Next Article in Journal
Experimental Study on Frost Height of Round Plate Fin-Tube Heat Exchangers for Mobile Heat Pumps
Previous Article in Journal
Feasibility Study of Micro-Wind Turbines for Powering Wireless Sensors on a Cable-Stayed Bridge
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

The Economic Cost of Unsupplied Diesel Product in Korea Using Input-Output Analysis

Department of Energy Policy, Graduate School of Energy & Environment, Seoul National University of Science & Technology, 232 Gongreung-Ro, Nowon-Gu, Seoul 139-743, Korea
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Energies 2012, 5(9), 3465-3478; https://doi.org/10.3390/en5093465
Submission received: 20 May 2012 / Revised: 27 August 2012 / Accepted: 27 August 2012 / Published: 6 September 2012

Abstract

:
Diesel is an essential factor in industrial production and development, and thus its stable supply is a crucial element for economic growth. The supply shortage of diesel has massive economic costs, namely supply shortage costs. This paper attempts to apply input-output (I-O) analysis to measuring the supply shortage cost of industrial diesel in Korea by finding an optimal way of allocating the limited diesel resources to different sectors according to the objective of maximizing overall value-added. To this end, a static I-O framework is presented using a recently published I-O table. The results indicate that the marginal cost of unsupplied diesel ranges from KRW 716 (USD 0.65) to KRW 113,376 (USD 103.07) per liter and these costs depend not only on the shortage rate of each non-diesel sector but also on the level of its own final demand. The quantitative results are useful for policy-makers to set economic reliability standards, develop optimum curtailment levels and priorities, and plan curtailment strategies for diesel supply and demand.

1. Introduction

Oil is widely accepted as a vital input to industrial development and economic growth. However, the prospects of future oil shortages have resulted in forecasts of continued high prices and even wars. Thus, the issue of oil risk has received increasing attention in both developed and developing countries. According to Energy Outlook 2030 [1], oil is expected to be a gradually growing fuel over the next two decades. Nevertheless, global oil consumption is likely to rise by 16.5 million barrels per day (Mb/d), exceeding 102 Mb/d by 2030. Furthermore, the growth of oil consumption comes exclusively from rapidly growing developing economies. Developing countries, rising by nearly 13 Mb/d, account for more than three quarters of the global increase. However, oil consumption in developed countries has been growing at a slower pace or even declining. Reynolds [2] emphasized that oil is the main energy source for the operation of mobile equipment and the main driver of economic growth. For example, some studies have showed that oil consumption causes economic growth [3,4].
This study pays particular attention to diesel. A stable supply of diesel is an important element to continuing industrial activities. Diesel supply shortages may bring massive economic losses [5,6,7,8,9,10,11,12]. If a diesel supply shortage happens, it will directly cause production disruptions, raw material supply shortages, and production and other processing problems, including equipment failures, and indirectly cause losses of production in related industries, unemployment, and inflation due to production disruptions. Korea’s industrial structure is highly dependent on diesel consumption. Rapid economic growth has boosted the country’s diesel demand in the past four decades. Furthermore, as the diesel price has been continuously increasing, the security of diesel supply has attracted a great deal of attention in recent years. These situations require the researcher to provide energy policy-makers with accessible and reliable information on the reliability of diesel supply. Diesel supply reliability can be characterized almost exclusively by shortage costs.
There are four well-known approaches to the measurement of the shortage cost of diesel, that is, the economic cost of unsupplied diesel: the willingness-to-pay approach, the production factor approach, the customer survey approach, and the input-output (I-O) approach.
First, the willingness-to-pay approach involves the valuation of specific changes from the status quo by using the stated preference technique [13]. Second, the production factor approach estimates the economic loss associated with reduced productive activity (for firms) or lost time (for households) as a result of idle resources, spoiled materials, and damaged equipment [14,15]. The approach enables us to infer the marginal cost of a diesel cut. Third, the customer survey approach lists the effects of an actual supply interruption and then monetizes them [16]. Finally, the I-O approach, which addresses the impact of supply shortages on the whole economy by recognizing the interdependence of all sectors of the economy, has been applied in the energy shortage context. For example, Bernstein and Hegazy [17] employed the I-O approach to examine the effect of electricity shortages in Egypt. Chen and Vella [18] used the Leontief I-O framework to account for the average economic impact of short-term diesel shortages in all industrial sectors. The approach assumes that diesel supply shortage brings about supply problems in heavy industries which will lead to huge production reduction of the whole industries.
Each has its own merits. This study uses the I-O methodology of Chen and Vella [18], because both the government and diesel sector can measure the macro-economic impacts of unsupplied diesel in the existing economy. This approach can also provide the information of decision-making related to which sectors should be cut off in the case of diesel shortages. Thus, the purpose of this paper is to measure the supply shortage cost of diesel in the Korean economy in order to obtain an indication of the impact of diesel supply shortages in other sectors. In this study, national economic impacts caused by supply shortages of diesel product will be calculated using the I-O analysis. In particular, diesel products commonly used by commercial vehicles and manufacturing activities will be studied. This supply will show specifically how much macroscopic social cost will be when we encounter diesel supply shortage. In addition, benefits from establishing a stable supply of diesel products can be estimated indirectly.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows: Section 2 presents an overview of the methodology and the empirical model adopted here. Section 3 describes the data and some assumptions. Section 4 reports the empirical findings. Some concluding remarks are made in the final section.

2. Methodology and Empirical Model

2.1. Methodology: I-O Analysis

I-O analysis, an analytical framework developed by Wassily Leontief [19]. Leontief, has become well known in the energy and environmental fields in recent decades [20]. I-O analysis is very useful for analyzing diesel-related issues in the economic context at the national level because it recognizes the interdependence of all sectors of the economy and their diesel consumption, which is embodied in their sectoral output. The I-O model is a linear and inter-sectoral model that shows the relationship among various productive sectors of an economic system. In an economy composed of n sectors, the inter-relationship among those sectors can be represented as:
X i = j = 1 n Z i j + F i = j = 1 n a i j X j + F i
where Xi is the total gross output of sector i = 1, …, n; Zij is the inter-industry purchases of producing sector i from supply sector j; Fi is the final demand for products of sector i; and aij is the direct input coefficient which divide Zij by total gross output in sector j (Xj). Considering imports (M), Equation (1) can be rewritten in an abbreviated matrix form:
( I A ) X = F M
The following theoretical background is based on Chen and Vella [18]. To clearly demonstrate the effect of diesel supply on the economy, we move the items referring to the diesel sector to the nth sector. Using partitioning, Equation (2) becomes:
[ ( I A ) α d 1 f ] [ X D ] = [ F F D ] [ M M D ]
where I is an (n − 1) × (n − 1) identity matrix; A is an (n − 1) × (n − 1) technical coefficient matrix of non-diesel sectors; α is the diesel column of non- diesel sectors; d is the diesel row of non-diesel sectors; f is the self-use-ratio of the diesel sector; D is diesel supply; X is non-diesel outputs; F is the final demand of non-diesel products; FD is the final demand of diesel; M is the import by non-diesel sectors; and MD is the import by diesel sector.
We are interested in knowing how diesel shortages impose extra cost on all sectors. Thus, the items of D are isolated on the right-hand side of the equations to enable the investigation of its relation to other sectors. Rewriting Equation (3) gives us:
( I A ) X = α D + ( F M )
d X ^ F D = ( f 1 ) D M D

2.2. Empirical Model

The optimal allocation of limited diesel resources to various sectors can be achieved by solving overall value-added maximization problem. This can be specified as maximizing the total benefit (TB):
T B = V X + V D D
subject to:
( I A ) 1 X = α D + ( F M )
d X ^ F D = ( f 1 ) D M D
0 F F 0
0 X X 0
D = ( 1 S ) D 0
0 F D F D 0
where V is the row vector of value-added coefficients for non-diesel sectors; VD is the value-added coefficient for the diesel sector; D0, X 0 , F 0 , and F D 0 are D, X , F , and FD under an adequate condition, respectively; and S is the unsupplied diesel as a proportion of diesel demand (D0). Thus, D, D0, and SD0 are the amount of diesel actually supplied, the amount of diesel supplied under the condition of no shortage, the amount of diesel unsupplied in shortage situations, respectively. Maximizing Equation (5) under the six constraints implies that curtailment of the diesel will be performed to reduce the final demand of the sector with the lowest value-added multiplier as the shortage percentage increases.
We define five matrices as follows:
B = [ ( I A ) 0 d 1 ] ,   X * = [ X F D ] ,   α * = [ α f 1 ] ,   F * = [ F ^ 0 ] ,   and   M * = [ M ^ M D ]
Equation (4b) can be re-written as:
B X * = α * D + F * M *
The solution of X* can be derived as:
X * = B 1 α * D + B 1 ( F * M * )
From Equation (6), B−1 can be:
B 1 = [ ( I A ) 1 0 d ( I A ) 1 1 ]
Equation (4a,b) can be re-written as:
X = ( I A ) 1 α D + ( I A ) 1 ( F M )
F D = [ 1 f d ( I A ^ ) 1 α ] D d ( I A ^ ) 1 ( F M ) + M D
For brevity, let K = ( I A ) 1 α , ε = d ( I A ^ ) 1 , θ = 1−fεα, and C D = M D ε M ^ . Thus, Equation (10a,b) become:
X = K D + ( I A ) 1 ( F M )
F D = θ D + C D + ε F
Substituting Equation (11a) for X ^ in Equation (5) gives us:
V X + V D D = ( V ^ K + V D ) D + V ^ ( I A ^ ) 1 ( F ^ M ^ )
Therefore, Equation (5) can be:
T B = V X + V D D = w F ^ + Q D C M
where w = V ^ ( I A ^ ) 1 , C M = w M ^ , and Q = V ^ K + V D = w α + V D .
If the diesel shortage occurs in such a short time that due to the limited capacities of import facilities and other factors the amount of imports M ^ cannot be changed, then CM is assumed to be constant. Since w = [wj] is a constant vector, and Q constant as well, the optimal benefit of an economy is dominated by the product of w and F . wj is the value-added multiplier of sector j. The final demand of a sector which has the highest value-added multiplier will induce the largest amount of total value-added. Hence, when facing difficulties of satisfying all the demand, the diesel-providing industry will first cut down supply to those sectors which have lower value-added multipliers based on economic aspect. In order to find the optimal solution, we can sort the value-added multipliers into ascending order. The best allocation policy is to cut down the final demands one by one in ascending order of value-added multipliers, until the diesel supply is sufficient to accommodate the new production configuration of the whole economy.
The amount of diesel supply is fixed at its upper limit in shortage situations. Therefore the direct value-added generated by the diesel sector is fixed at VDD, no matter how the diesel-providing industry allocates its diesel supply. Because the final demand for diesel consumes goods but does not induce value-added products, supplying diesel to its final-demand consumers does not induce any value-added effects. Hence, if the economic aspect is only considered, the final demand users will be the first to suffer curtailment.

2.3. Economic Consideration

The consumers in final demand will be the first target for diesel cuts if we want to maximize total value-added. Without loss of generality, the sectors would be considered in ascending order of multiplier. From Equation (11b):
F D = θ D 0 ( 1 S ) + k = 1 n 1 ε k F k + C D
This can be re-expressed as:
S = 1 F D θ D 0 + C D θ D 0 + k = 1 n 1 ε k F k θ D 0
Under adequate conditions, the final demand of various sectors is denoted as F D 0 , F n 1 0 , F n 2 0 , …, F 1 0 . If S = 0, then F D = F D 0 and F k = F k 0 (k = 1, 2, …, n − 1). F D 0 and F k 0 in Equation (15) are the final demands of diesel sector and non-diesel k th sector, respectively, under adequate conditions. Thus:
F D 0 θ D 0 C D θ D 0 k = 1 n 1 ε k F k 0 θ D 0 = 1
Let r D = 1 θ D 0 and r k = ε k θ D 0 for k = 1, 2, …, n − 1. Replacing Equation (14) with Equation (15) gives us the following relation between shortage percentage and final demand:
S = r D ( F D 0 F D ) [ k = 1 n 1 r k ( F k 0 F k ) ]
The shortage percentage in Equation (16) is S that means the unsupplied diesel as a proportion of diesel demand (D0). As the shortage percentage increases, the diesel sector first reduces its diesel supply to its final-demand consumers to maximize the total value-added. Theoretically, this first curtailment measure can last until FD = 0. Then, if diesel demand is still greater than the supply, the second curtailment will be performed to reduce the final demand of the sector with the lowest value-added multiplier. These steps are:
S D = r D F D 0 ,
S 1 = r D F D 0 r 1 F 1 0 ,
S t = r D F D 0 k = 1 t r k F k 0 ,
S n 1 = r D F D 0 k = 1 n 1 r k F k 0
where t means the curtailment stage. At stage t, the optimal solution for F is:
{ F k = 0   for  k t       = F k 0   for  k > t
From Equation (11a), the elements of ( I A ^ ) 1 and ( I A ^ ) 1 M ^ are represented as β’s and m’s. The output of sector i at stage t is:
X i t = K i D m i + k = 1 n 1 β i k F k     = K i ( 1 S t ) D 0 m i + k = t + 1 n 1 β i k F k 0
for i = 1, 2, …, n − 1 and xi ≥ 0. From Equation (13) the total benefit at stage i is:
T B t = T B 0 k = 1 t w k F k 0 Q Δ D
The decrements of sector production, diesel, and total benefit from stage t − 1 to t are:
Δ X i t = K i Δ D t β i t F t 0  for   i = 1 , 2 , , n 1 Δ D t = ( S t 1 S t ) D 0 = r F t 0 D 0 = ε t F t 0 θ Δ T B t = Q r t F t 0 D 0 w t F t 0 = F t 0 ( w t Q r t D 0 )
Based on the assumption of fixed input coefficients, the diesel supply to sector i for producing Xi will be diXi, and the optimal curtailment policy in stage t will be d i ( X i 0 X i ) . Under such a policy the marginal production and the marginal benefit (cost) of diesel shortage can be derived as:
M X i t = Δ X i t Δ D t = K i θ β i t ε t
and:
M B t = Δ T B t Δ D t = Q θ w t ε t ,
respectively.

3. Data and Some Assumptions

3.1. Data

For the diesel-based I-O analysis, we used the original 2009 benchmark I-O table for Korea [21]. The original benchmark I-O table was composed of 403 sectors. To avoid the arbitrariness of aggregation and minimize sectoral bias, we used the Bank of Korea’s 28-sector classification method. Sector 7 was originally petroleum and coal products sector, but for the I-O analysis, we divided this sector into two sectors (diesel sector and non-diesel petroleum and coal products sector). Therefore, we considered a total of 29 sectors. Sectors 1 to 28 are non-diesel sectors; Sector 29 is the diesel sector. Section classification adopted in this study is described in Table 1.
Table 1. Sector classification in this study.
Table 1. Sector classification in this study.
CodeName of Sector
1Agriculture, forestry and fishing
2Mining and quarrying
3Food, beverages and tobacco products
4Textile and apparel
5Wood and paper products
6Printing and reproduction of recorded media
7Non-diesel petroleum and coal products
8Chemicals, drugs and medicines
9Non-metallic mineral products
10Basic metal products
11Fabricated metal products except machinery and furniture
12General machinery and equipment
13Electronic and electrical equipment
14Precision instruments
15Transportation equipment
16Furniture and other manufactured products
17Electricity, gas, steam and water supply
18Construction
19Wholesale and retail trade
20Accommodation and food services
21Transportation
22Communications and broadcasting
23Finance and insurance
24Real estate and business services
25Public administration and defense
26Education, health and social work
27Other services
28Dummy (miscellaneous) sectors
29Diesel products

3.2. Some Assumptions

To determine an optimal solution from the empirical model, first of all, we have to sort the value-added multipliers into ascending order. In general, the optimal allocation policy involves the reduction of the final demand one by one in the ascending order of value-added multipliers until the diesel supply can accommodate the new production configuration of the whole economy. Moreover, the best allocation policies are typically achieved by maximizing the overall social economic benefit with respect to various supply shortage situations.
Next, to analyze the influence of such policies on the cost of unsupplied diesel in the Korean economy, we determined whether the diesel sector could reduce its supply to its final-demand consumers based on economic considerations and to what extent the sectoral supply to final-demand consumers could be curtailed. Optimal allocation policy assuming the allocation is maximizing the total social benefit for each supply shortage situations. However, it is important whether we can restrict the supply of the product to the end user and by how far we can reduce sectoral supply to the end user. We assume that the diesel-providing industry can cut diesel to final demand consumers based on economic considerations. Thus, the assumptions about supply reduction allocation policy are needed. We consider two cases. The maximum decrease percentages for sectoral supplies to final demand (σ) are assumed to be 20% or 30%.
For more realistic results, we made some modifications during the calculation procedure. Because the final demand of Sector 2 (mining and quarrying) was too small relative to other sectors, the proportion of real consumption to the final demand was also quite small, and thus, the sector’s σ was set to zero. Furthermore, the economic cost of unsupplied diesel is expressed as KRW per liter for a better understanding. The average price of diesel per liter was KRW 967 (USD 0.88) during 2009 [22].

4. Results

The value-added multipliers of all the non-diesel sectors are shown in Table 2. Sector 23, “finance and insurance”, has the highest value-added multiplier at 0.9920, which means that this sector will generate more value-added than any other sectors to the Korean national economy. Sector 21, ‘transportation’, has the lowest value-added multiplier at 0.8770.
Table 2. Value-added multipliers for non-diesel sectors in Korea.
Table 2. Value-added multipliers for non-diesel sectors in Korea.
Name of SectorsSector CodesValue-Added Multipliers
Transportation210.8770
Mining and quarrying20.9155
Non-diesel petroleum and coal products70.9303
Non-metallic mineral products90.9450
Electricity, gas, steam and water supply170.9504
Basic metal products100.9601
Chemicals, drugs and medicines80.9649
Agriculture, forestry and fishing10.9650
Construction180.9666
Fabricated metal products except machinery and furniture110.9705
Food, beverages and tobacco products30.9718
Wood and paper products50.9735
Wholesale and retail trade190.9736
Furniture and other manufactured products160.9746
General machinery and equipment120.9764
Dummy (miscellaneous) sectors280.9772
Transportation equipment150.9777
Textile and apparel40.9778
Electronic and electrical equipment130.9792
Accommodation and food services200.9797
Precision instruments140.9797
Printing and reproduction of recorded media60.9804
Other services270.9826
Education, health and social work260.9833
Public administration and defense250.9868
Communications and broadcasting220.9872
Real estate and business services240.9906
Finance and insurance230.9920
In order to deal with the matrix calculations, a GAUSS program was written and EXCEL was used for computing this input-output framework. The program was applied to estimating the diesel shortage costs of Korea in 2009. Table 3 presents the marginal shortage costs, and average shortage costs of unsupplied diesel under different shortage percentages. The marginal shortage costs are independent of shortage percentages. Therefore, they are the same under different shortage percentages.
Table 3. Average and marginal shortage costs of unsupplied diesel.
Table 3. Average and marginal shortage costs of unsupplied diesel.
StageName of SectorsCase 1 (σ = 20%)Case 2 (σ = 30%)Marginal Shortage Cost b
Shortage %Total Benefit aAverage Shortage cost bShortage %Total Benefit aAverage Shortage Cost b
1Diesel product0.08501,045,7882,1160.12751,044,7303,175716
2Transportation0.12961,034,27711,5110.19431,027,46217,2677,420
3Non-diesel petroleum and coal products0.14231,028,4775,7990.21341,018,7638,69913,099
4Non-metallic mineral products0.14291,028,1493270.21431,018,27149116,608
5Electricity, gas, steam and water supply0.14791,024,9393,2090.22181,013,4564,81418,409
6Basic metal products0.15251,021,2433,6960.22881,007,9125,54422,902
7Chemicals, drugs and medicines0.16531,009,68311,5590.2479990,57217,33925,991
8Agriculture, forestry and fishing0.16881,006,4493,2340.2533985,7214,85126,087
9Construction0.2074970,87335,5750.3111932,35753,36326,508
10Fabricated metal products except machinery and furniture0.2102967,9072,9660.3152927,9074,44930,984
11Food, beverages and tobacco products0.2201956,70711,1990.3301911,10816,79932,393
12Wood and paper products0.2205956,1705360.3308910,30380534,395
13Wholesale and retail trade0.2318942,67913,4910.3477890,06620,23634,551
14Furniture and other manufactured products0.2335940,4682,2100.3503886,7503,31535,893
15General machinery and equipment0.2441926,33114,1370.3661865,54421,20538,633
16Dummy (miscellaneous) sectors0.2441926,279520.3661865,4667840,103
17Transportation equipment0.2631899,20327,0760.3947824,85140,61440,852
18Textile and apparel0.2688891,1258,0780.4032812,73412,11741,147
19Electronic and electrical equipment0.2938852,86838,2560.4407755,35057,38443,922
20Accommodation and food services0.3009841,80411,0630.4513738,75416,59544,896
21Precision instruments0.3027839,0362,7680.4540734,6014,15244,983
22Printing and reproduction of recorded media0.3027838,9231120.4541734,43216946,561
23Other services0.3091827,36311,5590.4636717,09217,33952,345
24Education, health and social work0.3259795,38331,9800.4888669,12147,97054,674
25Public administration and defense0.3336776,91918,4640.5004641,42527,69668,969
26Communications and broadcasting0.3355772,0974,8210.5033634,1937,23271,129
27Real estate and business services0.3433746,07426,0220.5149595,15939,03496,796
28Finance and insurance0.3458736,1209,9540.5187580,22714,931113,376
a Total benefits are in billion Korean won; b Average and marginal shortage costs are expressed in Korean won per liter.
Total benefit in Korean national economy calculated using Equation (17) is KRW 1,047,905 billion (USD 953 billion). Marginal shortage cost of unsupplied diesel incurred by society is as low as KRW 716 (USD 0.65) per liter, which is 74% of the sales price, in case that the diesel sector initially opts to curtail its supply to final demand consumers. This is based on the fact that the final demand users only consume goods and do not add any values nor do they indirectly contribute to any value-added effects.
Next to that, transportation sector will be the target to have reduced diesel supply because they have the lowest value-added multiplier. Its marginal cost of the shortage is KRW 7,420 (USD 6.75) per liter. The third target will be non-diesel petroleum and coal products sector and its marginal cost of the shortage will be KRW 13,099 (USD 11.91) per liter. When the supply of diesel exceeds its demand and it leads to a continuous supply shortage and ends up with targeting the final supply reduction target, finance and insurance sector, the marginal cost of the shortage is analyzed to be reaching KRW 113,376 (USD 103.07) per liter. The marginal costs of unsupplied diesel increase from KRW 716 (USD 0.65) to KRW 113,376 (USD 103.07) per liter as the stage goes from 0 to 29, which means that opportunity costs increase as value-added multipliers get higher.
Without loss of generality, the stage of each sector has already determined by ascending order of value-added multiplier. Therefore, sector 21, “transportation”, would be the second target for curtailment, due to its lower value-added multiplier. According to the ascending order of value-added multiplier (see Table 2), sector 7, “non-diesel petroleum and coal products”, would be the third target, and so on.

5. Concluding Remarks

Korea has been highly reliant on diesel consumption. Timely and unceasing supply of diesel could be a cornerstone of its modern economy. Ensuring reliable diesel supply has been and will continue to be one of the most important considerations in decision-making about the industrial policy of the diesel sector. Recently, the industrial development has made diesel supply reliability a critical part of any policy for a sustainable future. These situations require researchers to provide energy policy-makers with accessible and reliable information on the reliability of diesel supply. In this regard, this study employed I-O analysis to estimate the economic cost of unsupplied diesel for all sectors in Korea by determining the optimal way in which limited diesel product resources can be allocated to various sectors while maximizing the total value-added. The results indicate that the marginal cost of unsupplied diesel ranged from KRW 716 (USD 0.65) to KRW 113,376 (USD 103.07) per liter and that these total costs depended not only on the shortage percentage of each non-diesel sector but also on the level of its final demand. This exercise provides important insights into both policy and research.
For policy purposes, the results are useful starting points in understanding the possible implications of the role of diesel supply in Korea. The overall results indicate that diesel product shortages have a big influence on the industrial production and standard of living. The data on the economic cost of diesel supply shortages, which is obtained from our study, may provide valuable information for planners in various ways. First, it can be used in setting economic reliability standards in diesel production and distribution planning and diesel system optimization. The social optimal service quality level is determined at the minimum of the sum of supply costs and shortage costs [23]. Second, it can be employed in determining pricing and load management strategies. Finally, it can be applied in developing shortage management strategies, optimum curtailment levels and priorities. The data can help in assessing a more economically sound way of allocating the available diesel during a period of shortage. A policy dealing with limited diesel being provided for sectors in which shortage costs are relatively high could be considered.
Judging from a review of the literature, there are only several studies in which the I-O model was used for analyzing diesel-related issues. The advantage of I-O analysis lies in the use of data from the latest I-O table produced by the government [21]. Thus, this method helps to simplify the estimation and ensure more reliable results. For research purposes, beyond the intrinsic interest of the results in relation to the diesel policy, this case study has demonstrated the feasibility of extending the use of the I-O analysis at least to diesel-providing industry. It could provide one prerequisite for helping diesel-related policy-making, but the extension of the present framework needs to be undertaken in a future study as a second phase of the work. The extension can be made in three aspects.
First, the next study has to focus the multi-regional I-O model. This study focused on the national I-O model. The multi-regional I-O model reflecting the peculiarities of a regional problem could improve understanding of diesel-providing industry.
Second, dynamic consideration can be useful in the demand-driven I-O model. Actually, some input goods contribute to the production process but are not immediately used up during that production. Therefore, dynamic I-O analysis, which allows the changing of input coefficients over time, will significantly increase the precision of analytical results.
Third, in deriving the shortage costs of energy supply, the supply-driven model can be more useful than the demand-driven model adopted here. The demand-driven I-O approach assesses the economic cost of unsupplied diesel product dealing with diesel as a raw material for the production of other sectors. The demand-driven I-O approach has been widely used in computing the forward linkage effect [24]. The demand-driven I-O model, which depends on the assumption of fixed input coefficients and a perfectly elastic supply of inputs, concentrates on analyzing the impacts stemming from the final demand, or backward linkage, and output orientation of activities [25,26]. However, the model may not be appropriate for dealing with the impact from the primary supply, or forward linkage, and the input orientation of activities. Therefore, the supply-driven I-O model has been developed to deal with the direct and indirect impacts of natural resource supply restrictions [27]. Thus, it is appropriate to assume that allocation coefficients are fixed during supply restriction in primary inputs [28]. According to Equation (13), TB is the only function of F ^ , indicating any non-diesel value-added sectors may not directly affect those non-diesel industries total outputs. Similarly, the equation is not explaining how the VD affects other non-diesel industries; it only assumes non-diesel final demands may be the first affected factors. Thus, the framework of our paper should be extended to the supply-driven I-O approach as a second stage of the study.

References and Notes

  1. BP. Energy Outlook 2030. 2011. Available online: http://www.bp.com (accessed on 2 March 2010).
  2. Reynolds, D.B. The energy utilization chain: Determining viable oil alternative technology. Energy Sources 2000, 22, 215–226. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Yoo, S.-H. Oil consumption and economic growth: Evidence from Korea. Energy Sources B Econ. Plan. Policy 2006, 1, 235–243. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Usama, A.M. Oil consumption, CO2 emission and economic growth in MENA countries. Energy 2011, 36, 6165–6171. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Maltby, D. Implications of oil resources shortage for urban transport investment. Transp. Res. 1974, 8, 277–291. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Lee, T.R.; Wood, L.J. The city in an era of restricted car usage: Some potential responses and adjustments to future oil shortages. Geoforum 1980, 11, 17–29. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Sanghvi, A.P. Economic costs of electricity supply interruptions: US and foreign experience. Energy Econ. 1982, 4, 180–198. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Olofin, S.; Iyaniwura, J.O. From oil shortage to oil glut: Simulation of growth prospects in the Nigerian economy. J. Policy Model. 1983, 5, 363–378. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Smith, K.G. Reducing vulnerability to oil shortages. Energy 1983, 8, 609–614. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Davis, H.C.; Cherniack, H. Inter-Industry approaches to the analysis of a supply disruption of a critical resource. Resour. Policy 1987, 13, 47–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Hirsch, R.L. Mitigation of maximum world oil production: Shortage scenarios. Energy Policy 2008, 36, 881–889. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Kerschner, C.; Hubacek, K. Assessing the suitability of input-output analysis for enhancing our understanding of potential economic effects of peak oil. Energy 2009, 34, 284–290. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Carlsson, F.; Martinsson, P. Does it matter when a power outage occurs? A choice experiment study on the willingness to pay to avoid power outages. Energy Econ. 2008, 30, 1232–1245. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. De Nooij, M.; Koopmans, C.; Bijvoet, C. The value of supply security: The costs of power interruptions: Economic input for damage reduction and investment in networks. Energy Econ. 2007, 29, 277–295. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Leahy, E.; Tol, R.S.J. An estimate of the value of lost load for Ireland. Energy Policy 2011, 39, 1514–1520. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Serra, P.; Fierro, G. Outage cost in Chilean industry. Energy Econ. 1997, 19, 417–434. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Bernstein, M.A.; Hegazy, Y. The economic costs of electricity shortages: A case study of Egypt. Bell J. Econ. 1988, 13, 249–253. [Google Scholar]
  18. Chen, C.-Y.; Vella, A. Estimating the economic costs of electricity shortages using input-ouput analysis: The case of Taiwan. Appl. Econ. 1994, 26, 1061–1069. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Leontief, W. Composite commodities and the problem of index numbers. Econometrica 1936, 4, 39–59. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Liu, H.T.; Guo, J.E.; Qian, D.; Xi, Y.M. Comprehensive evaluation of household indirect energy consumption and impacts of alternative energy policies in China by input-output analysis. Energy Policy 2009, 37, 3194–3204. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. 2009 I-O Table; Bank of Korea: Seoul, Korea, 2010.
  22. At the time of 31 December 2009, USD 1.0 was approximately equal to KRW 1,100.
  23. Howe, C.W.; Smith, M.G. The value of water supply reliability in urban water systems. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 1994, 26, 19–30. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Hirschman, A.O. The Strategy of Economic Development; Yale University Press: New Haven, CT, USA, 1985. [Google Scholar]
  25. Oosterhaven, J. On the plausibility of supply-driven input-output model. J. Reg. Sci. 1988, 28, 203–217. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Oosterhaven, J. Leontief versus Ghoshian price and quantity models. South. Econ. J. 1996, 62, 750–759. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Davis, H.C.; Salkin, E.L. Alternative approaches to the estimation of economic impacts resulting from supply constraints. Ann. Reg. Sci. 1984, 18, 25–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Wu, R.H.; Chen, C.Y. On the application of input-output analysis to energy issues. Energy Econ. 1990, 12, 71–76. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Kim, M.; Yoo, S.-H. The Economic Cost of Unsupplied Diesel Product in Korea Using Input-Output Analysis. Energies 2012, 5, 3465-3478. https://doi.org/10.3390/en5093465

AMA Style

Kim M, Yoo S-H. The Economic Cost of Unsupplied Diesel Product in Korea Using Input-Output Analysis. Energies. 2012; 5(9):3465-3478. https://doi.org/10.3390/en5093465

Chicago/Turabian Style

Kim, Myunghwan, and Seung-Hoon Yoo. 2012. "The Economic Cost of Unsupplied Diesel Product in Korea Using Input-Output Analysis" Energies 5, no. 9: 3465-3478. https://doi.org/10.3390/en5093465

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop