Next Article in Journal
Educational Differences in Smoking among Adolescents in Germany: What is the Role of Parental and Adolescent Education Levels and Intergenerational Educational Mobility?
Next Article in Special Issue
Measuring the Value of Mortality Risk Reductions in Turkey
Previous Article in Journal
Estimation of Chlorophyll-a Concentration in Turbid Lake Using Spectral Smoothing and Derivative Analysis
Previous Article in Special Issue
Assessing Local Communities’ Willingness to Pay for River Network Protection: A Contingent Valuation Study of Shanghai, China
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

The Impact of Health Insurance Programs on Out-of-Pocket Expenditures in Indonesia: An Increase or a Decrease?

1
Institute of Public Health, Faculty of Medicine, University of Heidelberg, Im Neuenheimer Feld 324, Heidelberg 69120, Germany
2
School of Public Health, Faculty of Medicine and Health Sciences, Jenderal Soedirman University, Kampus Karangwangkal, Purwokerto 53123, Indonesia
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2013, 10(7), 2995-3013; https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph10072995
Submission received: 30 April 2013 / Revised: 4 July 2013 / Accepted: 8 July 2013 / Published: 18 July 2013
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Health Economics)

Abstract

:
We used panel data from the Indonesian Family Life Survey to investigate the impact of health insurance programs on reducing out-of-pocket expenditures. We employed three linear panel data models, two of which accounted for endogeneity: pooled ordinary least squares (OLS), pooled two-stage least squares (2SLS) for instrumental variable (IV), and fixed effects (FE). The study revealed that two health insurance programs had a significantly negative impact on out-of-pocket expenditures by using IV estimates. In the IV model, Askeskin decreased out-of-pocket expenditures by 34% and Askes by 55% compared with non-Askeskin and non-Askes, respectively, while Jamsostek was found to bear a nonsignificant effect on out-of-pocket expenditures. In the FE model, only Askeskin had a significant negative effect with an 11% reduction on out-of-pocket expenditures. This study showed that two large existing health insurance programs in Indonesia, Askeskin and Askes, effectively reduced household out-of-pocket expenditures. The ability of programs to offer financial protection by reducing out-of-pocket expenditures is likely to be a direct function of their benefits package and co-payment policies.

1. Introduction

In the past two decades, several Asian countries, including Indonesia, have implemented social health insurance in the process of restructuring their health care financing systems and improving access to health services by reducing the price at point of use for medical services. Most studies from these developing countries found that health insurance had a positive impact on increasing health care utilization [1,2,3,4]. However, evidence on the adequacy of social health insurance in providing financial protection, by alleviating the burden of out-of-pocket spending, still appears contradictory. For example, the existing health insurance systems in China and India have shown limited success in reducing financial risk or in protecting households from catastrophic health spending [5,6]. Conversely, health insurance for the poor in Vietnam did reduce out-of-pocket spending [7,8]. One of the reasons for the conflicting evidence is the differences in the health insurance structures and the contexts in which they operate. This makes it necessary to investigate and evaluate insurance systems for their performance with respect to their targeted impacts in the pertinent settings [9]. To date, the health insurance and out-of-pocket payments nexus has become central to the debate on effective health care financing mechanisms [3,5,7,8].
In Indonesia, the health care financing system has been set up to include a mix of public and private financing, of which the latter still plays a dominant role. To a large extent, this has led to a fragmented and segmented health insurance structure. After the implementation of the Social Security Act in early 2005, Indonesia has three large health insurance schemes that differ in population coverage, benefits packages, and insurance agencies: namely Askes—for civil servants (introduced in 1968); Jamsostek—for private formal employees (introduced in 1992); and Askeskin—for poor people (introduced in 2005). This substantial development of the health insurance market obviously influenced subsequent demand for health services. Hidayat et al. [10] confirmed that both Askes and Jamsostek had a strong positive impact on increasing demand for outpatient care. Furthermore, the World Bank reported that after the implementation of Askeskin, the utilization rates for outpatient and inpatient care increased by nearly 50% [11]. These results are consistent with the argument that health insurance increases the demand for health services by reducing the costs at point of use. This phenomenon is known as “ex post moral hazard” [12].
The increasing demand for health services due to insurance raises a question as to whether it is also followed by increasing financial protection against the cost of illness among insured people. The purpose of health insurance is not only to tear down the barriers to the access of health services due to financial reasons, but also to ensure further financial protection [13]. Theoretically, health insurance should prevent excessive out-of-pocket expenditures. However, we postulate that supplier-induced demand may subvert the financial protection offered in principle by health insurance. This may occur as people who would have not reached the facilities in the absence of insurance are now encouraged by providers to use several treatments and procedures, still subject to copayments. This increased utilization and its link to existing supplier-induced demand may actually result in higher out-of-pocket expenditures and hence in an increased financial burden for those with a valid insurance [14]. Health insurance in Indonesia is potentially vulnerable to this supplier-induced demand, as by its own design, it lacks the infrastructure for utilization review, i.e., a mechanism to monitor what services and in what quantities are prescribed.
From a methodological prospective, a crucial aspect when assessing the effect of health insurance on health care expenditures is the problem of endogeneity [3,5,15,16]. Endogeneity refers to the fact that an explanatory variable is correlated with unobservables, relegated to the error term. Measurements of the impact of insurance on out-of-pocket expenditures without controlling for the problem of endogeneity may be misleading [5]. Several studies to date have adopted different econometric approaches to deal with these issues. Wagstaff [8] used difference-in-difference to measure the impact of the health care fund for poor people in Vietnam, and found that this program reduced out-of-pocket spending. Shaefer et al. [17] used an instrumental variable (IV) approach to examine the effect of transitions from private to public health insurance by children on out-of-pocket and insurance premium costs in the U.S. and found that these transitions offered a cash-equivalent transfer of nearly US$1,500 annually in the form of reduced spending. Moreover, Sepehri et al. [18] concluded that failure to capture endogeneity resulted in different study outcomes against the basic argument that health insurance eliminates excessive household financial expenditures on health care.
In view of the available evidence, this study aimed to investigate the effects of various health insurance schemes in Indonesia on reducing out-of-pocket expenditures, correcting for underlying endogeneity. We used panel household survey data gathered at four points in time points 1993 and 2007.

2. Health Insurance in Indonesia—Sources of Endogeneity

With approximately 237 million people in 2010, Indonesia is the 4th largest country in the World [19]. Its population is spread over five major islands and 30 small groups of islands, covering more than 17,000 individual islands. National public health expenditure has been rising gradually from 2001 to 2006, but the levels still remain below 1% of Gross Domestic Product (GDP) [20].
Table 1 provides summary characteristics of the three available health insurance schemes in relation to payment systems, health care provider network, and services covered [10,21]. Efforts to scale up health insurance in Indonesia have evolved substantially since the drafting of Law No. 40 in 2004, that ratified the National Social Security System. This law marked governmental commitment to reform the existing social protection system to advance universal coverage by promoting nation-wide social health insurance. By the first quarter in 2005, the government had already achieved remarkable progress in providing health insurance for the poor and vulnerable groups (Askeskin), funded through the public budget [21,22]. This program has gradually increased the number of insured people in Indonesia. A target of 36.1 million (17% of the total population) covered individuals was set for the first semester of 2005 and a higher target of 60 million for the second semester of the same year. By mid-2007, Askeskin was estimated to cover 76.4 million people [23].
The implementation of Askeskin caused nation-wide health insurance coverage to increase from 10% in 2005 to 48% of the total population in 2008 [21]. Askeskin includes non-contributory premiums and no cost sharing for all health benefits. However, this scheme does not include treatments categorized as luxury treatments.
Target Askeskin beneficiaries were identified on the basis of the poverty listing drawn by the Indonesian Bureau of Statistics. The national government allocated fixed quotas to districts, and districts had responsibility to identify the target beneficiaries. Targeting proved challenging, so that during the initial enrollment phase, a number of shortcomings was actually highlighted in Askeskin program. A rapid assessment report conducted by Bachtiar et al. [11] points out that Askeskin was sometimes allocated based on health status. Endogeneity in estimating the impact of Askeskin on financial protection may arise as sicker people might have self-selected into the scheme to benefit from its generous benefits package.
Table 1. Main features of the three health insurance schemes in Indonesia.
Table 1. Main features of the three health insurance schemes in Indonesia.
CharacteristicsHealth Insurance Schemes
AskesJamsostekAskeskin
Established196819922005
Population coverage14 million (about 6% of the population) in 20074.1 million (about 2% of the population) in 200976.4 million (about 34% of the population) in 2007
ParticipationMandatoryMandatory, opt-out option for employers that could provide better benefit plansSocial insurance
Organization/CarrierState-owned company (PT ASKES Indonesia)State-owned company (PT JAMSOSTEK Indonesia)Ministry of Health
BeneficiariesCivil servants, pensioners of civil servants and armed forcesFormal private employeeIdentified poor and near poor, based on individual and household targeting
Eligible dependentsSpouse and 2 oldest children <21 years of age (if unemployed, unmarried), or <25 years of age if a full-time studentSpouse and 3 oldest children <21 years of ageSpouse and children
Source of fundsMember contribution 2% of basic salary + contribution from government 2% of basic salaryMember contribution, if single: 3% of basic salary; member with dependents: 6% of basic salaryNo contribution from beneficiaries because it is tax-based with calculation for premium 6,000 IDR (0.46€) per capita
Benefits package and provider choiceOutpatient and inpatient care at public providers onlyOutpatient care at both public and private providers networks, and for inpatient care at public providers onlyOutpatient and inpatient care at public providers only
Negative list of benefits packageCosmetic surgery, physical check-up, alternative medicine, dental prostheses, fertility treatment, non-basic immunizationGeneral check-up, cancer treatment, heart surgery, renal dialysis, and lifelong treatment for congenital diseases, prostheses, non-basic immunization, transplantation, fertility treatmentCosmetic surgery, physical check-ups, alternative medicine, dental prostheses, fertility treatment
CopaymentYes, if members want to upgrade class, branded drugs out of formulary, renal dialysis, transplantation, heart surgeryNone, but Jamsostek does not cover high cost treatments such as cancer treatment, heart surgery, and renal dialysisNone
Provider payment arrangementPrimary care: capitation Secondary care: fee schedulePrimary care: capitation Secondary care: capitation and fee schedulePrimary care: capitation Secondary care: negotiated fee with limit
Source: Abstracted from Hidayat et al. and Roxt et al. [10,21].
Askes is a contributory social insurance (for civil servants, pensioned civil servants and armed forces with their dependents). This scheme is managed by the state-owned enterprise, PT Askes, and covers about 14 million people. Member contribution is set at 2 percent of monthly base salary, with the government contributing an additional 0.5% since 2003. This scheme provides comprehensive benefits for both outpatient and inpatient care through a structured health provider mechanism. A cost sharing policy is applied for certain medical treatments [10,21,24].
Endogeneity in estimating the impact of Askes on financial protection may arise, as enrollment is dependent on social servant status. Askes provides comprehensive benefits packages upon retirement, so this may be a choice variable for individuals in Indonesia. Poorer health status individuals, in anticipation of their high future medical needs, may be more likely to choose to be civil servants, knowing that such a position grants them access to health insurance. Healthier individuals may be more likely to seek a job in an enterprise or to choose self-employment, knowing no portion of their earnings will be deducted for health insurance [25].
Jamsostek is a social insurance fund targeting workers in the formal economy, specifically in firms with at least 10 employees and with a minimum wage of 1 million IDR (80.50€) per month. The insurance premium is fully the employer’s responsibility and is set at 3% of the monthly base salary for single workers and at 6% for workers with dependents. The scheme covers about 4.1 million employees and their dependents. Jamsostek provides a comprehensive benefits package and allows the members to access both public and private outpatient provider networks, but inpatient care is limited to public hospitals. However, this scheme does not cover catastrophic health care. Participation into Jamsostek is relatively low due to an opt-out provision for employers if they can provide better private insurance coverage than the Jamsostek benefits package. Jamsostek only covers approximately 7% of total formal sector employees. The participation of the employers into Jamsostek is subject to option, and employers choosing to select out of the program if they have other options. This opt-out clause or optional membership policy has resulted in adverse selection for Jamsostek. Some employers purchase a commercial insurance plan for their employees, and many employers still provide no protection for their employees [21,23,26,27,28].

3. Methodology

3.1. Data

The study was based on data from the Indonesia Family Life Survey (IFLS) dataset. The IFLS dataset consists of panel household data stretched over four time periods. The sample represents 83 percent of the population in 13 out of the 27 Indonesian provinces and is stratified to include various cultural and socioeconomic backgrounds. The IFLS was first conducted in 1993, covering 7,224 households. Additional rounds were conducted in 1997, 2000, and 2007. 87.6% of all initially sampled households were included in all four rounds. For a detailed description of the IFLS, see Frankenberg and Thomas and Strauss et al. [29,30,31].
The IFLS gathers information on socioeconomic and health seeking behavior at both the individual and at the household level. Across rounds, interviews were conducted in the national language (Bahasa), however, interviewers sometimes also mixed in the local language to facilitate the interview process. The econometric model was developed and tested empirically by using panel data from the four rounds of the IFLS. Table 2 presents descriptive statistics for the main variables.

3.2. Outcome Variable

Out-of-pocket expenditure was measured as the amount of household expenditure paid as a consequence of obtaining health care during the previous one year. Health expenditure was consistently reported in all four IFLS rounds (1993, 1997, 2000 and 2007). We defined out-of-pocket expenditures to include: hospitalization costs, clinic charges, physician fees, traditional healer fees, and medicines. Expenditure incurred on transportation to access health services was not included in the analysis, because it was not available in the dataset. To remove the effect of inflation, we adjusted annual expenditure values using the Consumer Price Index (CPI) to 2007 values [32]. We set the unit of analysis at the household level. We adjusted for household size and age structure, converting aggregated household values into per capita expenditure [33].
Table 2. Descriptive statistics IFLS household panel 1993–2007.
Table 2. Descriptive statistics IFLS household panel 1993–2007.
Variable1993199720002007
N = 7,194N = 6,667N = 6,703N = 6,335
MeanStd. Dev.Mean Std. Dev.Mean Std. Dev.Mean Std. Dev.
Out-of-pocket expenditures (IDR)167,072.80806,423.10182,327.30816,080.70171,308.302,033,662.00186,134.00843,351.20
Household income (IDR)5,310,577.005,310,577.006,999,397.001.22e+076,447,424.007,573,455.007,862,883.002.48e+07
Health insurance
   Askes0.0860.2810.1470.3540.1340.3400.1290.335
   Jamsostek0.0100.0970.0700.2550.0670.2510.0740.262
   Askeskin------0.1790.383
Male0.8390.3680.8220.3820.8160.3870.7810.414
Married0.3680.3770.8150.3890.8050.3960.7650.424
Education:
Below junior high0.6870.4640.6910.4620.6690.4710.6380.481
Junior high0.1180.3220.1140.3180.1240.3290.1240.328
Senior high0.1390.3460.1400.3470.1430.3500.1630.369
University0.0560.2310.0550.2270.0620.2410.0770.266
Household size >40.4710.4990.5940.4910.6740.4690.7560.429
Age composition (years):
0–50.1150.1510.0880.1240.0740.1060.0480.084
6–170.2450.2200.2430.1970.2310.1860.1750.160
18–590.5450.2450.5640.2300.5840.2260.6620.211
60 and above0.0950.2200.1050.2160.1110.2120.1150.194
Urban0.4750.4990.4520.4980.4550.4980.4930.500
Ethnicity (Javanese)0.5870.4920.5890.4920.5900.4920.5850.493
Health status
GHS is “poor”0.2000.4000.2700.4440.3250.4680.3560.479
ADL with limitation0.2970.4570.5350.4990.6270.4840.5950.491

3.3. Explanatory Variables

3.3.1. Income

We used household consumption as a proxy of income given that in low and middle income settings, consumption has been identified to be a more reliable measure of living standard than income [10,33]. We adjusted annual consumption values using the CPI to the 2007 value. Per capita consumption levels were computed by adjusting household values for household size. This method of computing socio-economic status allows accounting for intra-household spillover effects, i.e., intra-household resource transfer or cross subsidies [33].

3.3.2. Health Insurance

We analyzed the three largest health insurance schemes implemented in Indonesia: civil servant health insurance (Askes), employee health insurance (Jamsostek), and health insurance for poor people (Askeskin). The survey asked whether the head of the household was enrolled in one of these insurance schemes which also automatically included household dependents. The insurance types were included in the model as dummy variables.

3.3.3. Health Status

Health status is one of the determinants driving health seeking behavior. Sick people are more likely to seek health care services from traditional or modern (either public or private) providers than healthier people. Ha et al. [34] found that households with sick people were correlated with choosing health care providers. Gotsadze et al. [35] confirmed that perceived seriousness of illness was a significant factor which increased the probability to seek for health care. Patients with high levels of illness perception were more likely to seek health care than those with low level of perception, which suggests that patients with higher perceived illness would spend more or have higher medical expenditures than those with lesser degree of perceived illness.
We included two indicators of health status in the models: self-rated general health status (GHS) and activity of daily living (ADL). These are two measures of self-reported illness that reflect the need for health care and derived from individuals’ responses to the health-related questions in the IFLS surveys. The GHS measures were based on individuals’ assessment of subjective health status. The questions on the GHS asked individuals to rate their general health status on a 4-point categorical scale: very good, good, bad and very bad. For the purpose of this study, we aggregated very good and good into one response category, and bad and very bad into another one. A dummy indicating whether members in the household had a “poor” health status was included. The ADL measures were based on individuals’ self-ratings of ability to perform the basic tasks of everyday life, such as carrying a heavy object 20 meters, climbing stairs, walking, bending, kneeling or stooping, drawing water from a well, dressing without assistance, rising from a sitting position in a chair, toileting, and rising from a sitting position on the floor. A dummy indicating whether household members had difficulty or an inability to perform these activities was also included.

3.3.4. Age Composition of Household

Because the unit analysis of this study was the household, individual age could not be used in this model. As an alternative, we computed the percentage of the household in different age groups. This grouping reflected patterns of morbidity associated with different ages: (a) <6 years; (b) 6–17 years; (c) 18–60 years; and (d) >60 years.

3.3.5. Other Variables

Other independent variables included demographic variables such as married (a dummy indicating household head is currently married), male (a dummy indicating household head is male), family members (a dummy indicating family members are more than four persons), urban (a dummy indicating residence in urban area), education of the household head (dummies indicating below junior high (reference), senior high, and college and university), and ethnicity (a dummy indicating Javanese).

3.4. Econometric Model

We used three different econometrics approaches in the selection process of an appropriate model based on the principle of panel data analysis, the sampling design of study, and the nature of health insurance uptake. Askes, Jamsostek and Askeskin have different dates of establishment, enrollment mechanisms, benefits schemes, and population targets. To address these issues, we conducted an econometric identification strategy that allowed for robust and unbiased estimation and also facilitated the interpretations of the parameters. All estimation was carried out using Stata version 12.1.
To investigate the effects of health insurance on out-of-pocket payments, we first employed a pooled ordinary least squares (OLS) model covering the whole period, 1993–2007. We constructed a pooled OLS regression as follows:
ln oopit = β0 + β1xit + β2Askesit + β3Jamsostekit + β4Askeskinit + β5zit + β6yt + αi + εit
where i = 1,...,n represents households and t = 1993, 1997, 2000, 2007 represents years. oopit is per capita out-of-pocket expenditures for household i at period t. To reduce the effects of the skewed nature of the out-of-pocket expenditures variable in the equation, the dependent variable (oopit) was log-transformed. The treatment variable was defined as: Askesit = 1 if the household was enrolled in Askes, and Askesit = 0 otherwise; Jamsostekit = 1 if the household was enrolled in Jamsostek, and Jamsostekit = 0 otherwise; Askeskinit = 1 if the household was enrolled in Askeskin, and Askeskinit = 0 otherwise. xit is a vector of time-variant specific effects such as household head sex, marital status, education of the household head, and household size, age composition, location, income, and health status,. zit denotes a vector of time-invariant household characteristics such as ethnicity. yt denotes year dummies that capture time shock; αi is a vector of unobserved time-invariant specific effect and εit is an idiosyncratic error or time-varying error which was assumed to be randomly distributed.
Note that in Equation (1), the OLS estimates of β2, β3 and β4 are still heavily biased because of endogeneity, that is, a correlation between insurance status and the error term, αi. The problem of adverse selection in the schemes creates a higher likelihood of correlation between insurance status and the error term (αi) which induces a bias in the coefficient of health insurance on the out-of-pocket expenditures equation. This condition leads to a positive association between insurance status and out-of-pocket expenditures because higher health risk people are more likely to enroll in an insurance plan than others. To address this endogeneity problem, we considered two options: to develop an instrumental variable (IV) model estimated on the pooled panel data and a fixed effects (FE) model.
We first addressed endogeneity through the application of an instrumental variable model. The IV on the pooled panel data provides a consistent estimator under the strong assumption that a valid instrument exists, meaning that the instrument is correlated with insurance status and uncorrelated with the error term. As in prior applications of the same [36], the instrument is used to control the error term but it does not lead to a direct change in the outcome variable.
In the IV model, we treated insurance status as an endogenous variable. We tested for possible endogeneity of the regressor using the Hausman test to measure the difference between OLS and IV estimator and the related Durbin-Wu-Hausman (DWH) test to produce a robust test statistic. A significant difference between OLS and IV model estimates, as indicated in the Hausman test, would suggest the exogenous status of insurance. Similarly, a significant DWH test would also suggest that insurance is endogenous [36].
We constructed pooled two-stage least squares (2SLS) to calculate IV estimates for insurance status. We conducted the instrument relevance and validity tests to indicate that our instruments were correlated with insurance status, but uncorrelated with error term (αi). For the relevance of the instruments, we employed several key diagnostic statistics to identify weak instruments. We evaluated the R2 of the first-stage reduced-form equation and the F-test of the joint significance of the instruments excluded from the structural model. Given one of our models had two suspected endogenous regressors (i.e., Askes and Jamsostek variables), the R2 value and F statistic might not have been sufficient to diagnose instrument relevance. Therefore, we also used a Shea partial R2 measure that investigates inter-correlations among instruments. For the validity of the instruments’ diagnostic, we applied an over-identification test by using Sargan statistic. Then, for the original set of orthogonality conditions of the instruments’ testing, we employed C-statistic. The C test allows to confirm whether selected instruments are exogenous [36,37,38].
We used the eligibility for the government social protection program as an instrument for Askeskin variable (git). However, given this eligibility criteria was only relevant for the surveys from 2000 and 2007, we limited our analysis related to the Askeskin scheme only to these two data collection points. To assess the impact of both Askes and Jamsostek on household out-of-pocket health expenditure, we employed the same set of three instrumental variables (eit): household participation in community meetings, household participation in women’s group organizations, and workplace size (workplace with at least 10 employees). The first two instruments were successfully used in a prior study in Indonesia [25]. We assumed that these instruments were correlated with the probability of being insured in either scheme and uncorrelated with out-of-pocket expenditures only through insurance once we had controlled for health insurance and other covariates. For these two schemes, we constructed a model that used only three waves of panel data (i.e., 1997 to 2007), due to the availability of the information needed to construct the instruments.
We controlled for autocorrelation in the error term by applying cluster-robust standard errors. Since instrumental variables are aggregated at the household level, we used household level as clustering option. Furthermore, in case of Askeskin, we also considered another form of shock from alternative targeted poverty programs. These programs could lead to confounding effects of Askeskin, particularly while there was the overlap of the target groups, targeting criteria and mechanisms [39]. We therefore included subsidized rice variable as a potential confounding factor for Askeskin to control some non-trivial overlap between both programs. Subsidized rice program introduced in 1998 under social safety net in response to the 1997 economic crisis. The information of subsidized rice program was also available in the IFLS 2000 and 2007. We constructed a subsidized rice recipient dummy variable in the IV model for Askeskin to correct for this issue.
Lastly, a fallback of the IV model was that we could only count on partial observation (i.e., 2000 and 2007 for Askeskin scheme and 1997-2007 for Askes and Jamsostek schemes) leading to rather imperfect estimates. We therefore also addressed the problem of endogeneity through the application of an FE model covering the entire IFLS dataset (i.e., 1993–2007). FE models offer consistent parameter estimates, provided that endogeneity is due to the correlation between unobserved time-invariant specific effects (αi) and insurance status and that insurance is uncorrelated with εit. FE models consistently provide an unbiased estimator of insurance by taking advantage of differencing transformation that eliminates αi [34] (i.e., health care preference and static socioeconomic characteristics). This model also included the control variable, xit, for change in gender of household heads, marital status of household heads, education of household heads, household size, age composition, location, and income. Our FE model did not include time-invariant variables, such as ethnicity. In our FE model, we also applied cluster-robust standard errors, assuming that observations are independent over the number of time periods.

4. Results

4.1. Descriptive Analysis

Table 3 reports the sample distribution and the percentage of insured people in each scheme, across the four survey periods. The sample of this study decreased over the years. From 7,224 original households in IFLS1, after data cleaning, we selected 7,194 households for our analysis. Table 3 indicates that the number of Askes beneficiaries ranged from 9 to 14% of the total sample during survey periods; the number of Jamsostek beneficiaries increased from 1% in the initial survey period to 7% in the next periods; and the number of Askeskin beneficiaries was at 18% in 2007. From 1993 to 1997, the overall percentage of enrolled households increased substantially. Table 3 also confirms that the introduction of Askeskin caused a sizeable increase in the number of health insurance beneficiaries in 2007.
Table 3. The distribution of health insurance status across year.
Table 3. The distribution of health insurance status across year.
Insurance status1993199720002007
n%n%n%n%
Askes6229.5698114.7189513.3581712.90
Jamsostek690.964677.004516.734707.42
Askeskin00.0000.0000.001,13317.88
Uninsured6,50390.395,21978.285,35779.923,91561.80
Total households7,194100.006,667100.006,703100.006,335100.00
Figure 1 depicts annual per capita out-of-pocket expenditures by insured and uninsured households. Per capita out-of-pocket expenditures among Askes beneficiaries slightly decreased between 1993 and 2000, but increased by 16% from 2000 to 2007. Per capita out-of-pocket expenditures dropped by 50% among Jamsostek beneficiaries between 1993 and 1997. A further decrease of less than 1% occurred between 1997 and 2007. Figure 1 also displays per capita out-of-pocket expenditures among Askeskin beneficiaries before and after the scheme implementation. In 2007, households receiving Askeskin benefits spent 20% more than in 2000. This increase might be due to adverse selection, in which non-eligible individuals with high anticipated health expenditures enrolled in the program. As depicted in Figure 2, around 20% of Askeskin beneficiaries came from households in higher and highest income quintiles.
Figure 1. The distribution of mean out-of-pocket expenditures across year in Indonesia Rupiah (IDR) (1€ = 12,421.89 IDR).
Figure 1. The distribution of mean out-of-pocket expenditures across year in Indonesia Rupiah (IDR) (1€ = 12,421.89 IDR).
Ijerph 10 02995 g001
Figure 2. The distribution of Askeskin enrollees across different income level (2007).
Figure 2. The distribution of Askeskin enrollees across different income level (2007).
Ijerph 10 02995 g002

4.2. Impact Estimation Results

Table 4 reports the results of all three models (simple OLS, IV model, and FE model). We found that the OLS estimates (Models 2 and 4) differed substantially from the IV estimates (Models 3 and 5). The OLS coefficients for Askes, Jamsostek and Askeskin, −0.007, 0.011, and −0.022, respectively, (Models 2 and model 4) differed significantly from the IV coefficients of −0.802 for Askes (Model 3), −0.102 for Jamsostek (Model 3) and −0.411 for Askeskin (Model 5). Model 3 and model 5 produced significant values for Askes and Askeskin. Both this set of results and the robustified DWH test confirmed the endogeneity of insurance status and led to the rejection of the null hypothesis that Askes, Jamsostek and Askeskin were exogenous (Table 5).
Table 4. The effects of health insurance programs on household out-of-pocket expenditures.
Table 4. The effects of health insurance programs on household out-of-pocket expenditures.
Variables(1) Pooled OLS 1993–2007(2) Pooled OLS—comparison for (3) 1997–2007(3) Pooled 2SLS (IV) for Askes and Jamsostek 1997–2007(4) Pooled OLS—comparison for (5) 2000–2007(5) Pooled 2SLS (IV) for Askeskin 2000–2007(6) FE 1993–2007
Health insurance
Askes0.015 (0.040)−0.007 (0.045)−0.802 (0.337) **--0.008 (0.068)
Jamsostek0.024 (0.051)0.011 (0.053)−0.102 (0.261)--0.017 (0.064)
Askeskin−0.088 (0.055)--−0.022 (0.059)−0.411 (0.238) *−0.111 (0.064) *
Subsidized rice recipient---−0.146 (0.036) ***−0.113 (0.041) ***-
Male−0.026 (0.049)0.015 (0.056)0.004 (0.057)−0.021 (0.070)−0.013 (0.070)0.002 (0.070)
Married−0.049 (0.049)−0.100 (0.056) *−0.107 (0.057) *−0.086 (0.070)−0.095 (0.070)0.032 (0.068)
Education: Below junior high *)
Junior high0.167 (0.037) ***0.186 (0.042) ***0.264 (0.055) ***0.138 (0.051) ***0.132 (0.051) **−0.036 (0.062)
Senior high0.209 (0.037) ***0.237 (0.044) ***0.431 (0.097) ***0.171 (0.052) ***0.156 (0.053) ***−0.069 (0.073)
University0.273 (0.056) ***0.273 (0.065) ***0.661 (0.176) ***0.196 (0.075) ***0.179 (0.076) **−0.201 (0.106) *
Household size−0.073 (0.027) ***−0.100 (0.032) ***−0.058 (0.040)−0.084 (0.041) **−0.086 (0.041) **−0.056 (0.046)
Age composition (years): 18–59 *)
0–50.699 (0.096) ***0.757 (0.124) ***0.648 (0.134) ***0.864 (0.168) ***0.890 (0.169) ***0.975 (0.140) ***
6–17−0.384 (0.067) ***−0.395 (0.081) ***−0.450 (0.088) ***−0.453 (0.102) ***−0.438 (0.102) ***−0.124 (0.091)
60 and above0.445 (0.068) ***0.427 (0.081) ***0.473 (0.085) ***0.459 (0.101) ***0.455 (0.101) ***0.413 (0.112) ***
Urban0.071 (0.025) ***0.055 (0.029) *0.078 (0.034) **0.043 (0.035)0.052 (0.036)0.013 (0.068)
Ethnicity0.193 (0.024) ***0.246 (0.028) ***0.255 (0.031) ***0.210 (0.036) ***0.203 (0.036) ***-
Health status
GHS is poor0.365 (0.025) ***0.350 (0.028) ***0.355 (0.028) ***0.342 (0.034) ***0.346 (0.034) ***0.292 (0.029) ***
ADL with limitation0.177 (0.024) ***0.159 (0.027) ***0.182 (0.029) ***0.145 (0.033) ***0.146 (0.033) ***0.160 (0.028) ***
Household income: Lowest *)
Lower 20%0.582 (0.033) ***0.517 (0.039) ***0.538 (0.040) ***0.471 (0.048) ***0.469 (0.048) ***0.416 (0.042) ***
Middle 20%1.009 (0.035) ***0.936 (0.040) ***0.967 (0.044) ***0.861 (0.048) ***0.856 (0.048) ***0.759 (0.045) ***
Higher 20%1.531 (0.036) ***1.448 (0.042) ***1.511 (0.053) ***1.370 (0.051) ***1.356 (0.052) ***1.206 (0.049) ***
Highest 20%2.231 (0.041) ***2.119 (0.048) ***2.230 (0.073) ***1.981 (0.059) ***1.964 (0.060) ***1.698 (0.057) ***
Year: 1993 *)
19970.024 (0.029)--- 0.026 (0.031)
2000−0.182 (0.029) ***−0.204 (0.029) ***−0.222 (0.030) ***- −0.146 (0.034) ***
2007−0.131 (0.034) ***−0.177 (0.032) ***−0.203 (0.035) ***0.070 (0.035) **0.135 (0.053) **−0.001 (0.042)
Constant9.282 (0.050) ***9.388 (0.058) ***9.380 (0.059) ***9.356 (0.072) ***9.350 (0.072) ***9.595 (0.072) ***
F-statistic (p-value)237.35 ( .00)179.64 ( .00)172.48 ( .00)116.81 ( .00)116.51 ( .00)57.85 ( .00)
R20.2480.233-0.219-0.095
No. of observation20,16814,47514,4749,1409,14020,168
No. of clusters6,9696,3906,3905,8835,8836,969
Note. Standard errors in parentheses. Standard errors were adjusted for clustering at the household level. *** 1%, ** 5%, and *10% significance levels. *) as reference. OLS, ordinary least squares; 2SLS, two-stage least squares; IV, instrumental variable; FE, fixed effects.
Table 5. Endogeneity tests.
Table 5. Endogeneity tests.
TestAskes and JamsostekAskeskin
Statisticsp-valueStatisticsp-value
Durbin-Wu-Hausman chi-square testχ2 = 6.6840.035χ2 = 2.8590.091
Wu-Hausman F testF (2,14450) = 3.3370.037F (1,9118) = 2.8590.091
In addition, we tested the relevance and validity of the selected instruments based on several key diagnostic statistics. For weak instrument testing (Table 6), the values of the R2 and adjusted −R2 from first-stage regression were around 0.1 to 0.2, showing that there will be considerable loss of precision because of IV estimation. These values were not low enough to indicate a weak-instrument problem. Moreover, the values of Partial R2 and Shea’s partial R2 were similar for both Askes and Jamsostek insurance, indicating that the instruments were sufficient relevance to explain all the endogenous regressors, and the model was well identified. We also considered F-test where the instrument should have an F-value greater than 10 to indicate that it is relevant [37,38]. The analysis revealed an F-value was 69.775 for Askes, 77.467 for Jamsostek, and 227.177 for Askeskin, which suggests that all instruments were strongly correlated with each insurance status.
Table 6. Instruments relevance tests.
Table 6. Instruments relevance tests.
TestAskesJamsostekAskeskin
R20.2390.1000.192
Adjusted R20.2380.0990.191
Partial R20.0190.0450.059
F-testF (3,14451) = 69.775 ***F (3,14451) = 77.467 ***F (1,9119) = 227.177 ***
Shea’s partial R20.0160.0380.059
Shea’s Adjusted partial R20.0150.0370.057
*** significant 1%.
For the validity of the instruments, we conducted an over-identification test to assess whether the instruments were valid instruments (i.e., uncorrelated with error term) and they were correctly excluded from the estimated equation. The value of the Sargan’s statistic tests was 2.236 (p = 0.135) for Askes and Jamsostek, which suggests that all instruments were valid and the models were well specified. Further, for orthogonality condition of the instruments, the value of the C-statistic was 2.236 (p = 0.135) for Askes and Jamsostek, which suggests that all instruments were exogenous. For Askeskin which was a just-identified model, we did not test exogeneity condition of the instrument. The instrument’s independence from error term can be identified if we have a surfeit of instruments [36]. Based on all specification test findings, we concluded that the selected instruments were appropriate enough to be applied in our model and the IV estimators more robust.
Table 4 shows that Askes and Askeskin had a significant negative effect on household out-of-pocket expenditures for the IV models (Model 3 and 5), whereas in the FE model (Model 6), only Askeskin had a significant negative effect. Otherwise, in all OLS models (Model 1, 2 and 4), all insurances had no significant effect on household out-of-pocket expenditures. According to IV models (Model 3 and 5), two insurances decreased household out-of-pocket expenditures. Askes decreased out-of-pocket expenditures by 55% (= e−0.802 − 1) on average at α = 0.05 and Askeskin by 34% (= e−0.411 − 1) at α = 0.10 compared with non-Askes and non-Askeskin, respectively. Jamsostek was found to have a nonsignificant effect on out-of-pocket expenditures, although the association was negative. Furthermore, according to the FE model (Model 6), Askeskin had a significant negative effect on household out-of-pocket expenditures at α = 0.10, that is, Askeskin decreased household out-of-pocket expenditures by 11% (= e−0.111 − 1). However, in this model, Askes and Jamsostek were found to have nonsignificant effects on household out-of-pocket expenditures.
With regard to other covariates, the four household income dummy variables and the two indicators of health status were found to have a significant positive effect on household out-of-pocket expenditures across all regression models. Age composition of less than 5 years and greater than 60 years had a positive effect, but age composition of 6–17 years had a negative effect in all regression analyses. Conversely, in the FE model, age composition of 16–17 year was found to be nonsignificant. Moreover, in the FE model, household heads with a higher education level, such as a university degree, were found to have a significant negative effect. In contrast, in both OLS and IV models, household heads in every education level (i.e., from junior high school to university) were found to have a significant positive effect.

5. Discussion

The results of the three models yielded somewhat contradictory findings. In line with our research question, we focused our discussion exclusively on the impact of health insurance on out-of-pocket expenditures and paid particular attention to the problem of endogeneity, independently from the factors, such as supplier-induced demand or provider moral hazard, which might be at the core of the observed effect. We therefore focused our discussion on the results of IV and FE models that, we believe, address the endogeneity of insurance. The findings of IV model confirmed that that two health insurance programs (i.e., Askes and Askeskin) significantly decreased household out-of-pocket expenditures. Using the IV model lead to identify a substantially different effect of insurance status on out-of-pocket expenditures than the standard OLS model. The IV model produced a robust estimator of the extent to which health insurance programs contributed to reduce household out-of-pocket expenditures, while correcting for possible endogeneity. These results are in line with previously published work by Galarraga et al. and Shaefer et al. in relation to their evaluation of health insurance in Mexico and in the US, respectively [16,17].
The results of the FE analysis confirmed that only Askeskin health insurance significantly decreased out-of-pocket expenditures. In contrast, the FE model did not detect any impact of Askes and Jamsostek schemes on reducing out-of-pocket expenditures. One possible reason explaining why the model detected a significant effect only for the Askeskin scheme may be that the number of households in the sample acting as non-treatment group (i.e., non-insured) for Askes and Jamsostek were highly unlikely to experience entry and exit into the treatment group (i.e., the insured group) over the four survey periods, as opposed to Askeskin whose “non-treatment” group was defined by a clear time point (2005). This is due to the fact that FE models correct for selectivity by computing differences from mean values [36]. The power to estimate an effect is therefore severely jeopardized if the model does not contain sufficient controls.
Appraising our findings in the light of existing literature is difficult since only a few studies have, to date, investigated the impact of health insurance in Indonesia, with specific focus on out-of-pocket expenditures. Sparrow et al. [24] examined the effect of Askeskin by using propensity score matching approach and found that the program significantly increased out-of-pocket expenditures particularly in urban areas. Their study, however, was vulnerable to biases since it only conditioned “observables” and ruled out “selection on unobservables” to deal with the endogeneity problem. Our findings on Askes cannot be appraised in light of similar studies on Indonesia, but may be compared to findings from Vietnam. Controlling for endogeneity, Sepehri et al. [18] found that public health insurance, covering civil servants similarly to Askes, reduced out-of-pocket expenditures. Our study also suggested that unlike other programs, Jamsostek did not significantly reduce out-of-pocket expenditures. The reason is possibly to be found in its less comprehensive benefits package, not covering high cost medical treatments such as hemodialysis, cancer treatment, cardiac surgery, and congenital diseases. This may lead beneficiaries to experience higher out-of-pocket spending to cover treatment for these conditions. This particular situation may explain why Jamsostek members end up paying more for uncovered drugs and tests.
Differences in benefits packages may in fact be at the core of the difference in the observed effects across insurance schemes. Askeskin has the most generous benefits package, covering almost all types of care with no cost sharing policy and limited service limitations. This is likely to explain why its observed protective effect on out-of-pocket expenditures was more pronounced than that of any other scheme. Askes provides a less generous benefits package than Askeskin, although more generous than Jamsostek, covering several high cost treatments, but applying cost-sharing. This is likely to explain why its protective effect on out-of-pocket expenditures was less pronounced than Askeskin, but still more pronounced than Jamsostek.
Our study provides relevant evidence for policy, by establishing that at least two of the existing health insurance programs in Indonesia effectively provide households the needed financial protection against the cost of illness. This is an important starting point in the discussions on how to continue and expand health care financing options in the light of moving towards universal health coverage [21]. This study has confirmed that two health insurances (i.e., Askeskin and Askes), which are the largest insurance scheme in Indonesia, have had a positive impact on the financial protection of its members. Our results can conceivably be extended to other populations for which universal health insurance is policy option. A common argument has been that universal coverage health insurance can lead to better financial protection outcomes in some Asian countries [40,41].
There are several limitations to our study. First, our measure of households’ out-of-pocket expenditures included expenditure on traditional medications, a product not covered by any insurance scheme under analysis. In provinces where traditional medical practices are the preferred health seeking choice, due to long-standing socio-cultural norms, the inclusion of traditional treatments in the measure of out-of-pocket expenditures may inflate the relevant value due to factors which are beyond the control or responsibility of the single insurance schemes. Second, the IFLS data did not include information on transportation costs, i.e., out-of-pocket expenditure that allowed households to reach to the selected health care facility. Many studies revealed that even though treatment is free or covered by the public insurance, transport costs can be so burdensome to actually hamper access to services and/or lead to substantially higher out-of-pocket values than when treatment costs alone are considered [42,43]. Third, our study focused exclusively on the effect of health insurance on actual out-of-pocket expenditures and did not analyze other more comprehensive indicators of financial protection, such as catastrophic and impoverishing health spending. Such an analysis should definitely constitute the object of future research. Fourth, our study could not take into account endogeneity deriving from the fact that expenditure could only be observed for the sub-sample of respondents who decided to utilize services in the first place. Fifth, in case of Askeskin, the time intervals between the IFLS panel waves are large, allowing confounding time variant unobservables. Other alternative targeted poverty programs, such as unconditional cash transfers and scholarship programs could lead to confounding effects of Askeskin.

6. Conclusions

Most of the evidence from our models pointed at the fact that two existing health insurance programs, Askeskin and Askes, in Indonesia significantly reduced household out-of-pocket expenditures after correcting for endogeneity (selection on unobservables). One scheme, Jamsostek, produced no significant impact on the reduction of household out-of-pocket expenditures. The ability of schemes to offer financial protection by reducing out-of-pocket expenditures is likely to be a direct function of their benefits package and co-payment policies. Future research needs to expand on our work to explore the impact of health insurance on more comprehensive financial protection indicators, such as catastrophic and impoverishing health spending.

Acknowledgments

The authors thank The RAND Corporation for providing the data. We are also grateful to the DGHE of Ministry of Education and Culture of the Republic of Indonesia for providing the financial scholarship to study in the PhD Program at the Institute of Public Health, University of Heidelberg, Germany. Finally, we thank Lena Janys for econometric advice and Michael Cofrin for correcting English error.

Conflict of Interest

The authors declare that they have no competing interest.

References

  1. Yip, W.; Berman, P. Targeted health insurance in a low income country and its impact on access and equity in access: Egypt’s school health insurance. Health Econ. 2001, 10, 207–220. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Devadasan, N.; Criel, B.; Van Damme, W.; Manoharan, S.; Sarma, P.S.; Van der Stuyft, P. Community health insurance in Gudalur, India, increases access to hospital care. Health Policy Plann. 2010, 25, 145–154. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Axelson, H.; Bales, S.; Minh, P.D.; Ekman, B.; Gerdtham, U.G. Health financing for the poor produces promising short-term effects on utilization and out-of-pocket expenditure: Evidence from Vietnam. Int J. Equity Health 2009, 8, 20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Noirhomme, M.; Meessen, B.; Griffiths, F.; Ir, P.; Jacobs, B.; Thor, R.; Criel, B.; Van Damme, W. Improving access to hospital care for the poor: Comparative analysis of four health equity funds in Cambodia. Health Policy Plann. 2007, 22, 246–262. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Wagstaff, A.; Lindelow, M. Can insurance increase financial risk? The curious case of health insurance in China. J. Health Econ. 2008, 27, 990–1005. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Ghosh, S. Catastrophic Payments and Impoverishment due to Out-of-Pocket Health Spending: The Effects of Recent Health Sector Reforms in India. In Working Paper Series on Health and Demographic Change in the Asia-Pacific; Stanford University, Walter H. Shorenstein Asia-Pacific Research Center, Asia Health Policy Program: Stanford ,CA, USA, 2010. [Google Scholar]
  7. Ekman, B.; Liem, N.T.; Duc, H.A.; Axelson, H. Health insurance reform in Vietnam: A review of recent developments and future challenges. Health Policy Plann. 2008, 23, 252–263. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Wagstaff, A. Estimating health insurance impacts under unobserved heterogeneity: The case of Vietnam’s health care fund for the poor. Health Econ. 2010, 19, 189–208. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. The World Health Report 2000—Health Systems: Improving Performance; World Health Organization: Geneva, Switzerland, 2002.
  10. Hidayat, B.; Thabrany, H.; Dong, H.; Sauerborn, R. The effects of mandatory health insurance on equity in access to outpatient care in Indonesia. Health Policy Plann. 2004, 19, 322–335. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Bachtiar, A.; Wibisana, W.; Pujiyanto. Laporan Akhir Hasil Asesmen Cepat Program PKPS-BBM 2005 Bidang Kesehatan; PUSKA-FKM University of Indonesia: Jakarta, Indonesia, 2006. [Google Scholar]
  12. Zweifel, P.; Manning, W.G. Moral Hazard and Consumer. Incentives in Health Care. In Handbook of Health Economics; Culyer, A.J., Newhouse, J.P., Eds.; Elsevier: Amsterdam, The Nertherlands, 2000; Volume 1A, pp. 409–459. [Google Scholar]
  13. Cutler, D.M.; Zeckhauser, R.J. The Anatomy of Health Insurance. In Handbook of Health Economics; Culyer, A.J., Newhouse, J.P., Eds.; Elsevier: Amsterdam, The Nertherlands, 2000; Volume 1A. [Google Scholar]
  14. McGuire, T.G. Physician Agency. In Handbook of Health Economics; Culyer, A.J., Newhouse, J.P., Eds.; Elsevier: Amsterdam, The Nertherlands, 2000; Volume 1A. [Google Scholar]
  15. Nguyen, C.V. The Impact of voluntary health insurance on health care utilization and out-of-pocket payments: New evidence for Vietnam. Health Econ. 2012, 21, 946–966. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  16. Galarraga, O.; Sosa-Rubi, S.G.; Salinas-Rodriguez, A.; Sesma-Vazquez, S. Health insurance for the poor: Impact on catastrophic and out-of-pocket health expenditures in Mexico. Eur. J. Health Econ. 2010, 11, 437–447. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Luke Shaefer, H.; Grogan, C.M.; Pollack, H.A. Transitions from private to public health coverage among children: Estimating effects on out-of-pocket medical costs and health insurance premium costs. Health Serv. Res. 2011, 46, 840–858. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Sepehri, A.; Sarma, S.; Simpson, W. Does non-profit health insurance reduce financial burden? Evidence from the Vietnam living standards survey panel. Health Econ. 2006, 15, 603–616. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Statistical Yearbook of Indonesia 2012; BPS-Statistics Indonesia: Jakarta, Indonesia, 2012.
  20. World Bank, Investing in Indonesia’s Health: Challenges and Opportunities for Future Public Spending; The World Bank Office Jakarta: Jakarta, Indonesia, 2008.
  21. Rokx, C.; Schieber, G.; Harimurti, P.; Tandon, A.; Somanathan, A. Health Financing in Indonesia: A Reform Road Map; The World Bank: Washington DC, USA, 2009. [Google Scholar]
  22. Bender, K.; GTZ Office Jakarta. Options for Social Protection Reform in Indonesia; GTZ Office Jakarta: Jakarta, Indonesia, 2008. [Google Scholar]
  23. ILO, Social Security in Indonesia: Advancing the Development Agenda; International Labour Organization: Jakarta, Indonesia, 2008.
  24. Sparrow, R.; Suryahadi, A.; Widyanti, W. Social Health Insurance for the Poor: Targeting and Impact of Indonesia’s Askeskin Program; The SMERU Research Institute: Jakarta, Indonesia, 2010. [Google Scholar]
  25. Hidayat, B.; Pokhrel, S. The selection of an appropriate count data model for modelling health insurance and health care demand: case of Indonesia. Int J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2010, 7, 9–27. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Thabrany, H. Social Security for All: A continuous Challenge for Workers in Indonesia. Available online: Available online: library.fes.de/pdf-files/iez/08152.pdf (accessed on 23 October 2011).
  27. ADB, Preparatory Studies on National Social Security System in Indonesia; Asian Development Bank: Manila, Philippines, 2007.
  28. WHO, Social Health Insurance: Selected Country Case Studies from Asia and the Pacific; World Health Organization—South-East Asia Region: New Delhi, India, 2005.
  29. Frankenberg, E.; Thomas, D. The Indonesia Family Life Survey (IFLS): Study Design and Results from Waves 1 and 2; RAND Labor and Population Program: Santa Monica, CA, USA, 2000. [Google Scholar]
  30. Strauss, J.; Beegle, K.; Sikoki, B.; Dwiyanto, A.; Herawati, Y.; Witoelar, F. The Third Wave of the Indonesia Family Life Survey: Overview and Field Report; RAND Labor and Population: Santa Monica, CA, USA, 2004. [Google Scholar]
  31. Strauss, J.; Witoelar, F.; Sikoki, B.; Wattie, A.M. The Fourth Wave of the Indonesia Family Life Survey: Overview and Field Report; RAND Labor and Population: Santa Monica, CA, USA, 2009. [Google Scholar]
  32. Statistics Canada, Your Guide to the Consumer Price Index; Minister of Industry Canada: Ottawa, Canada, 1996.
  33. O’Donnell, O.; Doorslaer, E.V.; Wagstaff, A.; Lindelow, M. Analyzing Health Equity Using Household Survey Data: A Guide to Techniques and Their Implementation; The World Bank: Washington, DC, USA, 2008. [Google Scholar]
  34. Ha, N.T.; Berman, P.; Larsen, U. Household utilization and expenditure on private and public health services in Vietnam. Health Policy Plann. 2002, 17, 61–70. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Gotsadze, G. Health care—Seeking behaviour and out-of-pocket payments in Tbilisi, Georgia. Health Policy Plann. 2005, 20, 232–242. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Cameron, A.C.; Trivedi, P.K. Microeconometrics Using Stata; Stata Press: Texas, TX, USA, 2009. [Google Scholar]
  37. Stock, J.H.; Yogo, M. Testing for Weak Instruments in Linear IV Regression. In Technical Working Paper 284; National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2002. [Google Scholar]
  38. Baum, C.F.; Schaffer, M.E. Instrumental variables and GMM: Estimation and testing. Stata J. 2003, 3, 1–31. [Google Scholar]
  39. World Bank, Jamkesmas Health Service Fee Waiver: Social Assistance Program and Public Expenditures Review 4; Jakarta Office: Jakarta, Indonesia, 2012.
  40. Chu, T.B.; Liu, T.C.; Chen, C.S.; Tsai, Y.W.; Chiu, W.T. Household out-of-pocket medical expenditures and National Health Insurance in Taiwan: Income and regional inequality. BMC Health Serv. Res. 2005, 5, 60. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  41. Limwattananon, S.; Tangcharoensathien, V.; Prakongsai, P. Equity in Financing Healthcare: Impact of Universal Access to Healthcare in Thailand. In Working Paper 16; EQUITAP: Phnom Pehn, Cambodia, 2005. [Google Scholar]
  42. Abel-Smith, B.; Rawal, P. Can the poor afford “free” health services? A case study of Tanzania. Health Policy Plann. 1992, 7, 329–341. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Shamsun, N.; Costello, A. The hidden cost of “free” maternity care in Dhaka, Bangladesh. Health Policy Plann. 1998, 13, 417–422. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Aji, B.; De Allegri, M.; Souares, A.; Sauerborn, R. The Impact of Health Insurance Programs on Out-of-Pocket Expenditures in Indonesia: An Increase or a Decrease? Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2013, 10, 2995-3013. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph10072995

AMA Style

Aji B, De Allegri M, Souares A, Sauerborn R. The Impact of Health Insurance Programs on Out-of-Pocket Expenditures in Indonesia: An Increase or a Decrease? International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health. 2013; 10(7):2995-3013. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph10072995

Chicago/Turabian Style

Aji, Budi, Manuela De Allegri, Aurelia Souares, and Rainer Sauerborn. 2013. "The Impact of Health Insurance Programs on Out-of-Pocket Expenditures in Indonesia: An Increase or a Decrease?" International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health 10, no. 7: 2995-3013. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph10072995

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop