Next Article in Journal
Process Heat Generation Potential from Solar Concentration Technologies in Latin America: The Case of Argentina
Next Article in Special Issue
A Solar Energy Solution for Sustainable Third Generation Mobile Networks
Previous Article in Journal
Smart Home Energy Management
Previous Article in Special Issue
Bioenergy from Low-Intensity Agricultural Systems: An Energy Efficiency Analysis
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Does Renewable Energy Drive Sustainable Economic Growth? Multivariate Panel Data Evidence for EU-28 Countries

by
Daniel Ştefan Armeanu
,
Georgeta Vintilă
and
Ştefan Cristian Gherghina
*
Department of Finance, The Bucharest University of Economic Studies, 6 Piata Romana, 010374 Bucharest, Romania
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Energies 2017, 10(3), 381; https://doi.org/10.3390/en10030381
Submission received: 24 February 2017 / Revised: 10 March 2017 / Accepted: 13 March 2017 / Published: 17 March 2017

Abstract

:
Energy is crucial to economic progress, but the contemporary worldwide population increase that demands greater energy generated from conventional exhaustible resources, an energy price upsurge, and environmental concerns, imperils sustainable economic growth. Nevertheless, switching to renewable energy produced from naturally replenished resources promotes energy security, likewise addressing issues such as global warming and climate change. This paper aims at exploring the influence and causal relation between renewable energy, both overall and by type, and sustainable economic growth of European Union (EU)-28 countries for the period of 2003–2014. We notice that the mean share of renewable energy in the gross final energy consumption is 15%, while the mean share of renewable energy in transport fuel consumption is 3%, which are below the thresholds of 20% and 10%, respectively, as set by the EU Directive 2009/28/EC. By estimating panel data fixed-effects regression models, the results provide support for a positive influence of renewable energy overall, as well as by type, namely biomass, hydropower, geothermal energy, wind power, and solar energy on gross domestic product per capita. However, biomass energy shows the highest influence on economic growth among the rest of renewable energy types. In fact, a 1% increase of the primary production of solid biofuels increases GDP per capita by 0.16%. Besides, cointegrating regressions set on panel fully modified and dynamic ordinary least squares regressions confirm the positive influence related to the primary production of renewable energies on economic growth. A 1% increase in primary production of renewable energies increases GDP per capita by 0.05%–0.06%. However, the results of Granger causality based on panel vector error correction model indicate both in short-run and long-run a unidirectional causal relationship running from sustainable economic growth to the primary production of renewable energies, being supported the conservation hypothesis.

1. Introduction

Energy represents a vital factor for achieving sustainable economic growth [1], but the contemporary economic welfare is endangered by circumstances such as increased energy demand driven by the increase of world population which has entailed the quick consumption of traditional energy resources such as oil, coal, and natural gas, besides energy price rises, and discharging of harmful gases to the atmosphere. In fact, the lack of access to energy indicates a deficient situation as regards lowering poverty and accelerating development [2], but climate change issues have emerged due to greenhouse gas emissions caused by burning fossil fuels [3]. Therefore, a longer dependence on such fuels in order to overtake an upward energy demand will merely speed up environmental degradation [4]. For instance, the U.S. Energy Information Administration (EIA) [5] indicated a 48% intensification in world energy consumption by 2040; hence, the need for low carbon is obvious. Substitutes for fossil fuels, which are detrimental for the environment, are renewable energy resources that fulfill the main energy requests actual economies are confronted with, specifically regular renewal, less pollution, decreasing reliance on imported sources [6], enhanced employment [7], no security or safety concerns [8].
As long as common energy is produced from limited resources, governments should take into account a suitable utilization of it. Growth is regarded as sustainable if the existing population’s desires are fulfilled without undermining the ability of upcoming generations to meet their own necessities. A sustainable economy relies on the flow of resource usage and the value of externalities being created [9] and comprises three pillars: environmental, economic and social dimensions [10]. Thus, when assessing sustainable development, also nature impairment, as well as social welfare must be considered. Sustainable economic growth reveals the key to solving the ecological disasters, weather modifications, social and the economic crises affecting most nations [11,12]. In fact, a measure like the Index of Sustainable Economic Welfare [11,12,13,14,15] was developed to address such concerns.
Renewable energy contributes to energy resilience through its decentralized structure that lessens the effect caused by potential technical failures or extremist assaults which might significantly damage the national electricity grid, therewith redirecting oil profits that can run to governmentally insecure states [16]. In the context of outward migration noticed within rural regions, the operation of bioenergy factories may have positive effects on related rural labor markets [17]. According to Fang [18], an increase of renewable energy consumption by 1% drives a growth of real gross domestic product (GDP) by 0.120%, GDP per capita by 0.162%, per capita annual income of rural households by 0.444%, and per capita annual income of urban households by 0.368%. Bölük and Mert [19] proved that the greenhouse gas emissions in EU countries are reduced by approximately 1/2 per unit of renewable energy consumed over fossil energy consumption. However, Vass [20] contended that renewables can support the emissions reduction goal in 2050 by roughly 8.2%, which is better relative to the forest sector with a 5.3% share, but renewables cannot surpass forest carbon sequestration without government aid.
Renewable energy technologies are grouped into mainstream energy technologies (hydropower, wind energy, solar energy, biomass, biofuels, and geothermal energy) and emerging energy technologies (marine energy, concentrated solar photovoltaic, enhanced geothermal energy, cellulosic ethanol, and artificial photosynthesis) [21]. In order to be sustainable, a renewable resource should be boundless, but without harming the environment, whereas a sustainable energy should be inexpensive over an extended period, while satisfying the community desires and fitting with actual and future civil rules [22]. Pahle et al. [23] mentioned that renewable distribution may lead to short-term socio-economic benefits that supports the robust green growth since the renewable energy segment is crucial for the shift to a green economy [24] and Foster et al. [25] discussed the interplay amongst renewable energy diffusion and the value chains of fossil fuels. In this framework, the green paradox theory of Sinn [26] argues that a policy wishing for global warming reduction may actually hasten the usage of fossil fuels for the reason that holders will want to pull out and sell more fossil fuels whilst they are still expensive. Fourth, the carbon leakage theory [27] claims that if there is not a set of worldwide harmonized climate change directives, the manufacture of goods and services reliant on fossil fuels will shift to states with less severe environmental policies, in this manner balancing emission savings accrued elsewhere.
The Directive 2009/28/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council on the promotion of the use of energy from renewable sources [28] is enforced through two European Union (EU) compulsory goals, namely a 20% share of energy consumption from renewable sources and a 10% share of energy from renewable sources in transport, both by 2020. Notwithstanding, Jäger-Waldau [29] revealed structural impediments against the implementation of renewable energies, such as dependency on national conventional sources of energy and their supply network, combined with high primary investment. Thereby, Woo et al. [30] revealed geographical disparities on the topic of environmental efficiency, respectively considerable environmental efficiency related to the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) American countries relative to high standard deviation of OECD European states. Also, Reboredo [31] advocated discrepancy and contradictory temporal shapes in the share of renewable energies to the energy supply. Chontanawat et al. [32] noticed that energy is neutral as regards its influence on economic growth in the developing countries as compared to developed states. Howbeit, even if Chien and Hu [33] found that OECD economies registered higher technical efficiency than non-OECD economies, a higher share of renewable energy was uncovered in the total energy supply non-of OECD economies compared to OECD ones.
Moreover, even though renewable energy fits properly in several opportunity fields like socioeconomic progress, energy access, energy security, and climate change alleviation [34], the sustainability appraisal of energy technologies should not be overlooked [35]. The adverse effects of renewable energy threaten the wellbeing of inhabitants in the environs of the renewable energy sources facilities [36] via sound from wind turbines [37] or through the risk of glare by mirroring of straight sunlight from photovoltaic unit areas [38]. The research focus is here is twofold. First, the aim of the current study is to explore the influence of renewable energy, both overall and by type, on the sustainable economic growth of the 28 EU countries for the period spanning from 2003 to 2014. Subsequently, an empirical approach will address the causal relationship between primary production of renewable energies, energy dependence, and gross domestic product per capita. The literature on the relationship between renewable energy consumption and economic growth is quite extensive [7,8,18,19,39,40,41,42,43,44,45,46,47,48,49,50,51,52,53,54,55,56,57,58], studies on the link between biomass energy and economic growth also exist [59,60,61,62], as well as hydroelectricity consumption and economic growth [63,64]. Yildirim et al. [58] considered several renewable energy types, but for the case of U.S. Nevertheless, the current manuscript differs from previous research to some extent. Particularly, the novelty of this research ensues from the investigation of the effect related to every type of renewable energy, respectively biomass, hydropower, geothermal energy, wind power, and solar energy on gross domestic product per capita. Thereby, this paper also provides insights on the causal linkage between renewable energy production, energy dependence, and economic growth at the EU-28 level, instead of renewable energy consumption, gross fixed capital formation, and labor force as in previous studies [18,41,42,43,44,45,46,48,49,52,55,56,59,63,65].
The remainder of the article is organized as follows: Section 2 reviews the empirical literature on the renewable energy consumption-economic growth nexus. Section 3 describes the employed dataset and econometric methodology. Section 4 discusses the empirical results. The final section provides concluding remarks.

2. An Overview of Literature on Renewable Energy Consumption-Economic Growth Nexus

The causal relationship between renewable energy consumption and economic growth takes the form of four testable hypotheses, respectively feedback (bidirectional causality between energy consumption and economic growth), conservation (unidirectional causality from economic growth to energy consumption), growth (unidirectional causality from renewable energy consumption to economic growth), and neutrality (the lack of causality between energy consumption and economic growth) [42]. In addition, the environmental Kuznets curve (EKC) advises that environmental degradation rises with growing income up to a boundary stage over which ecological quality straighten with greater income per capita. Nevertheless, there was not achieved any unanimity towards energy-economic growth association [44] inasmuch as selected samples, explored states’ features, employed variables, and applied quantitative methods were varied [66].
Based on the estimation of a panel vector error correction model (PVECM) for twenty OECD countries over the period 1985–2005, Apergis and Payne [41] found both short-run and long-run bidirectional causality between renewable energy consumption and economic growth, being supported the feedback hypothesis. Similarly, analogous findings were exposed for six Central American countries over the period 1980–2006 [42], as well as 80 countries over the period 1990–2007 [43]. Bidirectional Granger causality between economic growth and renewable energy consumption was also noticed for Brazil, Russia, India, China, and South Africa (BRICS countries) over the period 1971–2010 [54], likewise for China for 1977–2011 [50]. By means of vector error correction model (VECM) Granger causality, Shahbaz et al. [55] confirmed the feedback effect in Pakistan for 1972Q1–2011Q4. The feedback hypothesis was supported withal for MENA Net Oil Importing Countries over 1980–2012 [48]. Likewise, Amri [40] reinforced the feedback connection in the case of 23 developed countries and 49 developing countries over 1990–2012. Koçak and Şarkgüneşi [49] for nine Black Sea and Balkan countries also proved the two-way causality link between renewable energy consumption and economic growth in 1990–2012 period.
Lise and Van Montfort [67] provided evidence for conservation hypothesis for the case of Turkey over the period 1970–2003, whereas also for Turkey over 1990–2010, based on the autoregressive distributed lag (ARDL) method and Toda-Yamamoto causality tests, Ocal and Aslan [52] revealed the conservation hypothesis for the link between renewable energy consumption and economic growth. Similarly, Sadorsky [53] exposed for 18 emerging countries over 1994–2003 that growth in real per capita income exhibits a positive and statistically significant effect on per capita renewable energy consumption. For the U.S. case for 1960–2007, Menyah and Wolde-Rufael [51] ascertained a unidirectional causality running from GDP to renewable energy consumption.
Bhattacharya et al. [44] supported the growth hypothesis forasmuch as within 57% of 38 top renewable energy consuming states over 1991–2012, renewable energy consumption exerted a positive impact on economic growth. In the same vein, Inglesi-Lotz [46] showed for 34 OECD countries a positive and statistically significant influence of renewable energy consumption to economic growth.
By employing the Toda-Yamamoto causality tests on U.S. data for the period 1949–2006, Payne [65] pointed out the lack of Granger-causality between renewable and non-renewable energy consumption and real GDP and claimed the neutrality hypothesis. The irregular and sparse use of renewable energy within Europe over 1997–2007 was established by Menegaki [8] since the estimated panel error correction model indicated the lack of short-run, as well as long-run Granger causality from renewable energy consumption to economic growth, thereby the neutrality hypothesis being acknowledged. Also, for the Italy from 1861 to 2000, Vaona [57] supported the neutrality hypothesis.
Other studies concluded mixed results, such as Huang et al. [45], which established for 82 countries classified as low income, lower middle income, upper middle income, and high income, from 1972 to 2002, the neutrality hypothesis for the low income category and the conservation hypothesis for the middle income group. Ozturk and Acaravci [68] employed the ARDL method for 1980–2006, along with the dynamic VEC model, and revealed the feedback hypothesis for Hungary, whilst the neutrality hypothesis was set for Albania, Bulgaria, Romania. Tugcu et al. [56] employed Hatemi-J causality tests for G7 countries over 1980–2009 and noticed the neutrality hypothesis for France, Italy, Canada, and U.S., feedback hypothesis for England and Japan, conservation hypothesis for Germany. Al-Mulali [39] explored through fully modified OLS more than 108 low income, lower middle income, upper middle income, and high income countries over 1980–2009 and established the bidirectional causality within 79% of countries, neutrality causality within 19% of the sample, and unidirectional causality from growth to renewable energy within 2% of states.
With reference to the literature on the types of renewable energy, Shahbaz et al. [62] confirmed the feedback hypothesis between biomass energy consumption and economic growth over 1991Q1–2015Q4, for BRICS region. Bilgili and Ozturk [59] noticed the growth hypothesis inasmuch as biomass energy consumption showed positive effects on economic growth in G7 countries for the period 1980–2009, as well as in 51 Sub-Sahara African states over 1980–2009 [60]. Yildirim et al. [58] employed the Toda-Yamamoto procedure and bootstrap-corrected causality test for U.S. over 1949–2010 and provided evidence for a causal link between biomass-waste-derived energy consumption and economic growth (growth hypothesis) and no causal association between growth and all of the other renewable energy types. Bildirici [61] explored the link between biomass energy consumption and economic growth within ten developing and emerging states and provided evidence over 1980–2009 towards long-run bidirectional causality for Argentina, Bolivia, Nicaragua, whilst long-run unidirectional causality from biomass energy consumption to GDP for Cuba, Costa Rica, El Salvador, Jamaica, Panama. Solarin and Ozturk [63] explored seven Latin America countries over 1970–2012 and supported the long-run bidirectional causality between hydroelectricity consumption and economic growth in Argentina and Venezuela, withal long-run unidirectional causality from hydroelectricity consumption to economic growth in Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Ecuador, and Peru. For a sample of the 10 major hydroelectricity consuming states during 1965–2012, Apergis et al. [64] documented for the pre-1988 period the unidirectional causality from real GDP per capita to hydroelectricity per capita, whilst bidirectional causality for the post-1988 period.
Another strand of literature revealed inconsistent results when alternative measures for sustainable income were employed as compared with the traditional examination of energy-GDP growth nexus. For instance, Menegaki and Tugcu [13] developed an Index of Sustainable Economic Welfare Growth (ISEW) for 42 Sub-Saharan African states over 1985–2013 covering the weighted consumption, non-defensive public expenditure, net capital growth, unpaid work benefit, depletion of natural environment, and the cost from social problems. By means of panel data cointegration and Granger causality, Menegaki and Tugcu [13] supported the feedback hypothesis when ISEW was used as proxy for sustainable economic welfare, but the neutrality hypothesis in case of GDP employment. Further, for 15 emerging economies during 1995–2013, Menegaki and Tugcu [14] proposed two measures of welfare: the first (BISEW) made up of adjusted personal consumption with durables, education and health expenditure, as well as net capital growth, whilst the second (SISEW) emerged by subtracting mineral, energy, and forest depletion, as well as damage related to carbon dioxide emissions, from BISEW. However, based on Granger causality and seemingly unrelated regression, Menegaki and Tugcu [14] concluded multifarious causality results. Likewise, for G7 states, over 1995–2013, Menegaki and Tugcu [11] computed a basic ISEW covering only economic variables, as well as a solid ISEW comprising the sum of economic and environmental variables. By applying a panel ARDL model, Menegaki and Tugcu [11] revealed the conservation hypothesis for GDP or basic ISEW per capita and energy consumption, but the feedback hypothesis in case of solid ISEW per capita and energy consumption. Withal, Menegaki and Tiwari [12] computed the ISEW for 20 American countries over 1990–2013 and followed quantile regression and fixed effects with PVECM approach, thus reinforcing the feedback hypothesis in case of ISEW framework, but the neutrality hypothesis for the GDP framework. In the same vein, for twenty European countries over 1995–2014, Gaspar et al. [15] confirmed the feedback hypothesis when using ISEW and the conservative hypothesis when using GDP.
Concerning the environmental Kuznets curve, for the Tunisian case during the period 1980–2009, Jebli and Youssef [47] did not support the EKC, the same conclusion being also stated by Özokcu and Özdemir [69] for 26 OECD countries with high-income levels, as well as for 52 emerging states over 1980–2010. On the contrary, Apergis et al. [70] confirmed the EKC hypothesis, but only for ten U.S. states over 1960–2010, Ahmad et al. [71] for Croatia over 1992Q1–2011Q1, Wang et al. [72] for China over 2000–2013, and Sinha and Bhattacharya [73] for 139 Indian cities during 2001–2013. Table 1 summarizes the literature regarding the relationship between renewable energy consumption and economic growth.
In could be remarked that the studies summarized within Table 1 provide scant evidence on the renewable energy consumption-economic growth nexus in EU-28 countries. Hence, the previously mentioned gap emphasizes our motivation for current paper and the study aims to contribute to the literature in this manner.

3. Data and Methodological Framework

3.1. Sample Selection and Variable Description

This paper follows panel data of EU-28 countries for the period 2003–2014, acquired from Eurostat—European Commission and World Development Indicators (WDI)—World Bank. The multivariate framework includes gross domestic product per capita as proxy for sustainable economic growth [8,18,19,32,40,45,46,47,49,50,53,55,59,64,67,68,69,72], renewable energy measures (both overall and by type), and country-level controls, as given in Table 2.

3.2. Econometric Approach

Primarily, our purpose is to estimate the effect of renewable energy, both overall and by type, on sustainable economic growth by means of panel data fixed-effects regression model, having the general specification as follows:
Y i t = α 0 + β 1 X i t + β 2 Z i t + ε i t i = 1 ,   2 ,   ,   28 ,   t = 2003 ,   2004 ,   ,   2014
where Y denotes the dependent variable, respectively gross domestic product per capita (logarithmic values), X signifies the explanatory variables towards renewable energy, overall and by type, Z represents the country-level control variables, α is the intercept, β 1 and β 2 are parameters, ε is the error term, i is the subscript of states, and t is the subscript of the time dimension. We have adopted a fixed-effects approach in order to overcome the omitted variable bias.
Onward, our goal is to investigate the linkages between renewable energy production (PRE), energy dependence (ED), and gross domestic product per capita (GDPC), through the Granger causality based on panel vector error correction model (PVECM), by following the procedure described in previous studies [8,41,42,43,46,48,53,62,67]. Therefore, we will assess the stationarity of the variables by the instrumentality of the Im, Pesaran and Shin (IPS) test developed by Im et al. [74] which allows for heterogeneous autoregressive coefficients. The equation employed in order to check for unit roots takes the following form:
y i t = ρ i y i t 1 + δ i X i t + ε i t i = 1 ,   2 ,   ,   28 ,   t = 2003 ,   2004 ,   ,   2014
where X i t depicts the exogenous variables comprising fixed effects or individual time trend; ρ i signifies the autoregressive coefficients, and ε i t shows the stationary error terms. However, the IPS test averages the augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) unit root tests and grant for various orders of serial correlation:
ε i t = j = 1 p i φ i j ε i t j + u i t
By substituting the third equation within the second equation, there ensues the form as below:
y i t = ρ i y i t 1 + j = 1 p i φ i j ε i t j + δ i X i t + u i t
where p i expresses the number of lags in the ADF regression. The null hypothesis supposes that each series in the panel dataset comprises a unit root, whilst the alternative hypothesis reveals that at least one of the individual series in the panel is stationary. Besides, several stationarity tests are executed, such as Levin, Lin & Chu (LLC), Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF), Phillips-Perron (PP).
Further, we will employ the heterogeneous panel cointegration test developed by Pedroni [75,76] that permits for cross-section interdependence with different individual effects:
G D P C i t = α i + δ i t + γ 1 i P R E i t + γ 2 i E D i t + ε i t i = 1 ,   2 ,   ,   28 ,   t = 2003 ,   2004 ,   ,   2014
where the parameters α i and δ i permit for country-specific fixed effects and deterministic trends, ε i t denotes the estimated residuals which depicts deviations from the long-run relationship. The null hypothesis reveals the lack of cointegration, respectively non-stationary residuals.
The next step supposes the estimation of panel fully modified OLS (FMOLS) and dynamic OLS (DOLS) as in [44,49,59,60]. Lastly, we estimate the PVECM in order to perform the Granger-causality tests. As such, we carry the two-step procedure of Engle-Granger by estimating the long-run model described by the fifth equation in order to get the estimated residuals, whereas by formulating the lagged residuals from the fifth equation as the error correction term (ECT), we estimate the following dynamic error correction model:
Δ G D P C i t = α 1 j + k = 1 q φ 11 i k Δ G D P C i t k + k = 1 q φ 12 i k Δ P R E i t k + k = 1 q φ 13 i k Δ E D i t k + λ 1 i ε i t 1 + u 1 i t
Δ P R E i t = α 2 j + k = 1 q φ 21 i k Δ G D P C i t k + k = 1 q φ 22 i k Δ P R E i t k + k = 1 q φ 23 i k Δ E D i t k + λ 2 i ε i t 1 + u 2 i t
Δ E D i t = α 3 j + k = 1 q φ 31 i k Δ G D P C i t k + k = 1 q φ 32 i k Δ P R E i t k + k = 1 q φ 33 i k Δ E D i t k + λ 3 i ε i t 1 + u 3 i t
where Δ denotes the first-difference operator, q is the lag length set at one according to likelihood ratio tests, and u reveals the serially uncorrelated error term.

4. Empirical Findings

4.1. Descriptive Statistics, Correlation Analysis, and Stationarity Investigation

Table 3 provides summary statistics of the variables employed within the empirical study. We acknowledge that the mean share of renewable energy in gross final energy consumption is 15%, whereas the mean share of renewable energy in fuel consumption of transport is 3%, which are below the thresholds of 20%, respectively 10% as set by the EU Directive 2009/28/EC [28]. Moreover, we notice that primary production of solid biofuels, excluding charcoal, alongside primary production of hydropower register the highest mean values amongst renewable energies, whilst primary production of solar photovoltaic energy, primary production of solar thermal energy, as well as primary production of biogasoline, and primary production of other liquid biofuels reveal the lowest mean values. Consequently, EU-28 countries should consider more solar electricity production which is a sustainable and quickly accessible energy source within urban settings [77], since it represents a clean substitute of fossil fuel based electricity does not cause air or water pollution, safeness of public health, and without shocks as regards electricity price. In addition, biogasoline or “green” gasoline is low-priced and ecologically responsible [78].
The correlations between selected variables are disclosed in Table 4. Accordingly, we notice high correlations between the measures concerning renewable energy, but we will employ these variables within distinct panel data regression models in order to avoid the multicollinearity issue.
Table 5 reveals the output of panel unit root examination. We establish that selected variables are first order stationary. Therefore, we will inspect the cointegration relationship and if such a connection emerges then a PVECM in order to reveal the long-run association is justified [79].

4.2. Panel Data Regression Models Results

The results of panel data regression models with reference to the influence of renewable energy (overall) on sustainable economic growth are revealed in Table 6. Hence, we notice the positive influence of renewable energy on gross domestic product per capita (Equations (1)–(5)), except for final renewable energies consumption in households (Equation (6)). Besides, the share of renewable energy in gross final energy consumption shows the highest influence on economic growth among the variables towards renewable energy (overall). As such, Equation (3) reveals that if there is an increase by 1% of the share of renewable energy in gross final energy consumption, the effect would be to increase the gross domestic product per capita by 1.61%. As regards the explanatory power of the estimated models, between 9% and 17% of the variation in the economic growth is explained by the renewable energy (overall) and country-level controls. Thereby, also renowned as eco-friendly sources of energy or green energy, such energy sources drive sustainable growth through energy and financial savings achieved by replacing non-renewable and costly energy with low-priced renewable energy sources, also leading to a lesser depletion of natural resources. Besides the fact that the negative effect on the environment does not register the similar magnitude as in case of non-renewable systems, there is revealed an enlarged job creation required for developing, setting up, and operating with renewable energy systems.
Similarly, the costs related to the production, diffusion, supply, and maintenance of renewable energy grids are reduced, whereas the multifarious supply implies a lower risk as regards a full loss of power. Therewith, due to the expansive fossil fuel based power systems within rural regions, using renewable energy sources in these areas will uphold the access to basic services as illumination, communications, or water.
Table 7 shows the effect of biomass energy on gross domestic product per capita. Therefore, we acknowledge the positive influence of every kind of biomass energy on sustainable economic growth (Equations (1–5)), apart from primary production of other liquid biofuels (Equation (6)). We notice that the primary production of solid biofuels, excluding charcoal, registers the highest influence on economic growth among biomass energy types. Equation (1) shows that for a 1% increase of the primary production of solid biofuels, the gross domestic product per capita will rise by 0.16%. Based on the values related to the coefficient of determination, the proportion of variance in the economic growth that can be explained by the biomass energy varies between 9% and 28%. Founded on living matter such as solid, vegetal, or animal waste, easily accessible in rural and urban regions, biomass energy is transformed in disposable energy kinds like methane gas or transport fuels as ethanol and biodiesel. Being a carbon neutral renewable energy, biomass does not harm the atmosphere, also showing a lower level of sulphur dioxide emanations that avoids acid rain incidence.
Biomass affords sustainable growth through decreasing financial and ecological expenditures concerning transport and contributes to national energy security by diminishing the reliance on fossil fuels. In addition, biomass lessens landfills by converting the waste that is detrimental to the environment into somewhat valuable, while the rural development is spurred by agriculture and forestry wastes. The output of panel data fixed-effects regressions as regards the influence of hydropower, geothermal energy, wind, and solar energy on sustainable economic growth are pointed out in Table 8.
We acknowledge that primary production of hydropower shows a higher influence on economic growth than geothermal energy, wind power, and solar energy. Equation (1) suggests that a 1% increase in the primary production of hydropower increases gross domestic product per capita by 0.05%. However, the estimated models explain between 10% and 38% of the variation in the economic growth. Thereby, we reinforce the positive influence of renewable energy on economic growth (Equations (1–5)), with the exception of primary production of solar photovoltaic energy (Equation (6)). Besides, amongst all renewable energy types, hydropower is the least expensive and the most trustworthy and efficient. However, hydropower is narrowed by geography, geothermal energy requires tectonic activity, whereas wind, alongside solar energy are irregular. Instead, due to their spreading and modularity [16], wind and solar energy sources are less exposed to extensive breakdowns so that a mighty climatic incident in one setting will not take off power within overall area. Green energy show more resilience towards undesirable weather circumstances than fossil fuels. Per se, wind energy, as well as solar photovoltaic systems reveals no reliance on water in order to produce electricity, consequently the risks related to water insufficiency being alleviated.
Further, as regards the influence of country-level controls, we emphasize for the most part of the estimated regressions, the positive influence of energy dependence, greenhouse gas emissions, and research and development expenditure on gross domestic product per capita. Besides, the explanatory power of the estimated models is not so high due to large variance among EU-28 states as regards renewable energy utilization.

4.3. Cointegration and Causality Examination

The cointegration examination as proposed by Pedroni [75,76] by means of two tests (panel and group) is shown in Table 9. The panel tests are founded on the within-dimension form, which comprises four statistics, respectively panel v, panel rho, panel PP, and panel ADF that pool the autoregressive coefficients across dissimilar states for the unit root checks on the estimated residuals. The group tests are established on the between dimension form which cover three statistics: group rho, group PP, and group ADF, that are set on means of the individual autoregressive coefficients related with the unit root checks of the residuals for each state in the panel [41,42,43,46,48]. As such, panel ADF and group ADF statistic support the cointegration relationship.
In addition, the output of a Kao test [80] is shown in Table 10. This test estimates the homogeneous cointegration association by pooled regression permitting for individual fixed effects [48]. Based on the ADF panel cointegration check where the vectors of cointegration are homogeneous, we notice the hypothesis of cointegration among the selected variables.
Also, the Johansen [81] approach with Fisher effect entitled Fisher-type panel cointegration test was performed. The outcome (Table 11) lets us reject the null hypothesis of no-cointegration. Therefore, the empirical findings from Table 9, Table 10 and Table 11 document the presence of a long-term equilibrium between primary production of renewable energies, energy dependence, and gross domestic product per capita.
Since the hypothesis of the presence of a long-term relationship was confirmed, the next stage involves estimating this connection. The results from Table 12 reveals that a 1 percent increase in primary production of renewable energies increases gross domestic product per capita by 0.06 percent (in case of FMOLS) or 0.05 percent (in case of DOLS).
The direction of causal association between primary production of renewable energies, energy dependence, and gross domestic product per capita is examined by employing the PVECM Granger causality and results are conveyed in Table 13. In fact, there are showed the results of estimation of both the short- and the long-term dynamics as presented theoretically by Equations (6)–(8). With respect to Equation (6), primary production of renewable energies and energy dependence has a statistically insignificant impact on gross domestic product per capita in the short-run. In regards to Equation (7), gross domestic product per capita has a positive and statistically significant influence on primary production of renewable energies in the short-run, therefore the conservation hypothesis being supported similar [51,52,53,67]. Concerning Equation (8), primary production of renewable energies positively influence energy dependence in the short-run. With respect to the long-run causality, the results provide support for a unidirectional causality running from sustainable economic growth and energy dependence to the primary production of renewable energies, the conservation hypothesis being reinforced.

5. Concluding Remarks and Policy Implications

Energy is indispensable for life, but currently the main source of energy is still represented by fossil fuels whose supply is limited, and their extraction, conversion and transport cause substantial land and water pollution, also being responsible for global warming. However, renewable energies are limitless, the risk of climate alteration is reduced, and they also contribute to job creation. The current paper documented, by means of panel data fixed-effects regression models, for EU-28 states over the period 2003–2014, that primary production of renewable energies, gross inland renewable energies consumption, share of renewable energy in gross final energy consumption, share of renewable energy in fuel consumption of transport, and electricity generated from renewable sources, positively influence gross domestic product per capita. As well, biomass energy in the form of primary production of solid biofuels, biogas, municipal waste, biogasoline, and biodiesels positively influence sustainable economic growth. Likewise, we provide evidence for a positive influence of hydropower, geothermal energy, wind, and solar energy on sustainable economic growth. However, biomass energy revealed the highest influence on economic growth among the rest of renewable energy types. Besides, current study found a long-term relationship between primary production of renewable energies, energy dependence, and gross domestic product per capita. By estimating panel fully modified and dynamic ordinary least squares regressions, the positive influence of primary production of renewable energies on economic growth was noticed. In addition, the conservation hypothesis was acknowledged, being identified both a short-run and long-run unidirectional causal relationship running from gross domestic product per capita to the primary production of renewable energies.
Consistent with EU Directive 2009/28/EC, we acknowledge that EU-28 states did not achieve yet the targets set for the share of renewable energy in gross final energy consumption and for the share of renewable energy in transport fuel consumption. As policy implications, the cooperation mechanisms among EU-28 states, in form of statistical transfers, joint projects, or joint support schemes, should be intensified. In fact, appropriate connections among countries will mitigate the risk of electricity failures, therewith reducing the demand for setting other power plants and enhancing the management of fluctuating solar or wind renewable energies. Hence, binding the electricity framework at EU-28 level will develop a resilient energy infrastructure that could ensure the electricity supply security, as well as a better incorporation of renewable energy. Besides, reducing the increased dependence on imported fossil fuels from non-EU countries will lessen the energy price volatility and will contribute to the decarbonisation strategy. As a final point, potential venues for future research will be to expand the PVECM framework to each type of renewable energy. In addition, analyzing the renewable energy consumption-economic growth nexus by means of non-linear models will be further considered. Also, considering ISEW as an alternative measure of GDP will not be overlooked.

Author Contributions

These authors contributed equally to this work. All authors read and approved the final manuscript.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Sebri, M. Use renewables to be cleaner: Meta-analysis of the renewable energy consumption-economic growth nexus. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2015, 42, 657–665. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Terrapon-Pfaff, J.; Dienst, C.; Konig, J.; Ortiz, W. A cross-sectional review: Impacts and sustainability of small-scale renewable energy projects in developing countries. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2014, 40, 1–10. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Bilen, K.; Ozyurt, O.; Bakirci, K.; Karsli, S.; Erdogan, S.; Yimaz, M.; Comakli, O. Energy production, consumption, and environmental pollution for sustainable development: A case study in Turkey. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2008, 12, 1529–1561. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Gottschamer, L.; Zhang, Q. Interactions of factors impacting implementation and sustainability of renewable energy sourced electricity. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2016, 65, 164–174. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. U.S. Energy Information Administration. International Energy Outlook 2016; U.S. Energy Information Administration: Washington, DC, USA, 2016.
  6. Vaona, A. The effect of renewable energy generation on import demand. Renew. Energy 2016, 86, 354–359. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Alper, A.; Oguz, O. The role of renewable energy consumption in economic growth: Evidence from asymmetric causality. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2016, 60, 953–959. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Menegaki, A.N. Growth and renewable energy in europe: A random effect model with evidence for neutrality hypothesis. Energy Econ. 2011, 33, 257–263. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Beça, P.; Santos, R. Measuring sustainable welfare: A new approach to the isew. Ecol. Econ. 2010, 69, 810–819. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Moldan, B.; Janouskova, S.; Hak, T. How to understand and measure environmental sustainability: Indicators and targets. Ecol. Indic. 2012, 17, 4–13. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Menegaki, A.N.; Tugcu, C.T. Energy consumption and sustainable economic welfare in G7 countries; A comparison with the conventional nexus. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2017, 69, 892–901. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Menegaki, A.N.; Tiwari, A.K. The index of sustainable economic welfare in the energy-growth nexus for American countries. Ecol. Indic. 2017, 72, 494–509. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Menegaki, A.N.; Tugcu, C.T. Rethinking the energy-growth nexus: Proposing an index of sustainable economic welfare for sub-saharan Africa. Energy Res. Soc. Sci. 2016, 17, 147–159. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Menegaki, A.N.; Tugcu, C.T. The sensitivity of growth, conservation, feedback & neutrality hypotheses to sustainability accounting. Energy Sustain. Dev. 2016, 34, 77–87. [Google Scholar]
  15. Gaspar, J.S.; Marques, A.C.; Fuinhas, J.A. The traditional energy-growth nexus: A comparison between sustainable development and economic growth approaches. Ecol. Indic. 2017, 75, 286–296. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Valentine, S.V. Emerging symbiosis: Renewable energy and energy security. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2011, 15, 4572–4578. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Domac, J.; Richards, L.K.; Risovic, S. Socio-economic drivers in implementing bioenergy projects. Biomass Bioenergy 2005, 28, 97–106. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Fang, Y.P. Economic welfare impacts from renewable energy consumption: The China experience. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2011, 15, 5120–5128. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Bölük, G.; Mert, M. Fossil & renewable energy consumption, GHGS (greenhouse gases) and economic growth: Evidence from a panel of EU (European Union) countries. Energy 2014, 74, 439–446. [Google Scholar]
  20. Vass, M.M. Renewable energies cannot compete with forest carbon sequestration to cost-efficiently meet the EU carbon target for 2050. Renew. Energy 2017, 107, 164–180. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Hussain, A.; Arif, S.M.; Aslam, M. Emerging renewable and sustainable energy technologies: State of the art. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2017, 71, 12–28. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Keleş, S.; Bilgen, S. Renewable energy sources in turkey for climate change mitigation and energy sustainability. Renew. Sustain Energy Rev. 2012, 16, 5199–5206. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Pahle, M.; Pachauri, S.; Steinbacher, K. Can the green economy deliver it all? Experiences of renewable energy policies with socio-economic objectives. Appl. Energy 2016, 179, 1331–1341. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Gasparatos, A.; Doll, C.N.H.; Esteban, M.; Ahmed, A.; Olang, T.A. Renewable energy and biodiversity: Implications for transitioning to a green economy. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2017, 70, 161–184. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Foster, E.; Contestabile, M.; Blazquez, J.; Manzano, B.; Workman, M.; Shah, N. The unstudied barriers to widespread renewable energy deployment: Fossil fuel price responses. Energy Policy 2017, 103, 258–264. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Sinn, H.W. Public policies against global warming: A supply side approach. Int. Tax Public Financ. 2008, 15, 360–394. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Tirole, J. Some political economy of global warming. Econ. Energy Environ. Policy 2012, 1, 121–132. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. European Union. Directive 2009/28/EC of the european parliament and of the council of 23 april 2009 on the promotion of the use of energy from renewable sources and amending and subsequently repealing directives 2001/77/EC and 2003/30/EC (text with EEA relevance). Off. J. Eur. Union 2009, 5, 2009. [Google Scholar]
  29. Jäger-Waldau, A. Photovoltaics and renewable energies in europe. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2007, 11, 1414–1437. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Woo, C.; Chung, Y.; Chun, D.; Seo, H.; Hong, S. The static and dynamic environmental efficiency of renewable energy: A malmquist index analysis of OECD countries. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2015, 47, 367–376. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Reboredo, J.C. Renewable energy contribution to the energy supply: Is there convergence across countries? Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2015, 45, 290–295. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Chontanawat, J.; Hunt, L.C.; Pierse, R. Does energy consumption cause economic growth? Evidence from a systematic study of over 100 countries. J. Policy Model. 2008, 30, 209–220. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Chien, T.; Hu, J.L. Renewable energy and macroeconomic efficiency of OECD and non-OECD economies. Energy Policy 2007, 35, 3606–3615. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Sen, S.; Ganguly, S. Opportunities, barriers and issues with renewable energy development—A discussion. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2017, 69, 1170–1181. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Carrera, D.G.; Mack, A. Sustainability assessment of energy technologies via social indicators: Results of a survey among european energy experts. Energy Policy 2010, 38, 1030–1039. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Botelho, A.; Pinto, L.M.C.; Lourenco-Gomes, L.; Valente, M.; Sousa, S. Social sustainability of renewable energy sources in electricity production: An application of the contingent valuation method. Sustain. Cities Soc. 2016, 26, 429–437. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Van den Berg, G.P. The beat is getting stronger: The effect of atmospheric stability on low frequency modulated sound of wind turbines. J. Low Freq. Noise Vib. Act. Control 2005, 24, 1–23. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Chiabrando, R.; Fabrizio, E.; Garnero, G. The territorial and landscape impacts of photovoltaic systems: Definition of impacts and assessment of the glare risk. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2009, 13, 2441–2451. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Al-Mulali, U.; Fereidouni, H.G.; Lee, J.Y.; Sab, C.N.B.C. Examining the bi-directional long run relationship between renewable energy consumption and GDP growth. Renew. Sustain Energy Rev. 2013, 22, 209–222. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Amri, F. Intercourse across economic growth, trade and renewable energy consumption in developing and developed countries. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2017, 69, 527–534. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Apergis, N.; Payne, J.E. Renewable energy consumption and economic growth: Evidence from a panel of OECD countries. Energy Policy 2010, 38, 656–660. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Apergis, N.; Payne, J.E. The renewable energy consumption-growth nexus in central America. Appl. Energy 2011, 88, 343–347. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Apergis, N.; Payne, J.E. Renewable and non-renewable energy consumption-growth nexus: Evidence from a panel error correction model. Energy Econ. 2012, 34, 733–738. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Bhattacharya, M.; Paramati, S.R.; Ozturk, I.; Bhattacharya, S. The effect of renewable energy consumption on economic growth: Evidence from top 38 countries. Appl. Energy 2016, 162, 733–741. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Huang, B.N.; Hwang, M.J.; Yang, C.W. Causal relationship between energy consumption and GDP growth revisited: A dynamic panel data approach. Ecol. Econ. 2008, 67, 41–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Inglesi-Lotz, R. The impact of renewable energy consumption to economic growth: A panel data application. Energy Econ. 2016, 53, 58–63. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Jebli, M.B.; Youssef, S.B. The environmental kuznets curve, economic growth, renewable and non-renewable energy, and trade in Tunisia. Renew. Sustain Energy Rev. 2015, 47, 173–185. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Kahia, M.; Aïssa, M.S.B.; Lanouar, C. Renewable and non-renewable energy use—economic growth nexus: The case of mena net oil importing countries. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2017, 71, 127–140. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Koçak, E.; Şarkgüneşi, A. The renewable energy and economic growth nexus in black sea and balkan countries. Energy Policy 2017, 100, 51–57. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Lin, B.Q.; Moubarak, M. Renewable energy consumption—economic growth nexus for China. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2014, 40, 111–117. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Menyah, K.; Wolde-Rufael, Y. CO2 emissions, nuclear energy, renewable energy and economic growth in the us. Energy Policy 2010, 38, 2911–2915. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Ocal, O.; Aslan, A. Renewable energy consumption-economic growth nexus in Turkey. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2013, 28, 494–499. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Sadorsky, P. Renewable energy consumption and income in emerging economies. Energy Policy 2009, 37, 4021–4028. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Sebri, M.; Ben-Salha, O. On the causal dynamics between economic growth, renewable energy consumption, CO2 emissions and trade openness: Fresh evidence from BRICS countries. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2014, 39, 14–23. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Shahbaz, M.; Loganathan, N.; Zeshan, M.; Zaman, K. Does renewable energy consumption add in economic growth? An application of auto-regressive distributed lag model in Pakistan. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2015, 44, 576–585. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Tugcu, C.T.; Ozturk, I.; Aslan, A. Renewable and non-renewable energy consumption and economic growth relationship revisited: Evidence from G7 countries. Energy Econ. 2012, 34, 1942–1950. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Vaona, A. Granger non-causality tests between (non)renewable energy consumption and output in Italy since 1861: The (ir)relevance of structural breaks. Energy Policy 2012, 45, 226–236. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Yildirim, E.; Sarac, S.; Asian, A. Energy consumption and economic growth in the USA: Evidence from renewable energy. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2012, 16, 6770–6774. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Bilgili, F.; Ozturk, I. Biomass energy and economic growth nexus in G7 countries: Evidence from dynamic panel data. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2015, 49, 132–138. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Ozturk, I.; Bilgili, F. Economic growth and biomass consumption nexus: Dynamic panel analysis for sub-sahara African countries. Appl. Energy 2015, 137, 110–116. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Bildirici, M.E. Economic growth and biomass energy. Biomass Bioenergy 2013, 50, 19–24. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  62. Shahbaz, M.; Rasool, G.; Ahmed, K.; Mahalik, M.K. Considering the effect of biomass energy consumption on economic growth: Fresh evidence from BRICS region. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2016, 60, 1442–1450. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  63. Solarin, S.A.; Ozturk, I. On the causal dynamics between hydroelectricity consumption and economic growth in Latin America countries. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2015, 52, 1857–1868. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  64. Apergis, N.; Chang, T.; Gupta, R.; Ziramba, E. Hydroelectricity consumption and economic growth nexus: Evidence from a panel of ten largest hydroelectricity consumers. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2016, 62, 318–325. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  65. Payne, J.E. On the dynamics of energy consumption and output in the US. Appl. Energy 2009, 86, 575–577. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  66. Ozturk, I. A literature survey on energy-growth nexus. Energy Policy 2010, 38, 340–349. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  67. Lise, W.; Van Montfort, K. Energy consumption and GDP in Turkey: Is there a co-integration relationship? Energy Econ. 2007, 29, 1166–1178. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  68. Ozturk, I.; Acaravci, A. The causal relationship between energy consumption and gdp in Albania, Bulgaria, Hungary and Romania: Evidence from ARDL bound testing approach. Appl. Energy 2010, 87, 1938–1943. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  69. Özokcu, S.; Özdemir, Ö. Economic growth, energy, and environmental Kuznets curve. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2017, 72, 639–647. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  70. Apergis, N.; Christou, C.; Gupta, R. Are there environmental Kuznets curves for us state-level CO2 emissions? Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2017, 69, 551–558. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  71. Ahmad, N.; Du, L.; Lu, J.; Wang, J.; Li, H.Z.; Hashmi, M.Z. Modelling the CO2 emissions and economic growth in croatia: Is there any environmental Kuznets curve? Energy 2017, 123, 164–172. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  72. Wang, Y.; Zhang, C.; Lu, A.; Li, L.; He, Y.; Tojo, J.; Zhu, X. A disaggregated analysis of the environmental kuznets curve for industrial CO2 emissions in china. Appl. Energy 2017, 190, 172–180. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  73. Sinha, A.; Bhattacharya, J. Estimation of environmental kuznets curve for SO2 emission: A case of Indian cities. Ecol. Indic. 2017, 72, 881–894. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  74. Im, K.S.; Pesaran, M.H.; Shin, Y. Testing for unit roots in heterogeneous panels. J. Econom. 2003, 115, 53–74. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  75. Pedroni, P. Critical values for cointegration tests in heterogeneous panels with multiple regressors. Oxf. Bull. Econ. Stat. 1999, 61, 653–670. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  76. Pedroni, P. Fully modified ols for heterogeneous cointegrated panels. In Nonstationary Panels, Panel Cointegration, and Dynamic Panels; Emerald Group Publishing Limited: Bingley, UK, 2000; Volume 15, pp. 93–130. [Google Scholar]
  77. Lau, K.K.L.; Lindberg, F.; Johansson, E.; Rasmussen, M.I.; Thorsson, S. Investigating solar energy potential in tropical urban environment: A case study of dar es salaam, tanzania. Sustain. Cities Soc. 2017, 30, 118–127. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  78. Hassan, S.N.; Sani, Y.M.; Aziz, A.R.A.; Sulaiman, N.M.N.; Daud, W.M.A.W. Biogasoline: An out-of-the-box solution to the food-for-fuel and land-use competitions. Energy Convers. Manag. 2015, 89, 349–367. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  79. Ozturk, I.; Uddin, G.S. Causality among carbon emissions, energy consumption and growth in India. Ekonomska Istraživanja 2012, 25, 752–775. [Google Scholar]
  80. Kao, C. Spurious regression and residual-based tests for cointegration in panel data. J. Econom. 1999, 90, 1–44. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  81. Johansen, S. Estimation and hypothesis-testing of cointegration vectors in gaussian vector autoregressive models. J. Econom. Soc. 1991, 59, 1551–1580. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Table 1. Previous related studies on renewable energy consumption and economic growth.
Table 1. Previous related studies on renewable energy consumption and economic growth.
StudyPeriodDatasetEstimation TechniqueOutcome
Amri [40]1990–201272 countriesTwo-step GMMFeedback
Hypothesis
Apergis and Payne [41]1985–200520 OECD countriesPVECM
Apergis and Payne [42]1980–20066 Central American countriesPVECM
Apergis and Payne [43]1990–200780 countriesPVECM
Kahia et al. [48]1980–2012MENA Net Oil Importing CountriesPVECM
Koçak and Şarkgüneşi [49]1990–20129 Black Sea and Balkan countriesPanel cointegration and heterogeneous causality
Lin and Moubarak [50]1977–2011ChinaARDL, Johansen cointegration, Granger causality
Sebri and Ben-Salha [54]1971–2010BRICS countriesARDL and VECM
Shahbaz et al. [55]1972Q1–2011Q4PakistanARDL and VECM
Shahbaz et al. [62]1991Q1–2015Q4BRICS regionPVECM
Menyah and Wolde-Rufael [51]1960–2007U.S.Toda-Yamamoto causalityConservation Hypothesis
Ocal and Aslan [52]1990–2010TurkeyARDL and Toda-Yamamoto causality
Sadorsky [53]1994–200318 emerging countriesPanel cointegration
Lise and Van Montfort [67]1970–2003TurkeyECM
Bhattacharya et al. [44]1991–201238 top renewable energy consuming statesHeterogeneous panel estimationsGrowth Hypothesis
Inglesi-Lotz [46]1990–201034 OECD countriesPedroni cointegration
Bilgili and Ozturk [59]1980–2009G7 countriesPanel cointegration, Conventional OLS, DOLS
Ozturk and Bilgili [60]1980–200951 Sub-Sahara AfricanPanel cointegration, Conventional OLS, DOLS
Menegaki [8]1997–200727 European countriesPanel error correction modelNeutrality Hypothesis
Vaona [57]1861–2000ItalyGranger non-causality
Payne [65]1949–2006U.S.Toda-Yamamoto causality
Menegaki and Tugcu [11]1995–2013G7 statesARDLMixed Results
Menegaki and Tiwari [12]1990–201320 American countriesQuantile regression, Fixed effects model and PVECM
Menegaki and Tugcu [13]1985–201342 Sub-Saharan African statesPanel cointegration and Granger causality
Menegaki and Tugcu [14]1995–201315 emerging economiesGranger causality and seemingly unrelated regression
Gaspar et al. [15]1995–201420 European statesPanel-corrected standard errors and Fixed effects vector decomposition estimators
Al-mulali [39]1980–2009108 countriesFMOLS
Huang et al. [45]1972–200282 statesSystem GMM and PVAR
Tugcu et al. [56]1980–2009G7 countriesARDL and Hatemi J causality
Yildirim et al. [58]1949–2010U.S.Toda-Yamamoto and Bootstrap-corrected causality
Bildirici [61]1980–200910 developing and emerging statesARDL and Dynamic ECM
Solarin and Ozturk [63]1970–20127 Latin America countriesVECM
Apergis et al. [64]1965–201210 major hydroelectricity consuming statesNonlinear panel smooth transition VECM
Ozturk and Acaravci [68]1980–2006Albania, Bulgaria, Hungary, RomaniaARDL and VECM
Table 2. Exhibition of the variables.
Table 2. Exhibition of the variables.
VariablesDescriptionPeriodSource
Variables towards sustainable economic growth (dependent variables)
GDPCGross domestic product per capita (constant 2010 U.S. $), logarithmic values.2003–2014WDI [NY.GDP.PCAP.KD]
Variables towards renewable energy and country-level controls (explanatory variables)
Variables towards renewable energy (overall)
PREPrimary production of renewable energies (1000 tonnes of oil equivalent), logarithmic values.2003–2014Eurostat [ten00081]
CREGross inland renewable energies consumption (1000 tonnes of oil equivalent), logarithmic values.2003–2014Eurostat [tsdcc320]
SRE_GFECShare of renewable energy in gross final energy consumption (%).2004–2014Eurostat [t2020_31]
SRE_FCTShare of renewable energy in fuel consumption of transport (%).2004–2014Eurostat [tsdcc340]
EGRSElectricity generated from renewable sources (% of gross electricity consumption).2004–2014Eurostat [tsdcc330]
FECFinal renewable energies consumption in households (% of the total consumption).2003–2014Eurostat [t2020_rk210]
Variables towards renewable energy (by type)
Biomass
SBIOFUELSPrimary production of solid biofuels, excluding charcoal (1000 tonnes of oil equivalent), logarithmic values.2003–2014Eurostat [ten00081]
BGASPrimary production of biogas (1000 tonnes of oil equivalent), logarithmic values.2003–2014Eurostat [ten00081]
MWPrimary production of municipal waste, renewable (1000 tonnes of oil equivalent), logarithmic values.2003–2014Eurostat [ten00081]
BGASOLINEPrimary production of biogasoline (1000 tonnes of oil equivalent), logarithmic values.2003–2014Eurostat [ten00081]
BDIESELSPrimary production of biodiesels (1000 tonnes of oil equivalent), logarithmic values.2003–2014Eurostat [ten00081]
OLBPrimary production of other liquid biofuels (1000 tonnes of oil equivalent), logarithmic values. 2003–2014Eurostat [ten00081]
Hydropower
HYDROPrimary production of hydropower (1000 tonnes of oil equivalent), logarithmic values.2003–2014Eurostat [ten00081]
Geothermal energy
GEOTHERMALPrimary production of geothermal energy (1000 tonnes of oil equivalent), logarithmic values.2003–2014Eurostat [ten00081]
Wind power
WINDPrimary production of wind power (1000 tonnes of oil equivalent), logarithmic values.2003–2014Eurostat [ten00081]
Solar energy
SOLAR_TPrimary production of solar thermal energy (1000 tonnes of oil equivalent), logarithmic values.2003–2014Eurostat [ten00081]
SOLAR_PPrimary production of solar photovoltaic energy (1000 tonnes of oil equivalent), logarithmic values.2003–2014Eurostat [ten00081]
Country-level control variables
EDEnergy dependence of a certain country (%), assessing the level of reliance upon imports so as to achieve its energy requirements.2003–2014Eurostat [tsdcc310]
GGEGreenhouse gas emissions (in CO2 equivalent) indexed to 1990, logarithmic values.2003–2014Eurostat [tsdcc100]
PETPollutant emissions from transport, nitrogen oxides (index, 2000 = 100), logarithmic values.2003–2014Eurostat [t2020_rk300]
RPResource productivity (purchasing power standard per kilogram), as the ratio between gross domestic product and domestic material consumption.2003–2014Eurostat [tsdpc100]
RDResearch and development expenditure (% of GDP).2003–2014WDI [GB.XPD.RSDV.GD.ZS]
LFLabor force, total, logarithmic values.2003–2014WDI [SL.TLF.TOTL.IN]
Table 3. Summary statistics of the variables (raw data).
Table 3. Summary statistics of the variables (raw data).
VariablesObsMeanStd. Dev.MinMax
Variables towards sustainable economic growth
GDPC33631,663.8520,449.344864.61110,001.05
Variables towards renewable energy (overall)
PRE3365359.616653.160.3036,017.90
CRE3365502.686837.680.3035,406.30
SRE_GFEC3080.150.110.000.53
SRE_FCT3080.030.030.000.22
EGRS3080.200.170.000.70
FEC3340.190.140.000.52
Variables towards renewable energy (by type)
Biomass
SBIOFUELS3362720.082915.340.0011,424.70
BGAS333285.51857.350.007434.30
MW333262.99488.780.003037.00
BGASOLINE33349.77100.510.00503.40
BDIESELS333230.09503.490.003042.60
OLB33320.2279.960.00833.80
Hydropower, geothermal energy, wind, and solar energy
HYDRO3361029.011576.470.006786.90
GEOTHERMAL333201.48918.080.005235.00
WIND336419.16890.480.004931.80
SOLAR_T33662.56216.950.002400.90
SOLAR_P33586.95338.690.003100.30
Country-level control variables
ED3360.560.28−0.501.04
GGE33692.1630.3740.63171.25
PET33684.2320.7440.40138.30
RP3361.480.720.473.52
RD3360.010.010.000.04
LF3368,622,532.4910,953,756.15159,601.0042,755,645.00
Source: Authors’ computations. Notes: For the definition of variables, please see Table 2.
Table 4. Correlation matrix.
Table 4. Correlation matrix.
Variables(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)(8)(9)(10)(11)(12)
(1) GDPC1
(2) PRE0.081
(3) CRE0.11 *1.00 ***1
(4) SRE_GFEC−0.080.42 ***0.40 ***1
(5) SRE_FCT0.21 ***0.38 ***0.39 ***0.39 ***1
(6) EGRS0.080.47 ***0.46 ***0.83 ***0.39 ***1
(7) FEC−0.56 ***0.18 **0.15 **0.61 ***−0.110.43 ***1
(8) SBIOFUELS−0.030.97 ***0.96 ***0.48 ***0.35 ***0.47 ***0.26 ***1
(9) BGAS0.53 ***0.65 ***0.67 ***−0.040.41 ***0.16 **−0.37 ***0.56 ***1
(10) MW0.61 ***0.58 ***0.60 ***0.020.41 ***0.18 **−0.44 ***0.51 ***0.76 ***1
(11) BGASOLINE0.11 *0.53 ***0.53 ***0.090.56 ***0.14 *−0.21 ***0.50 ***0.57 ***0.50 ***1
(12) BDIESELS0.19 ***0.64 ***0.65 ***0.10.51 ***0.22 ***−0.14 *0.59 ***0.72 ***0.61 ***0.67 ***1
(13) OLB0.43 ***0.36 ***0.37 ***0.28 ***0.37 ***0.32 ***−0.18 ***0.32 ***0.44 ***0.58 ***0.25 ***0.36 ***
(14) HYDRO−0.030.75 ***0.74 ***0.42 ***0.33 ***0.57 ***0.18 **0.74 ***0.42 ***0.34 ***0.46 ***0.51 ***
(15) GEOTHERMAL−0.080.47 ***0.48 ***−0.040.16 **0.16 **0.060.44 ***0.33 ***0.36 ***0.27 ***0.45 ***
(16) WIND0.46 ***0.61 ***0.62 ***0.080.34 ***0.23 ***−0.21 ***0.52 ***0.77 ***0.68 ***0.48 ***0.67 ***
(17) SOLAR_T0.37 ***0.43 ***0.45 ***−0.080.24 ***0.20 ***−0.19 ***0.27 ***0.63 ***0.56 ***0.37 ***0.54 ***
(18) SOLAR_P0.14 *0.35 ***0.36 ***−0.070.31 ***0.12 *−0.070.28 ***0.52 ***0.39 ***0.48 ***0.51 ***
(19) ED0.18 ***−0.42 ***−0.41 ***−0.30 ***−0.07−0.16 **−0.23 ***−0.48 ***−0.18 **−0.15 **−0.1−0.14 *
(20) GGE0.55 ***−0.24 ***−0.21 ***−0.30 ***−0.15 **−0.05−0.46 ***−0.35 ***0.11 *0.18 **−0.12 *−0.07
(21) PET−0.40 ***−0.28 ***−0.30 ***−0.22 ***−0.41 ***−0.19 ***0.08−0.19 ***−0.52 ***−0.48 ***−0.34 ***−0.43 ***
(22) RP0.59 ***−0.04−0.01−0.39 ***0.17 **−0.18 **−0.56 ***−0.14 *0.50 ***0.50 ***0.25 ***0.26 ***
(23) RD0.67 ***0.44 ***0.46 ***0.42 ***0.44 ***0.41 ***−0.19 ***0.42 ***0.53 ***0.68 ***0.30 ***0.32 ***
(24) LF0.050.83 ***0.84 ***−0.040.26 ***0.12 *−0.17 **0.77 ***0.73 ***0.63 ***0.58 ***0.68 ***
Variables(13)(14)(15)(16)(17)(18)(19)(20)(21)(22)(23)(24)
(13) OLB1
(14) HYDRO0.17 **1
(15) GEOTHERMAL0.15 **0.47 ***1
(16) WIND0.44 ***0.35 ***0.37 ***1
(17) SOLAR_T0.33 ***0.32 ***0.44 ***0.68 ***1
(18) SOLAR_P0.27 ***0.30 ***0.41 ***0.48 ***0.58 ***1
(19) ED−0.13 *−0.040.08−0.15 **0.11 *0.11
(20) GGE0.06−0.060.040.17 **0.40 ***−0.040.46 ***1
(21) PET−0.38 ***−0.09−0.05−0.54 ***−0.48 ***−0.51 ***0.07−0.071
(22) RP0.20 ***−0.070.10.37 ***0.41 ***0.43 ***0.20 ***0.29 ***−0.41 ***1
(23) RD0.61 ***0.24 ***−0.020.44 ***0.25 ***0.15 **−0.26 ***0.15 **−0.49 ***0.24 ***1
(24) LF0.28 ***0.65 ***0.56 ***0.67 ***0.54 ***0.43 ***−0.31 ***−0.05−0.23 ***0.17 **0.22 ***1
Source: Authors’ computations. Notes: * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001. For the definition of variables, please see Table 2.
Table 5. Panel unit root test results.
Table 5. Panel unit root test results.
VariablesLevel
Individual InterceptIndividual Intercept and Trend
LLCIPSADFPPLLCIPSADFPP
GDPC−5.75 ***−2.83 **84.85 **167.04 ***−7.61 ***−0.5155.0559.46
PRE−4.45 ***2.1136.5282.96 *−6.89 ***−1.0668.08109.98 ***
CRE−5.35 ***0.9149.79102.04 ***−4.64 ***−0.1857.4380.91 *
SRE_GFEC2.136.0614.3112.22−4.98 ***0.3455.2776.34 *
SRE_FCT−3.12 ***0.6653.7852.02−5.43 ***−0.6870.27 56.53
EGRS7.939.275.1711.88−1.93 *2.4630.9659.38
FEC−0.063.1629.5234−4.75 ***−0.0352.33108.09 ***
SBIOFUELS−5.08 ***−0.660.877.67 *−3.83 ***0.9347.8069.75
BGAS−2.95 **1.1161.3568.12−6.05 ***−2.49 **94.05 **106.34 ***
MW−4.72 ***−0.3842.7351.48 −5.25 ***−0.1139.6854.55 *
BGASOLINE−19.94 ***−5.8 ***63.79 **43.22−21.23 ***−2.62 **48.61 27.85
BDIESELS−8.42 ***−2.3 *77.93 *118.73 ***−5.97 ***0.8143.7783.49 **
OLB−0.67−0.0722.8939.61 *−3.64 ***−0.6626.1157.51 ***
HYDRO−8.58 ***−5.93 ***133.67 ***219.98 ***−13.28 ***−4.99 ***114.73 ***196.45 ***
GEOTHERMAL−180.32 ***−63.66 ***59.11 *64.71 **−624.51 ***−103.32 ***55.83 *49.63
WIND−10.94 ***−2.94 **103.03 ***177.18 ***−5.80 ***0.0462.1090.14 ***
SOLAR_T−5.38 ***1.143.1138.781.472.8723.4135.75
SOLAR_P−1.97 *1.0748.8125.9−8.56 ***−1.82 *75.50 *48.84
ED0.592.7227.6669.88−6.11 ***−2.85 **92.79 **202.50 ***
GGE2.944.7725.4920.32−6.41 ***−1.1166.33126.22 ***
PET−1.71 *3.2237.0826.03−8.09 ***−1.68 *76.01 *106.09 ***
RP0.254.6316.1216.95−3.78 ***1.1640.34101.25 ***
RD−2.8 **2.1650.429.95−4.78 ***−0.1858.3786.95 **
LF−8 ***−1.38 81.55 *116.09 ***−5.28 ***0.7653.2069.96
VariablesFirst Difference
Individual InterceptIndividual Intercept and Trend
LLCIPSADFPPLLCIPSADFPP
ΔGDPC−8.08 ***−2.76 **83.78 **109.52 ***−11.96 ***−0.9473.15 77.84 *
ΔPRE−10.37 ***−6.04 ***143.00 ***242.85 ***−9.63 ***−2.38 **109.15 ***225.42 ***
ΔCRE−7.49 ***−4.40 ***117.65 ***218.64 ***−13.47 ***−2.03 *93.74 **209.88 ***
ΔSRE_GFEC−5.13 ***−2.37 **88.04**173.95 ***−4.75 ***−0.0960.77171.06 ***
ΔSRE_FCT−5.82 ***−3.29 ***99.67 ***162.77 ***−6.61 ***−0.1363.54133.15 ***
ΔEGRS−1.85 *0.0156.99118.42 ***−11.44 ***−1.0689.35 **156.94 ***
ΔFEC−6.54 ***−4.05 ***107.78 ***251.83 ***−4.67 ***−0.4763.27213.91 ***
ΔSBIOFUELS−5.02 ***−3.40 ***98.06 ***220.83 ***−3.41 ***−0.3268.32 247.66 ***
ΔBGAS−11.62 ***−7.02 ***154.65 ***247.18 ***−11.78 ***−3.11 ***122.08 ***225.96 ***
ΔMW−3.10 **−2.05 *54.77 *128.76 ***−1.29 0.0437.81135.87 ***
ΔBGASOLINE−15.92 ***−4.13 ***75.49 ***96.47 ***−11.69 ***−1.60 62.84 **137.17 ***
ΔBDIESELS−8.42 ***−3.85 ***98.29 ***194.14 ***−16.37 ***−3.34 ***118.53 ***220.86 ***
ΔOLB−4.12 ***−2.11 *37.61 *79.75 ***−3.07 **−0.1222.2771.19 ***
ΔHYDRO−16.70 ***−9.61 ***194.39 ***349.57 ***−15.30 ***−3.71 ***128.82 ***299.90 ***
ΔGEOTHERMAL−497.95 ***−80.40 ***96.05 ***147.50 ***−306.91 ***−31.68 ***75.29 ***150.37 ***
ΔWIND−9.22 ***−3.70 ***97.36 ***158.60 ***−25.28 ***−4.90 ***130.67 ***206.99 ***
ΔSOLAR_T−1.59 −1.1660.06137.08 ***−4.90 ***−0.0659.29175.25 ***
ΔSOLAR_P−4.47 ***−3.66 ***93.09 ***115.15 ***−4.17 ***−1.2680.49 **125.95 ***
ΔED−7.98 ***−7.75 ***168.48 ***383.62 ***−5.08 ***−2.58 **112.63 ***351.12 ***
ΔGGE−11.64 ***−6.79 ***154.76 ***275.04 ***−12.86 ***−3.20 ***123.94 ***293.40 ***
ΔPET−7.84 ***−4.71 ***120.33 ***191.42 ***−5.98 ***−0.8581.41 *145.72 ***
ΔRP−7.19 ***−4.77 ***120.45 ***269.63 ***−11.66 ***−2.59 **108.24 ***261.40 ***
ΔRD−4.90 ***−3.24 ***97.76 ***187.27 ***−4.33 ***−0.7172.08 174.11 ***
ΔLF−2.99 **−2.29 *81.50 *187.40 ***−2.94 **−1.0276.83 *243.79 ***
Source: authors’ computations. Notes: p < 0.1, * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001. LLC reveals Levin, Lin and Chu t* stat. IPS reveals Im, Pesaran and Shin W-stat. ADF reveals Augmented Dickey-Fuller Fisher Chi-square. PP reveals Phillips–Perron Fisher Chi-square. LLC assumes common unit root process. IPS, ADF, and PP assumes individual unit root process. For the definition of variables, please see Table 2.
Table 6. Fixed-effects estimations towards the impact of renewable energy (overall) on sustainable economic growth.
Table 6. Fixed-effects estimations towards the impact of renewable energy (overall) on sustainable economic growth.
VariablesEquations
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
PRE0.08 ***
(5.01)
CRE 0.07 ***
(4.45)
SRE_GFEC 1.61 ***
(5.43)
SRE_FCT 1.27 ***
(5.83)
EGRS 0.35 *
(2.14)
FEC 0.23
(1.27)
ED0.12
(1.82)
0.10
(1.54)
0.09
(1.46)
0.07
(1.23)
0.07
(1.13)
0.13
(1.93)
GGE0.19 *
(2.38)
0.20 *
(2.39)
0.37 ***
(4.30)
0.32 ***
(3.99)
0.23 **
(2.64)
0.22 *
(2.59)
PET−0.03
(−0.82)
−0.03
(−0.88)
0.09 *
(2.17)
0.03
(0.75)
0.01
(0.21)
−0.05
(−1.36)
RP−0.01
(−0.23)
−0.00
(−0.07)
0.01
(0.40)
0.02
(1.12)
−0.01
(−0.35)
0.01
(0.48)
RD5.68 *
(2.33)
6.34 **
(2.60)
1.93
(0.80)
6.98 **
(3.25)
5.86 *
(2.44)
8.43 ***
(3.34)
LF−0.29
(−1.88)
−0.31
(−1.96)
0.15
(1.10)
−0.07
(−0.47)
0.16
(1.11)
−0.00
(−0.03)
_cons13.02 ***
(5.78)
13.50 ***
(5.75)
5.46 *
(2.55)
9.40 ***
(4.45)
6.44 **
(2.84)
9.21 ***
(4.08)
F statistic8.18 ***7.36 ***7.02 ***7.71 ***3.23 ***4.45 ***
R-sq within0.160.150.150.170.080.09
Obs336336308308308334
N Countries282828282828
Source: Authors’ computations. Notes: p < 0.1, * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001. Values in parentheses represent t-statistic. For the definition of variables, please see Table 2.
Table 7. Fixed-effects estimations towards the influence of biomass energy on sustainable economic growth.
Table 7. Fixed-effects estimations towards the influence of biomass energy on sustainable economic growth.
VariablesEquations
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
SBIOFUELS0.16 ***
(6.77)
BGAS 0.06 ***
(8.27)
MW 0.04 ***
(5.88)
BGASOLINE 0.02 ***
(6.19)
BDIESELS 0.02 ***
(8.83)
OLB −0.00
(−0.33)
ED0.07
(1.15)
0.20 **
(3.22)
0.11
(1.72)
0.10
(1.56)
0.20 ***
(3.36)
0.12
(1.83)
GGE0.24 **
(3.01)
0.38 ***
(4.81)
0.25 **
(3.11)
0.30 ***
(3.71)
0.37 ***
(4.79)
0.20 *
(2.33)
PET−0.04
(−1.04)
−0.00
(−0.02)
−0.06
(−1.58)
−0.03
(−0.72)
−0.03
(−0.75)
−0.06
(−1.48)
RP−0.02
(−0.92)
0.01
(0.30)
0.01
(0.34)
0.01
(0.44)
0.02
(0.76)
0.01
(0.51)
RD6.60 **
(2.88)
5.59 *
(2.51)
7.43 **
(3.21)
7.61 **
(3.32)
7.74 ***
(3.58)
9.29 ***
(3.82)
LF−0.07
(−0.53)
0.03
(0.21)
−0.06
(−0.45)
−0.03
(−0.20)
−0.10
(−0.73)
0.01
(0.09)
_cons9.18 ***
(4.48)
7.64 ***
(3.83)
9.93 ***
(4.76)
9.13 ***
(4.40)
9.74 ***
(4.96)
9.12 ***
(4.14)
F statistic11.44 ***14.97 ***9.68 ***10.27 ***16.50 ***4.26 ***
R-sq within0.210.260.180.190.280.09
Obs336336336336336336
N Countries282828282828
Source: Authors’ computations. Notes: p < 0.1, * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001. Values in parentheses represent t-statistic. For the definition of variables, please see Table 2.
Table 8. Fixed-effects estimations towards the effect of hydropower, geothermal energy, wind, and solar energy on sustainable economic growth.
Table 8. Fixed-effects estimations towards the effect of hydropower, geothermal energy, wind, and solar energy on sustainable economic growth.
VariablesEquations
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)
HYDRO0.05
(1.94)
GEOTHERMAL 0.02 *
(2.17)
WIND 0.04 ***
(11.78)
SOLAR_T 0.03 ***
(3.90)
SOLAR_P −0.00
(−1.33)
ED0.15 *
(2.18)
0.14 *
(2.10)
0.13 *
(2.39)
0.14 *
2.09)
0.13
(1.94)
GGE0.22 *
(2.57)
0.22 **
(2.61)
0.40 ***
(5.57)
0.22 **
(2.63)
0.16
(1.82)
PET−0.06
(−1.55)
−0.07
(−1.68)
0.03
(0.90)
−0.06
(−1.62)
−0.07
(−1.76)
RP0.01
(0.39)
0.00
(0.03)
0.00
(0.08)
−0.02
(−0.93)
0.01
(0.49)
RD8.91 ***
(3.70)
8.04 **
(3.25)
7.33 ***
(3.66)
6.53 **
(2.65)
10.03 ***
(4.08)
LF0.00
(0.02)
0.03
(0.19)
0.09
(0.72)
−0.18
(−1.18)
0.03
(0.19)
_cons8.95 ***
(4.09)
8.82 ***
(4.03)
6.55 ***
(3.57)
11.98 ***
(5.28)
9.08 ***
(4.14)
F statistic4.84 ***4.99 ***26.02 ***6.63 ***4.52 ***
R-sq within0.100.100.380.130.10
Obs336336336336336
N Countries2828282828
Source: Authors’ computations. Notes: p < 0.1, * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001. Values in parentheses represent t-statistic. For the definition of variables, please see Table 2.
Table 9. Pedroni (Engle Granger based) test results.
Table 9. Pedroni (Engle Granger based) test results.
Within-Dimension
Cointegration TestIndividual InterceptIndividual Intercept and Individual TrendNo Intercept or Trend
StatisticWeighted
Statistic
StatisticWeighted
Statistic
StatisticWeighted
Statistic
Panel v-Statistic−0.11−1.110.65−3.32−3.06−3.84
Panel rho-Statistic2.181.874.254.49−2.45 **−2.61 **
Panel PP-Statistic−0.48−1.210.92−1.16−6.67 ***−6.02 ***
Panel ADF-Statistic−4.44 ***−3.41 ***−0.52−2.44 **−6.76 ***−6.03 ***
Between-Dimension
Statistic Statistic Statistic
Group rho-Statistic4.55 6.34 −0.21
Group PP-Statistic−0.16 −0.76 −9.12 ***
Group ADF-Statistic−3.46 *** −1.02 −7.73 ***
Source: Authors’ computations. Notes: ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001. Akaike Info Criterion was selected for lag length.
Table 10. Kao (Engle Granger based) test results.
Table 10. Kao (Engle Granger based) test results.
ADF (t-Statistic)Residual VarianceHAC Variance
−4.38 ***0.0020.003
Source: authors’ computations. Notes: *** p < 0.001. Akaike Info Criterion was selected for lag length.
Table 11. Fisher (combined Johansen) test results.
Table 11. Fisher (combined Johansen) test results.
Hypothesized
No. of CE(s)
Fisher Stat.
(From Trace Test)
Fisher Stat.
(From Max-Eigen Test)
None579.9 ***502.3 ***
At most 1169.6 ***146.7 ***
At most 2104.6 ***104.6 ***
Source: authors’ computations. Notes: *** p < 0.001. Akaike Info Criterion was selected for lag length. Probabilities are computed using asymptotic Chi-square distribution.
Table 12. Ouput of panel fully modified OLS (FMOLS) and dynamic OLS (DOLS).
Table 12. Ouput of panel fully modified OLS (FMOLS) and dynamic OLS (DOLS).
VariablesFMOLSDOLS
PRE0.06 ***
(4.40)
0.05 ***
(5.16)
ED0.08
(1.05)
0.12
(1.28)
R-squared0.990.99
Adjusted R-squared0.990.99
S.E. of regression0.070.06
Durbin-Watson stat0.42
Mean dependent var10.1610.15
S.D. dependent var0.660.67
Sum squared resid1.301.08
Long-run variance0.010.01
Source: authors’ computations. Notes: *** p < 0.001. Panel method: pooled. Heterogeneous variances. Akaike lag and lead method in case of DOLS estimation. Values in parentheses represent t-statistic. For the definition of variables, please see Table 2.
Table 13. Granger causality based on panel vector error correction model (PVECM).
Table 13. Granger causality based on panel vector error correction model (PVECM).
VariablesShort-Run (or Weak) Granger CausalityLong-Run
Granger Causality
ΔGDPCΔPREΔEDECT
(6) ΔGDPC-12.56 **4.00−0.002
(7) ΔPRE1.49-4.76 −0.020 **
(8) ΔED2.834.20-0.013 ***
Source: authors’ computations. Notes: p < 0.1, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001. ECT reveals the coefficient of the error correction term. The number of appropriate lag is two according to Schwarz information criterion. For the definition of variables, please see Table 2.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Armeanu, D.Ş.; Vintilă, G.; Gherghina, Ş.C. Does Renewable Energy Drive Sustainable Economic Growth? Multivariate Panel Data Evidence for EU-28 Countries. Energies 2017, 10, 381. https://doi.org/10.3390/en10030381

AMA Style

Armeanu DŞ, Vintilă G, Gherghina ŞC. Does Renewable Energy Drive Sustainable Economic Growth? Multivariate Panel Data Evidence for EU-28 Countries. Energies. 2017; 10(3):381. https://doi.org/10.3390/en10030381

Chicago/Turabian Style

Armeanu, Daniel Ştefan, Georgeta Vintilă, and Ştefan Cristian Gherghina. 2017. "Does Renewable Energy Drive Sustainable Economic Growth? Multivariate Panel Data Evidence for EU-28 Countries" Energies 10, no. 3: 381. https://doi.org/10.3390/en10030381

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop