B + * × ( B i ( z * ) P i ( x ) ) = B + * × ψ i ( z * , x ) and since ψ is M -majorized so is ψ ˜ .
For i = 0 :
ψ ˜ 0 ( z * , x ) = A 0 ( z * , x ) P ˜ 0 ( z * , x ) = P ˜ 0 ( z * , x ) =
= { q * B + * q * ( i I ( x i e i ) ) > z * ( i I ( x i e i ) ) } × X .
For ( q * , v ) ψ ˜ 0 ( z * , x ) , let G ( z * , x ) = ( q * , v ) which is a constant, and thus, a continuous multifunction. There exists O V ( z * , x ) such that G ( z * , x ) ψ ˜ 0 ( z * , x ) for each ( z * , x ) O , which implies that ψ ˜ 0 has CIP, and thus, ψ ˜ 0 is M -majorized.
For the abstract economy ( B + * × X i , A i , P ˜ i ) i I 0 , we may apply Theorem 30 and we get ( z ¯ * , x ¯ ) B + * × X such that ( z ¯ * , x ¯ i ) A i ( z ¯ * , x ¯ ) = B + * × B i ( z ¯ * ) and ψ ˜ ( z ¯ * , x ¯ ) = for each i I 0 . Thus, for i I , ψ ( z ¯ * , x ¯ ) = .
Since ψ ˜ 0 ( z ¯ * , x ¯ ) = , for each q * B + * , we have:
q * ( i I ( x i e i ) ) z * ( i I ( x i e i ) ) 0
and finally, i I ( x i e i ) 0 . Therefore, ( z ¯ * , x ¯ ) is a free disposal Walrasian equilibrium. □
In what follows, we present a result concerning the existence of a nonfree disposal Walrasian equilibrium.
Let us denote B i ( z * ) = { x i X i z * ( x i ) z * ( e i ) + 1 z * } for z * B + * , ψ ( z * , x ) = P i ( x ) B i ( z * ) and K = { x X i I x i = i I e i } .
A nonfree disposal Walrasian equilibrium is an element ( z ¯ * , x ¯ ) B + * × X such that:
  • For each i I , x ¯ B i ( z ¯ * ) , ψ i ( z ¯ * , x ¯ ) = ;
  • i I x ¯ i = i I e i .
Theorem 34. 
Let E be an exchange economy satisfying the following assumptions for each i I :
(i) 
X i is a nonempty compact convex subset of Z + ;
(ii) 
For each ( z * , x ) ( B + * × X ) dom ψ i we have x i co ψ i ( z * , x ) and ψ is M -majorized at ( z * , x ) .
(iii) 
x i pr i K implies that x i Fr P i ( x ) .
Then, E has a nonfree disposal Walrasian. equilibrium.
Proof. 
Similar to the first part of the proof in the case “free disposal”, we get ( z ¯ * , x ¯ ) B + * × X such that:
  • x ¯ i B i ( z ¯ * ) ;
  • ψ i ( z ¯ * , x ¯ ) = , i I 0 .
From 1, we obtain z ¯ * ( x ¯ i ) z * ( e i ) + 1 z * . Let z = i I ( x i e i ) and we suppose that z 0 . From 2, for i = 0 , we have q * ( z ) z ¯ * ( z ) for each q * B * . Let q * = 1 z ¯ * z ¯ * B + * ; we get z ¯ * ( z ) z z ¯ * ( z ) , which yields z ¯ * 1 and since z ¯ * B + * , we conclude that z ¯ * = 1 . Using 1, we obtain that z ¯ * ( z ) 0 , and thus, q * ( z ) 0 for each q * B + * . However, since z 0 , we find q * B + * such that q * ( z ) = q * > 0 , which is false. Thus, z = 0 and i I x ¯ i = i I e i , x ¯ K . Note that x ¯ i pr i K implies that x ¯ i Fr P i ( x ) . Since x ¯ i B i ( z ¯ * ) and x ¯ i co ψ i ( z ¯ * , x ¯ ) , x ¯ i P i ( x ¯ ) . If there exists i such that z ¯ * ( x ¯ i ) < z ¯ * ( e i ) + 1 z ¯ * , one can find a point y i P i ( x ¯ ) such that x ¯ i and y i are sufficiently close, and z ¯ * ( y i ) < z ¯ * ( e i ) + 1 z ¯ * . Thus, y i ψ i ( z ¯ * , x ¯ ) , which contradicts 2. Therefore, z ¯ * ( x ¯ i ) = z * ( e i ) + 1 z * for each i I , and summing up over all i yields z * = 1 . Finally, we conclude ( z ¯ * , x ¯ ) is a nonfree disposal Walrasian equilibrium. □
Let us remark that if Z = I R l , we get Theorems 3 and 4 from [24].
Finally, we remark that the notion of Walrasian equilibrium was extended for the case of a vector exchange economy with an infinite number of agents and commodities, both for the additive case and for the nonadditive one. For results concerning the existence of the Walrasian equilibrium and the core-Walras equivalence with linear and nonlinear prices, the reader may consult [29,30,31].

6. Applications of VEPs to the Vector Optimization Problems

In this section, we intend to find a vector optimization problem such that the solutions of the vector equilibrium problem are solutions for this vector optimization problem. Let F : A × A Z such that 0 F ( x , x ) and consider the problem ( V E P ) r ¯ 1 K :
( V E P ) r ¯ 1 K : find x A such that F ( x , y ) K = y A .
Let us recall the definition for the principal efficient points and the domination property which will be used in the following. For more details concerning this subject, see [32].
Let K Z + { 0 } , A Z , ε Z + . The following sets:
K I N F A = { y Z ¯ y a K , a A } ;
K I N F 1 A = { y K I N F A y Z ¯ , y y K , a A , y a K } ;
K M I N ε A = { a A ¬ a A , a a + ε K }
will be the K-infimal, the K-approximative infimal, and the K- ε minimal points sets of A, respectively. Similarly, we may consider the K-supremal, K-approximative supremal, and the K- ε maximal points sets of A denoted K S U P A , K S U P 1 A , and K M A X ε A .
We remark that if K = Z + { 0 } , the K-efficient points becomes the efficient points sets given in [33]. We will denoted these points by I N F A , I N F 1 A , and ε M I N A , respectively, M I N A if ε = { 0 } . If the interior of the cone is nonempty and K = int Z + , the K-efficient points are the weak efficiencies denoted w E F F A , i.e., w I N F A , w I N F 1 A , w ε M I N A , and w M I N A if ε = { 0 } , respectively.
In what follows, the efficient points are considered by respect to the cone K Z + which ensure that the following domination property does holds.
Theorem 35. 
Let A Z , K = ri A , iri A , int A and X = cone ( Z + x ) , x K . Let us denote B = { a A K I N F A ( a + X ) } and let us suppose that B . Then, K I N F 1 A A + X and the following domination properties hold:
B K I N F 1 A + K
K I N F A ( B + X ) = ( K I N F 1 A K ) .
Obviously, if x is a solution for ( V E P ) then x is a solution for the optimization problem ( P x ) :
( P x ) : K I N F 1 y A F ( x , y ) = K I N F 1 y A F x ( y ) = v ( P x )
The dual problem is ( D x ) :
K S U P 1 T L ( X , Z ) F x * A ( T ) = v ( D x ) ,
where F x * A ( T ) = K S U P 1 { T ( y ) F x ( y ) y A } .
We say that P x is stable if v ( ( P x ) ) = v ( ( D x ) ) = K M A X ( D x ) .
Let us consider now the perturbed problem:
( P a ( F ) ) K I N F 1 { Φ ( y , u ) , y X }
where Φ ( y , u ) = F x ( y + u ) if y + u A and Φ ( y , u ) = + else. We have Φ * ( 0 , T ) = S U P 1 { F x * A ( T ) + { T ( y ) y A } } . The dual problem is:
( D a ( F ) ) K S U P 1 T L ( X , Z ) Φ * ( 0 , T ) .
Let us denote γ ( x ) = T L ( X , Z ) K I N F 1 { F x * A ( T ) + { T ( y ) y A } } .
Let us consider the vector equilibrium problem ( V E P ) r 2 W K .
( V E P ) r 2 W K : find x A such that F ( x , y ) W K { 0 } , y A .
We denote F ( x , y ) = G ( x , y ) and W = W and the problem becomes:
( V E P G ) r 2 W + K : find x A such that G ( x , y ) W + K { 0 } y A .
We remark that if x is a solution for ( V E P ) r 2 W K , then x is a solution for the problems:
( I V E P ) r 2 W ε + K { 0 } find x A such that K I N F 1 y A G ( x , y ) W ε + K { 0 }
for all ε K { 0 } . We consider the dual problem for α W :
( P α ) K S U P 1 u A γ ( u )
where γ ( u ) = T L ( X , Z ) K I N F 1 { G x * A ( T ) + { T ( y ) y A } } .
The element x is a solution for ( P α ) if there exists z γ ( x ) such that ( K S U P 1 u A γ ( u ) ) ( z + α + K ) = . We denote the set of these solutions by S ( P α ) . Let us remark that if x S ( P α ) , then ( u A γ ( u ) ) ( z + α + K ) = and thus γ ( x ) K M A X α u A γ ( u ) , that is:
x is an α solution for ( P ) : K M A X α u A γ ( u ) .
Theorem 36. 
If ( P a ( G ) ) is stable, then there exists α W such that for all α > α we have:
S ( V E P ) r 2 W K S ( P α ) .
Proof. 
Let x S ( V E P ) r 2 W K . Thus, I N F 1 y A G ( x , y ) W ε + K { 0 } . If ( P a ( G ) ) is stable, then K I N F 1 y A G ( x , y ) = K M A X γ ( x ) . Since 0 F ( x , x ) , then for all z ( K I N F 1 y A G ( x , y ) ) = K M A X γ ( x ) , z 0 . Furthermore, following the domination property, there exists z 0 K I N F 1 y A G ( x , y ) = M A X γ ( x ) such that z 0 < 0 and there exists α W such that α ε < z 0 < 0 . We remark that for all z K M A X γ ( u ) = K I N F 1 y A G ( u , y ) , z 0 .
( u A K M A X γ ( u ) ) ( z 0 + α + ε + K ) =
since z 0 + α + ε > 0 . The conclusion follows obviously. □
Let us consider the vector equilibrium problem ( V E P ) r 1 W K { 0 } :
( V E P ) r 1 W K { 0 } : find x A such that F ( x , y ) ( W K { 0 } ) , y A .
Moreover, let us consider the problem ( I V E P ) r 1 W + K { 0 } :
( I V E P ) r 1 W + K { 0 } : find x A such that W K I N F y A F ( x , y ) W + K { 0 } .
This relation is equivalent with the following conditions: K I N F 1 y A F ( x , y ) ( W + K { 0 } ) and W K I N F y A F ( x , y ) . We remark that S ( I V E P ) r 1 W + K { 0 } S ( V E P ) r 1 W K { 0 } .
We consider the dual problem:
( P α ) K S U P 1 u A γ ( u )
γ ( u ) = T L ( X , Z ) K I N F 1 { F x * A ( T ) + { T ( y ) y A } } .
An element x is a solution for ( P α ) if there exists z γ ( x ) such that ( K S U P 1 u A γ ( u ) ) ( z α + K { 0 } ) = . We denote the set of these solutions by S ( P α ) . Let us remark that if z S ( P α ) then:
z α K S U P ( K S U P 1 u A γ ( u ) ) = K S U P u A γ ( u )
so z M A X α u A γ ( u ) , i.e., x is a solution for ( P ) .
Theorem 37. 
If ( P a ( F ) ) is stable, then there exists α W such that:
S ( I V E P ) r 1 W + K { 0 } S ( P α )
S ( V E P ) r 1 W K { 0 } S ( P α )
Proof. 
If x S ( I V E P ) r 1 W + K { 0 } , then there exists z 0 K I N F 1 y A F ( x , y ) = K M A X γ ( x ) (since ( P a ( F ) ) is stable) and α W such that z 0 α > 0 . If we suppose ( K S U P 1 u A γ ( u ) ) ( z 0 α + K { 0 } ) we have z K M A X γ ( u ) , z > z 0 α > 0 , which is false. Since S ( I V E P ) r 1 W + K { 0 } ( V E P ) r 1 W K { 0 } , we get the conclusion. □

7. Conclusions

We present a unified approach for the vector equilibrium problems in the case of the ordering cone with nonempty quasi-interior or relative interior (possible with empty interior). In this case, some results concerning the existence of the solutions for a vector equilibrium problem are given and are applied to obtain conditions of existence for equilibrium in an abstract economy and for Walrasian equilibrium in a vector exchange economy. Several properties concerning the continuity and the connectedness for the solutions set are obtained. Some applications of this study in other domains, such as vector optimization problems and vector duality, are also given. Optimality results, linear and nonlinear scalarization characterization, as well as algorithm methods remain topics for future research.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Data Availability Statement

Data are contained within the article.

Conflicts of Interest

The author declares no conflicts of interest.

References

  1. Blum, L.; Oettli, W. From optimization and vector variational inequalities to equilibrium problems. Math. Stud. 1994, 63, 123–145. [Google Scholar]
  2. Altangerel, L.; Boţ, R.I.; Wanka, G. Variational Primciples for Vector Equilibrium Problem Related to Conjugate Duality. J. Nonlinear Convex Anal. 2007, 135, 179–196. [Google Scholar]
  3. Capătxax, A. Existence Theorems for Vector Equilibrium Problems via Quasi Relative Interior. Sci. J. 2013, 2013, 150130. [Google Scholar]
  4. Gong, X.H. Optimality Conditions for Vector Equilibrium Problems. J. Math. Annal. Appl. 2008, 342, 455–466. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Hai, N.X.; Khanh, P.Q. The existence of ε-solutions to General Quasiequilibrium Problems. Vietnam J. Math. 2007, 35, 563–572. [Google Scholar]
  6. Han, Y.; Huang, N.J. Some characterization of the approximate solutions for generalized vector optimization problems. J. Ind. Manag. Optim. 2016, 12, 1135–1151. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Lee, G.M.; Bu, I.J. On Vector Equilibrium Problems with Multifunctions. Taiwan. J. Math. 2006, 10, 399–407. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Lin, L.J.; Chen, L.F.; Ansari, Q.H. Generalized abstract economy and systems of generalized vector quasi equilibrium problem. J. Comp. Appl. Math. 2007, 208, 341–353. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Wang, S.; Li, Q.; Fu, J. Strong Vector Equilibrium Problems on Noncompact Sets. Bull. Malays. Sci. Soc. 2012, 35, 119–132. [Google Scholar]
  10. Ansari, Q.H.; Kobis, E.; Yao, J.C. Vector Equilibrium Problems in Vector Variational Inequalities and Vector Optimization; Springer: Cham, Switzerland, 2018. [Google Scholar]
  11. Dali, I.; Moustard, M.B. A new existence of Equilibria for VEP. Numer. Funct. Anal. Optim. 2023, 44, 11. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Fu, J.Y. Vector Equilibrium Problems. Existence theorems and convexity of solution set. J. Glob. 2007, 31, 109–119. [Google Scholar]
  13. Gong, X.H. Strong Vector Equilibrium Problems. J. Glob. Optim. 2006, 36, 339–349. [Google Scholar]
  14. Szilard, L. A primal-dual approach of weak VEP. Open Math. 2018, 16, 276–288. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Uderzo, A. Solution analysis for a class of set-inclusive generalized equations: A convex case approach. Pure Appl. Funct. Anal. 2020, 5, 769–790. [Google Scholar]
  16. Uderzo, A. Some enhanced existence results for strong VEP. arXiv 2022, arXiv:2205.05010v1. [Google Scholar]
  17. Alleche, B.; Radulescu, V. Further on Set-Valued Equilibrium Problems and Applications to Browder Variational Inclusions. JOTA 2017, 175, 39–58. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Uderzo, A. On the quatitative solution stability of parametrised set-valued inclusions. Set Valued Var. Anal. 2021, 29, 425–451. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Capătă, A. Optimality conditions for vector equilibrium problem and their applications. J. Ind. Manag. Optim. 2013, 9, 659–669. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Grad, S.; Pop, E. Vector Duality for Convex Vector Optimization Problems by Means of the Quasi-Interior of the Ordering Cone. Optimization 2014, 1, 21–37. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Durea, M. On the existence and stability of approximate solutions of perturbed vector equilibrium problems. J. Math. Annal. Appl. 2007, 333, 1165–1171. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Chen, B.; Liu, Q.; Liu, Z.; Huang, N. Connectedness of approximate solutions set vector equilibrium problems in Hausdorff topological vector spaces. Fixed Point Theory Appl. 2011, 2011, 36. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Tarafdar, E. A fixed point theorem equivalent to the Fan-Knaster-Kuratowski-Mazur-Mazurkiewicz theorem. J. Math. Annal. Appl. 1987, 198, 475–479. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. He, W.; Yannelis, N. Equilibrium Theory with Discontinuous Non-Ordered Preferences; University of Iowa, Mimeo Posted: Iowa City, IA, USA, 2014. [Google Scholar]
  25. Stamate, C. Equilibrium Theory for Abstract Economies with M-majorized multifunctions. In Proceedings of the CAIM 2017, Iasi, Romania, 14–17 September 2017. [Google Scholar]
  26. Yannelis, N.C.; Prabhakar, N.D. Existence of Maximal Elements and Equilibria in Linear Topological Spaces. J. Math. Anal. Appl. 1996, 197, 61–74. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Shafer, W.; Sonnenschein, H. Equilibrium in Abstract Economies Without Ordered Preferences. J. Math. Econ. 1975, 23, 345–348. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Tian, G. Equilibrium in Abstract Economies with Non-compact Infinite Dimensional Strategy Space, an Infinite Number of Agents and Without Ordered Preferences. Econ. Lett. 1990, 33, 203–206. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Rustichini, A.; Yannelis, N. Edgeworth’s Conjecture in Economies with a Continuum of Agents and Commodities. J. Math. Econ. 1991, 20, 307–326. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Sambucini, A.R. The Choquet Integral with Respect to Fuzzy Measures and Applications. Mat. Slovaca 2017, 67, 1427–1450. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Stamate, C. A general Pettis-Choquet type integral. In Proceedings of the CAIM 2019, Târgoviste, Romania, 19–22 September 2019. [Google Scholar]
  32. Stamate, C. About the weak efficiencies in vector optimization. Curr. Top. Math. Comput. Sci. 2022, 11, 408–420. [Google Scholar]
  33. Postolica, V. Vectorial Optimization Programs with Multifunctions and Duality. Ann. Sci. Math. Que. 1986, 10, 85–102. [Google Scholar]
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Stamate, C. Vector Equilibrium Problems—A Unified Approach and Applications. Mathematics 2024, 12, 1448. https://doi.org/10.3390/math12101448

AMA Style

Stamate C. Vector Equilibrium Problems—A Unified Approach and Applications. Mathematics. 2024; 12(10):1448. https://doi.org/10.3390/math12101448

Chicago/Turabian Style

Stamate, Cristina. 2024. "Vector Equilibrium Problems—A Unified Approach and Applications" Mathematics 12, no. 10: 1448. https://doi.org/10.3390/math12101448

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop