Next Article in Journal
Exploring Landscape Engagement through a Participatory Touch Table Approach
Previous Article in Journal
Social Support Networks and the Mental Health of Runaway and Homeless Youth
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Determinants of Market Share of For-Profit Hospitals: An Empirical Examination

1
Samsung Economic Research Institute, Seoul 137-955, Korea
2
School of Business Administration, College of Business and Economics, Chung-Ang University, Seoul 156-756, Korea
3
Wharton Research Data Service, The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, PA 19104, USA
4
Graduate School of Business Administration, Chung-Ang University, Seoul 156-756, Korea
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Soc. Sci. 2017, 6(4), 119; https://doi.org/10.3390/socsci6040119
Submission received: 11 August 2017 / Revised: 23 September 2017 / Accepted: 28 September 2017 / Published: 3 October 2017

Abstract

:
This study estimates the effects of a prospective payment system on the growth of for-profit hospitals. The empirical results show that the proportion of patient care paid for by Medicare managed care has a positive, statistically significant relationship with the market share of for-profit hospitals. Medicare managed care reimburses health care providers prospectively, and a larger portion of prospective reimbursements is received by for-profit hospitals, whose market share consequently increases. In addition, the proportion of patients with Medi-Cal and third party managed care has a positive, statistically significant relationship with the market share of for-profit hospitals.

1. Introduction

The significant growth of for-profit hospitals is the most important change in the predominantly nonprofit hospital market in the last two decades.1 The growth in the market share of for-profit hospitals among U.S. community hospitals in the last two decades is an example of this trend (from 1980 to 2007, for-profit hospital growth was 5.3%, which is comparatively faster than the 2.7% growth of nonprofit hospitals and the −7.8% growth of government hospitals (Lee and Rosenman 2013).
There are two traditional views on why this change has occurred. First, for-profit hospitals are organized and operated by physicians who are unable to obtain admitting privileges at existing nonprofit hospitals. This distinction plays an important role in providing a financial advantage to for-profit hospitals, since for-profit hospitals are able to make a direct profit from the patients in their hospitals. Araújo et al. (2014) document the determinants of efficiency for Brazilian for-profit hospitals, and Langland-Orban et al. (2015) explain the differences in operating profitability between for-profit and nonprofit hospitals by analyzing Florida community hospitals during Medicare policy changes from 2000 to 2010. However, Woolhandler and Himmelstein (2004), Gawande (2009), and Teno et al. (2010) document that for-profit hospitals tend to provide unnecessary care and bill Medicare more while thy do not necessarily yield substantial enhancements in health outcomes.
The second explanation for the growth of for-profit hospitals is that hospitals organized for profit can respond much more rapidly to an increase in patients’ demands than nonprofit hospitals can. This difference can be explained by the financial sources of nonprofit hospitals. Nonprofit hospitals have relied heavily on capital contributions through either private charity or government aid. This financial capital structure can be an obstacle for nonprofit hospitals in responding to market change. For example, in some areas, rapid population growth generated a higher demand for additional hospital beds that was not immediately fulfilled by nonprofit hospitals, perhaps because the personal incomes of the people in these areas were not initially high enough to provide the necessary charitable support. Therefore, periods of rapid population growth have allowed for-profit hospitals to enter the industry (Bays 1983). In addition, Sloan (2000) document that the prices for health care services in for-profit nonprofit hospitals are as high as the ones in for-profit hospitals.
However, one question that has arisen from the above explanations is why there are no concerns about hospital financing or the reimbursement system. It is essential to investigate the hospital market structure since reimbursement schemes affect hospitals’ profits differently depending on the type of ownership. Reimbursement especially affects hospital behavior because it facilitates the acquisition of medical technologies, which have a crucial role in attracting patients. Chang and Jacobson (2011) argue that for-profit hospitals provide different quantities of health care and thus this incurs heterogeneity in the Medicare reimbursements compared to nonprofit counterparts.
The objective of this study is to estimate the effects of a prospective payment system on the growth of for-profit hospitals. Our central hypothesis is that the prospective payment system helps for-profit hospitals capture a larger market share, and this study is primarily concerned with addressing this claim.

2. Empirical Approach

To investigate how prospective reimbursement helps to increase the market share of for-profit hospitals, this study models the market share of each for-profit hospital in each time period separately as applying the theoretical implications in Lee (2010) and Lee and Rosenman (2013). The basic regression model is of the form:
s i t = α p i t + β t i t + γ d i t + e i t
where, for the ith for-profit hospital in time period t, s i t is the hospital’s market share, p i t represents the proportion of the hospital’s inpatients covered by different payer types, t i t is the type of care provided to patients, and d i t is the hospital’s direct expenses. α , β , and γ are vectors of the parameters to be estimated and potentially take on different values in each time period, and e i t is an error term that may include both individual-specific and idiosyncratic elements.
The dependent variable, the market share of for-profit hospitals, is calculated as the number of discharges from the selected for-profit hospitals divided by the total number of discharges from all of the hospitals in the market in each year. There are three categories of independent variables: the proportion of inpatient services utilization by payer type, the number of licensed beds by type of care, and direct expenses by cost center group.
The payer types include Medicare, Medicaid, “other third party,” indigent programs, and self-pay. Furthermore, each of the above payer types (Medicare, Medicaid, other third parties, indigent programs, and self-pay) is further specified as “managed” or “traditional” care. This study only considers patients covered by a Medicare or Medicaid managed care plan, since they represent the majority of patients covered by prospective reimbursement.
Utilization according to the type of care provided by each hospital is also included as an independent variable to discern the types of care hospitals focus on to attract more patients. The types of care provided by each hospital are defined as acute, psychiatric, chemical dependency, rehabilitation, and long-term care.
The last independent variable category is direct expenses. This variable is included in Equation (1) to assess how hospitals’ expenditures affect the market share of for-profit hospitals. Direct expenses are categorized as ambulatory, ancillary, purchased, and general services and as hospital and malpractice insurance.
Since the market share of for-profit hospitals has a longitudinal character, testing for random effects is required. First, the Breusch and Pagan Lagrange multiplier test is conducted. Then, to test for the orthogonality of the random effects and regressors, the Hausman test is also conducted.

3. Sample

3.1. Data and Variables

The data comes from the Office of Statewide Health Planning and Development (OSHPD), which provides annual financial data for licensed hospitals in California (see Brown et al. (2011) for details). All hospitals in the state provide inpatient and outpatient medical services in the areas of general, pediatric, psychiatric, and specialty care. The ownership type varies and can be categorized as nonprofit, for-profit, state, government, or district. This study uses data from 85 general for-profit hospitals for the sample period from 2003 to 2007.
Hospital accounting and financing reporting began in California with the passage of the California Hospital Disclosure Act by the California Legislature, Senate Bill 283, in 1971. The Act created the California Hospital Commission and gave it the authority to set standards for uniform hospital accounting and reporting to enable the public, third-party payers, and other interested parties to analyze the financial aspects of hospitals in California. These reports include general hospital information, services utilization data, patient revenues, expenses, balance sheets, and labor and productivity data, and they also provide extensive information about patient origin and the market shares of the selected hospitals.
Table 1 presents the number and percentage of California general hospitals by ownership type (for-profit and nonprofit), size, and year (2003 through 2007). The number of hospitals changes minimally during the study period.2 Nonprofit hospitals are the dominant ownership type in California, which is consistent with the trends in the U.S. hospital market. The average numbers of licensed beds of for-profit and nonprofit hospitals are 170 and 265, respectively, which implies nonprofit hospitals also dominate in size in California.

3.2. Market Share

Before describing the data further, let us discuss the overall trends for California hospitals. Nonprofit hospitals dominate in terms of both average and cumulative market share in California. The average market share is calculated as the number of discharges from the selected hospitals divided by the total number of discharges from all of the hospitals in the market in each year. The cumulative market share of each hospital type is calculated as the sum of the market share of each hospital of that type in each year.
Table 2 and Table 3 show the average and cumulative market shares, respectively, of hospitals by ownership type. Table 2 shows that the growth of for-profit hospitals is also reflected in their average market share. The average market share of for-profit hospitals in California grows from 0.197% to 0.208%. The average market share of for-profit hospitals with under 100 licensed beds slightly decreases, whereas that of hospitals with over 100 licensed beds increases. Interestingly, the average market share of nonprofit hospitals is slightly decreasing, and this pattern is especially evident among nonprofit hospitals that have between 200 and 250 licensed beds. Table 3 shows that the cumulative market share of for-profit hospitals grows slightly during the study period, whereas nonprofit hospitals do not exhibit consistent trends. However, at the market level in California, the cumulative market share of nonprofit hospitals is around 60%, whereas for for-profit hospitals, it is around 15%.

3.3. Hospital Quality

Next, we consider the quality of hospitals in California. In this study, a measure of hospital inpatients’ mortality rate is used to indicate quality. Inpatient mortality indicators form a set of measures that provide a perspective on the quality of hospital care using patient data routinely reported to the OSHPD. The indicators include medical conditions and procedures for which mortality rates vary significantly across institutions. Evidence suggests that high mortality may be associated with deficiencies in the quality of hospital care provided. These indicators (Inpatient Quality Indicators (Fishers Lane, Rockville, MD, USA), Version 3.2) were developed by the Agency for Healthcare Research and Quality (AHRQ), a federal agency, and are provided by the OSHPD for use by California consumers and healthcare purchasers and providers. Eight of the fifteen AHRQ Inpatient Quality Indicators are produced by the OSHPD for public release and are analyzed in this study. Five of them are related to in-hospital deaths after surgery, and three are related to in-hospital deaths after treatment for some medical conditions. Table 4 and Table 5 display these measures of hospital quality in California for the sample period.
Table 4 reports indicators related to in-hospital deaths after the following five types of surgery: esophageal resection, pancreatic resection, craniotomy, carotid endarterectomy, and percutaneous transluminal coronary angioplasty. Table 5 presents indicators related to in-hospital deaths after treatment for the following three medical conditions: acute stroke, gastrointestinal hemorrhage, and hip fracture.
These indicators are viewed as potentially useful starting points for examining hospital quality, but they are not regarded as absolute measures of quality. However, when this information and its limitations are carefully considered alongside other reliable healthcare provider information, this data may be helpful to patients and purchasers, such as insurance providers, when making decisions about healthcare. Healthcare providers may also benefit from using this information to improve quality.
Some hospitals tend to treat higher-risk patients, who have a greater chance of dying following a surgical procedure or treatment for a serious medical condition. To ensure that all California hospitals are assessed fairly, the OSHPD uses statistical risk adjustments to account for patient differences. Therefore, in this study, the risk-adjusted mortality rates for the aforementioned types of surgeries and treatments are used to measure hospital quality.
Among the risk-adjusted rates of in-hospital deaths after surgeries, only those of craniotomy, carotid endarterectomy, and percutaneous transluminal coronary angioplasty can be meaningfully compared between for-profit and nonprofit hospitals. However, neither type of hospital is found to provide much higher quality than the other in terms of these risk-adjusted mortality rates. Overall, for-profit hospitals have slightly lower mortality rates, but this result might be because they perform substantially fewer surgeries.
The risk-adjusted rates of in-hospital deaths after treatment for the aforementioned medical conditions are more comparable. For-profit hospitals provide better quality in the treatment of acute stroke and hip fracture, whereas nonprofit hospitals provide better quality in the treatment of gastrointestinal hemorrhage. Interestingly, for all treatment types, for-profit hospitals with under 200 licensed beds have lower mortality rates on average than nonprofit hospitals of the same size. However, nonprofit hospitals with 200–350 licensed beds exhibit better quality than similar-sized for-profit hospitals across all medical treatment types.

3.4. Proportion of Inpatients by Payer Type

Table 6 displays the percentage of inpatients by payer type. Each number in the table is calculated in percentage as the number of discharges covered by each payer type over the total number of discharges from the selected hospitals each year. The payer types are Medicare, Medicaid (Medi-Cal), “other third parties,” “indigent programs,” and “other payers.” For the Medicare, Medi-Cal, and “other third parties” payer types, both “traditional” and “managed” care are considered.
“Managed care” patients are patients enrolled in a managed care plan to receive health care from providers (specifically, from Health Maintenance Organizations) on a pre-negotiated or per diem basis. For example, the “Medicare managed care” category includes patients covered by a managed care plan funded by Medicare, whereas the “traditional Medicare” category includes patients covered under the Social Security Amendments of 1965. The “traditional Medi-Cal” category includes patients who qualify as needy under state laws. “Other third parties” includes patients enrolled in the Healthy Families program, Short-Doyle, and the Civilian Health and Medical Program of the Uniformed Services. The “other payers” (i.e., not the “other third parties”) category includes self-paying patients.
Overall, the Medicare program covers over 40%, other third parties cover about 30%, and Medi-Cal covers over 20% of California patients. The percentage of for-profit hospitals’ inpatients covered by Medicare increased by 9.3% from 2003 to 2007, whereas that of nonprofit hospitals did not change. However, the percentage of inpatients covered by Medi-Cal did not change for either hospital type. For both hospital types, the percentage of inpatients covered by other third parties slightly decreased during the five-year period. Therefore, the most notable change is the increase in the percentage of patients of for-profit hospitals covered by Medicare.

3.5. Per Case Reimbursement

We consider per case inpatient reimbursement to understand the financial schemes for hospital treatment reimbursements. To reflect the per unit charges of each hospital adjusted for illness, this study uses the case mix index (CMI). The CMI is the relative cost of the resources needed to treat the mix of patients in a licensed California hospital during a calendar year (Lee 2015). According to the OSHPD, the CMI can be used to adjust the average cost per patient for a given hospital relative to the adjusted average costs for other hospitals by dividing the average cost per patient by the hospital’s calculated CMI (Meyer et al. 2007). Therefore, the adjusted average cost per patient reflects the charges reported for the types of cases treated in that year. For example, if a hospital has a CMI greater than 1.00, its adjusted cost per patient or per day will be lower than its unadjusted cost per patient, and, conversely, if a hospital has a CMI less than 1.00, its adjusted cost will be higher (Anyika 2015).
The per inpatient case amount received from each type of hospital payer is calculated by the following formula:
P I R i j = G I P i j I P i j * C M I i * N P R i j G P R i j
where i = hospital and j = Medicare, Medicaid (Medi-Cal), and other third parties. In Equation (2), PIR represents per inpatient reimbursement, GIP is gross inpatient revenue, IP is the number of inpatients, NPR is net patient revenue, and GPR is gross patient revenue. As following the rule of Internal Revenue Service, the first part of Equation (2) represents charges adjusted per inpatient case at the hospital’s full, established rates for the provision of patient care services, before deductions from revenue are applied. The second part of Equation (2) represents the proportion of the full amount that is actually received from third-party payers. Since net inpatient revenue is unavailable, PIR is calculated using the proportion of the amount of total patient revenue. Table 7 shows the per case reimbursement by payer type in each type of hospital.
In general, hospital reimbursement increases over the study period, with a drop in 2007. For-profit hospitals are reimbursed more than nonprofit hospitals are per treatment case. Hospitals are reimbursed more when treating patients covered by other third parties than when treating those on Medicare or Medicaid. For-profit hospitals are reimbursed slightly more than nonprofit hospitals, whereas the reimbursement amounts for Medicare managed care are almost the same for the two hospital types.

3.6. Other Independent Variables of For-Profit Hospitals

As described previously, three categories of independent variables are used in this study: the proportion of inpatient utilization by payer type, the number of licensed beds by type of care, and direct expenses by cost center group. The payer types provided by each hospital are specified as the two managed care programs (Medicare and Medi-Cal), other third parties, indigent programs, and self-pay. This study uses the managed care programs, Medicare and Medi-Cal, since they accurately reflect the current prospective payment system. A second independent variable is licensed bed utilization according the type of care provided by each hospital, specified as acute, psychiatric, chemical dependency, rehabilitation, or long-term.
The last independent variable category is direct expenses, which are categorized as ambulatory, ancillary, purchased, and general services and as hospital and malpractice insurance. Table 8 provides information on the data used in the empirical analysis and the means and standard deviations of the variables used in the estimation. Of the 430 total data sets of for-profit hospitals over the five-year period, 244 had no missing values and, thus, were used in the empirical analysis.

4. Results

To test for random effects, the Breusch and Pagan’s (1980) Lagrange multiplier test was conducted. The obtained Lagrange multiplier test statistic was 262.03, which far exceeds 3.84, the 95% critical value for a chi-squared distribution with one degree of freedom. This result implies that a classical model with a single constant term is inappropriate for the data. Instead, a random effects model should be used. Because a fixed effects model might produce the same results, the Hausman test was conducted as well, resulting in a test statistic of 1.02. The critical value for the chi-squared distribution with thirteen degrees of freedom is 22.36, which is far larger than the test statistic value. As a result, the hypothesis that individual hospital effects are uncorrelated with other variables in the model cannot be rejected. Both test results indicate that a random effects model is the better choice. Table 9 presents the results of the random effects model analysis of the relative market share equation for for-profit hospitals.
Two-step estimations are utilized to fully investigate the effect of prospective reimbursements on market share. The first step is estimating the prospective reimbursement effects of quality improvements and cost-saving investments, and the second step is estimating the effect of these changes in investments on the relative market share of for-profit hospitals. Unfortunately, data for direct quality improvements and cost saving investments are unavailable, so two-step estimation cannot be conducted. Instead, this study investigates the overall, indirect, prospective reimbursement effects on the relative market share. The relative market share equation of the for-profit hospitals is estimated using the generalized least squares method, and most of the explanatory variables have significance levels of at least 10%.
The most important result in the context of this analysis is that the proportion of patients paying with Medicare managed care increases the market share of for-profit hospitals (significant at the 1% level). Because Medicare managed care reimburses the health care provider prospectively, we can infer that a larger portion of prospective reimbursements is received by for-profit hospitals, thus increasing the market share of for-profit hospitals. A larger proportion of patients with Medi-Cal managed care and other third party coverage significantly increases the market share of for-profit hospitals.
Having more beds for acute, psychiatric, and rehabilitation care also increases the relative market share of for-profit hospitals; this result is because most patients in a general hospital (91%) receive these three types of care.
Of the direct expenses analyzed, ancillary services, general services, and hospital and professional malpractice insurance all increase the market share of for-profit hospitals with a significance of at least 10%. Ancillary services include specific diagnostic or therapeutic services for patients. Convenient ancillary services, therefore, can play a significant role in a patient’s choice of hospital. Because ancillary services are special services that involve case-specific charges in addition to routine charges, they produce more revenue than routine diagnostic services do. Direct expenses related to general services include non-revenue-producing costs, such as dietary and hospital maintenance, which implies that for-profit hospitals invest more in amenities in order to obtain a larger market share.
The result for hospital and professional malpractice insurance can be explained from a cost and treatment perspective. As for-profit hospitals purchase more malpractice insurance, their malpractice liability is reduced, and operating costs decrease. Decreased costs can potentially increase the quality of hospital care and, thus, increase market share. Alternatively, from a treatment perspective, malpractice insurance can be a backup for loss-making services that induces the active treatment of high-risk patients, which attracts more patients.

5. Conclusions

This study investigates the determinants of market share of for-profit hospitals. In particular, it focuses on the effect of a prospective payment system on for-profit hospital growth. The findings show that the proportion of patient care paid by Medicare managed care is positively associated with the market share of for-profit hospitals. A larger portion of prospective reimbursements is received by for-profit hospitals, and since Medicare managed care reimburses health care providers prospectively, a higher proportion of Medicare managed care increases the market share of for-profit hospitals. We also find that the proportion of inpatients with Medi-Cal and other third-party managed care is positively associated with the market share of for-profit hospitals.

Acknowledgments

The paper is reorganized based on the empirical part of Seungchul Lee’s Ph.D. dissertation at Washington State University. This research was supported by the Chung-Ang University Research Scholarship Grants in 2016.

Author Contributions

The authors contributed equally to this work.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Anyika, Chinwe. 2015. Modeling and Analysis of a Clinical Documentation Improvement System: Calculating Patient Outcomes. Ph.D. dissertation, Rutgers University-School of Health Related Professions, Chung, Newark, NJ, USA. [Google Scholar]
  2. Araújo, Cláudia, Carlos P. Barros, and Peter Wanke. 2014. Efficiency determinants and capacity issues in Brazilian for-profit hospitals. Health Care Management Science 17: 126–38. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  3. Bays, Carson W. 1983. Patterns of hospital growth: The case of profit hospitals. Medical Care 21: 850–57. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  4. Brekke, Kurt R., Luigi Siciliani, and Odd Rune Straume. 2011. Hospital competition and quality with regulated prices. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 113: 444–69. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Breusch, Trevor Stanley, and Rodney Pagan Pagan. 1980. The Lagrange multiplier test and its applications to model specification in econometrics. The Review of Economic Studies 47: 239–53. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Brown, Edmund G., Jr., Douglas Sale, and Stephanie Clendenin. 2011. Office of statewide health planning and development California workforce investment board health workforce development council career pathway sub-committee final report 2011. Available online: https://pdfs.semanticscholar.org/bfca/1495f9f433d4fc331dcc51fa82a09783bbae.pdf (accessed on 15 May 2012).
  7. Chang, Tom, and Mireille Jacobson. 2011. What do Nonprofit Hospitals Maximize? Evidence from California’s Seismic Retrofit Mandate. NBER Working Paper Series. Available online: http://users.nber.org/~jacobson/ChangJacobson12.5.10.pdf (accessed on 13 March 2012).
  8. Friesner, Daniel L., and Robert Rosenman. 2002. Cost shifting revisited: The case of service intensity. Health Care Management Science 5: 15–24. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  9. Gawande, Atul. 2009. The cost conundrum. The New Yorker, June 1, 36–44. [Google Scholar]
  10. Gaynor, Martin, and Robert Town. 2012. The impact of hospital consolidation–update. The Synthesis Project. Robert Wood Johnson Foundation. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Herr, Annika. 2011. Quality and welfare in a mixed duopoly with regulated prices: The case of a public and a private hospital. German Economic Review 12: 422–37. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Lakdawalla, Darius, and Tomas Philipson. 2006. The nonprofit sector and industry performance. Journal of Public Economics 90: 1681–98. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Langland-Orban, Barbara, John T. Large, Alan M. Sear, Hanze Zhang, and Nanhua Zhang. 2015. Operating profitability of for-profit and not-for-profit Florida community hospitals during Medicare policy changes, 2000 to 2010. INQUIRY: The Journal of Health Care Organization, Provision, and Financing 52. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  14. Lee, Seungchul. 2010. Reimbursement and Investment: Why Market Share of For-Profit Hospitals Increased after Prospective Payment. Ph.D. dissertation, Washington State University of WA, Pullman, WA, USA. [Google Scholar]
  15. Lee, Jinhyung. 2015. Network Effects of Health Information Technology: Evidence from California Hospitals. Korean Economic Review 31: 359–81. [Google Scholar]
  16. Lee, Seungchul, and Robert E. Rosenman. 2013. Reimbursement and investment: Prospective payment and for-profit hospitals’ market share. Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade 13: 503–18. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Meyer, Elisabeth, Juergen Buttler, Christian Schneider, Egid Strehl, Barbara Schroeren-Boersch, Petra Gastmeier, Henning Ruden, Josef Zentner, Franz D. Daschner, and Frank Schwab. 2007. Modified guidelines impact on antibiotic use and costs: Duration of treatment for pneumonia in a neurosurgical ICU is reduced. Journal of antimicrobial chemotherapy 59: 1148–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  18. Sloan, Frank A. 2000. Not-for-profit ownership and hospital behavior. Handbook of Health Economics 1: 1141–74. [Google Scholar]
  19. Solutions, Treo. 2004. Costs, commitment and locality: A comparison of for-profit and not-for-profit health plans. INQUIRY: The Journal of Health Care Organization, Provision, and Financing 41: 116–29. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  20. Spetz, Joanne, Jean Ann Seago, and Shannon Mitchell. 1999. Changes in Hospital Ownership in California. San Francisco: Public Policy Institute of California. [Google Scholar]
  21. Teno, Joan M., Susan L. Mitchell, Pedro L. Gozalo, David Dosa, Amy Hsu, Orna Intrator, and Vincent Mor. 2010. Hospital characteristics associated with feeding tube placement in nursing home residents with advanced cognitive impairment. JAMA 303: 544–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  22. Woolhandler, Steffie, and David U. Himmelstein. 2004. The high costs of for-profit care. Canadian Medical Association Journal 170: 1814–15. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
1
The literature extensively documents the competition between for-profit and nonprofit hospitals. See Friesner and Rosenman (2002), Solutions (2004), Lakdawalla and Philipson (2006), Brekke et al. (2011), Herr (2011), and Gaynor and Town (2012), among others, for details.
2
In previous years, the ownership types of some hospitals changed from for-profit to nonprofit and vice versa. Spetz et al. (1999) highlight little change in the overall share of hospitals held by nonprofit and for-profit owners from 1986–1999. Of the 296 ownership changes between 1986 and 1996, only 13 involved conversions from nonprofit to for-profit ownership. During the same period, 12 hospitals switched from for-profit to nonprofit ownership. About 80 percent of hospital ownership changes in California did not involve any change in the nonprofit or for-profit status of the hospital (Spetz et al. 1999).
Table 1. Number and Percentage of California General Hospitals by Ownership Type.
Table 1. Number and Percentage of California General Hospitals by Ownership Type.
Hospital Size (Number of Licensed Beds)20032004200520062007
FPHNPHFPHNPHFPHNPHFPHNPHFPHNPH
<50515416316316416
50–10013181318151616161415
100–15023232320232224232424
150–20021252124202320232021
200–25011201116121711161218
250–300316322319321220
300–350118116115117117
350–400413416317315213
400–450314312413412515
450–5000507080809
500–5500908060706
550–6000202040403
600–6500001010103
650–10000404040403
>10001212131111
Total8518484184851848518485184
Percentage31.568.531.568.531.568.531.568.531.568.5
Average Number of Licensed Beds168257167260167269165264180264
Notes: The total number of general hospitals in California in the sample is 269. FPH and NPH denote for-profit hospitals and nonprofit hospitals, respectively.
Table 2. Average Market Share (Percentage) of California General Hospitals with Licensed Beds by Ownership Type.
Table 2. Average Market Share (Percentage) of California General Hospitals with Licensed Beds by Ownership Type.
Hospital Size (Number of Licensed Beds)20032004200520062007
FPHNPHFPHNPHFPHNPHFPHNPHFPHNPH
<500.0380.0510.0370.0480.0360.0510.0260.0510.0180.050
50–1000.0770.1090.0710.1010.0740.1050.0670.1040.0660.106
100–1500.1480.1830.1480.1930.1570.1810.1510.1780.1510.181
150–2000.2180.2980.2130.2980.2190.2900.2290.2990.2910.292
200–2500.2370.4000.2290.3620.2340.3520.2390.3490.2700.340
250–3000.4230.4310.3970.4430.3550.4380.3690.4420.4100.463
300–3500.3710.4810.2890.4850.2780.4710.2660.4770.2690.456
350–4000.6160.5700.6180.5540.6160.5570.5970.5610.6100.550
400–4500.3840.5690.4780.5510.4720.5360.4830.5350.4260.525
450–50000.56800.68800.63600.6340.6080.681
500–55000.84700.74600.73900.71000.726
550–60000.58900.58800.70200.67000.603
600–6500000.71900.71700.73700.911
650–100001.11800.10201.13301.12301.139
>10000.2021.02701.03600.94800.95300.924
Total0.1970.3860.2020.3840.2030.3840.2020.3820.2080.382
Notes: The total number of general hospitals in California in the sample is 269. FPH and NPH denote for-profit hospitals and nonprofit hospitals, respectively.
Table 3. Cumulative Market Share (Percentage) of California General Hospitals by Ownership Type.
Table 3. Cumulative Market Share (Percentage) of California General Hospitals by Ownership Type.
Hospital20032004200520062007
For-Profit Hospitals (86)13.614.114.614.614.7
Nonprofit Hospitals (184)58.056.558.259.959.3
Note: The number of observations is given in parentheses.
Table 4. Hospital Quality (In-hospital Deaths after Surgery—Risk-adjusted Mortality Rate).
Table 4. Hospital Quality (In-hospital Deaths after Surgery—Risk-adjusted Mortality Rate).
Hospital Size (Number of Licensed Beds)Esophageal ResectionPancreatic ResectionCraniotomyCarotid EndarterectomyPercutaneous Transluminal Coronary Angioplasty
FPHNPHFPHNPHFPHNPHFPHNPHFPHNPH
<50NANANANANANANA0(2)NANA
50–100NANANANANANA0(4)0(3)1.75(2)NA
100–150NANANA0(2)2.42(4)4.86(3)0(4)0.36(15)1.10(3)0.97(4)
150–200NANANA18.93(3)4.29(10)6.9(7)0.66(9)0.17(15)1.01(6)1.14(10)
200–250NA0(1)NA0(6)5.56(6)3.61(14)0.137(8)0.52(15)1.16(5)0.82(10)
250–300NA0(1)NA0(3)9.65(2)6.14(10)0.9(2)0.71(19)0(2)1.48(13)
300–350NA44.9(1)NA2.9(5)7.9(1)6.43(14)0(1)0.27(16)1.6(1)1.10(13)
350–400NANANA4.4(4)6.3(2)6.02(10)0.5(2)0.35(13)1.05(2)1.4(7)
400–4504.4(1)NA0(2)11.09(10)4.98(5)5.97(13)0.46(5)0.38(14)0.72(4)1.31(13)
450–500NA0(1)NA19.4(3)9.6(1)6.2(9)1(1)0.17(9)1.6(1)1.41(8)
500–550NA0(1)NA0(4)NA6.33(6)NA0(6)NA1.22(5)
550–600NA0(1)NA8.3(1)NA12.5(3)NA0(3)NA1.7(2)
600–650NA4.1(2)NA21.3(3)NA7.1(3)NA0(3)NA1.86(3)
650–1000NA0(2)NA5.7(2)NA6.43(3)NA0(3)NA1.26(3)
>1000NA34.3(1)NA0(1)NA7.8(1)0(1)0(1)NA1.5(1)
Total4.4(1)7.94(11)0(2)7.26(47)5.17(31)6.06(96)0.32(37)0.33(137)1.08(26)1.25(92)
Note: The number of observations is given in parentheses.
Table 5. Hospital Quality (In-Hospital Deaths after Treatment for Specific Medical Conditions—Risk-adjusted Mortality Rate).
Table 5. Hospital Quality (In-Hospital Deaths after Treatment for Specific Medical Conditions—Risk-adjusted Mortality Rate).
Hospital Size (Number of Licensed Beds)Acute StrokeGastrointestinal HemorrhageHip Fracture
FPHNPHFPHNPHFPHNPH
<500(1)14.17(13)0(1)5.22(14)NA4.8(10)
50–1006.41(6)11.59(15)0.85(8)3.12(15)2.22(5)1.91(14)
100–1508.1(21)11.96(24)2.08(21)2.75(24)1.39(21)1.84(24)
150–2006.69(20)10.21(20)1.30(20)2.78(20)1.62(17)2.52(20)
200–25010.28(10)9.21(19)2.36(11)1.75(18)4.82(10)2.07(18)
250–30011.35(2)9.98(20)0.6(2)1.99(20)5.7(2)2.19(20)
300–35010.9(1)9.92(17)2.1(1)1.72(17)2.3(1)1.65(17)
350–40011.35(2)10.94(13)1.45(2)2.43(13)2.1(2)2.68(13)
400–4507.84(5)11.36(15)2.42(5)1.84(15)1.76(5)2.05(14)
450–50012.4(1)9.54(9)2(1)2.55(9)3.6(1)1.94(9)
500–550NA9.91(6)NA1.56(6)NA1.53(6)
550–600NA12.56(3)NA2.4(3)NA2.7(3)
600–650NA11(3)NA1.33(3)NA2.36(3)
650–1000NA10.53(3)NA1.7(3)NA2.8(3)
>100011.5(1)9.4(1)1(1)1.6(1)7.8(1)2.1(1)
Total5.17(31)10.85(96)8.06(70)2.49(181)1.69(73)2.25(175)
Note: The number of observations is given in parentheses.
Table 6. Percentage of Inpatients by Payer Type.
Table 6. Percentage of Inpatients by Payer Type.
Payer20032004200520062007Total
FPHNPHFPHNPHFPHNPHFPHNPHFPHNPHFPHNPHTotal
Medicare44424542464247424542424442
Traditional38324031403340313932343832
Managed510510596115107510
Medi-Cal25172518251825182617222517
Traditional20132013191319132013172013
Managed5354646454453
Other Third Parties24342334223322332334292434
Traditional518575965588518
Managed18261826162416271825201826
Indigent Program1212121222212
Other Payers3223233233332
Observations83183831838418385184861844219171648
Note: FPH and NPH denote for-profit hospitals and nonprofit hospitals, respectively.
Table 7. Reimbursement by Payer ($).
Table 7. Reimbursement by Payer ($).
Payer20032004200520062007
FPHNPHFPHNPHFPHNPHFPHNPHFPHNPH
Medicare
Traditional9258 (79)8115 (157)9401 (80)8310 (158)10,808 (81)8684 (156)13,047 (83)10,095 (154)10,515 (81)9746 (156)
Managed11,043 (63)9826 (119)14,752 (64)9858 (122)12,371 (62)10,877 (123)12,872 (64)12,417 (123)11,433 (66)11,410 (127)
Medi-Cal
Traditional7937 (77)7146 (156)8004 (76)7476 (158)7442 (76)8550 (156)12,028 (79)14,035 (153)10,828 (79)9611 (156)
Managed8385 (68)5524 (112)8975 (70)5945 (113)8074 (69)5626 (120)8799 (69)6642 (115)8527 (71)7562 (118)
Other Third Parties
Traditional15,159 (74)13,087 (155)19,854 (78)14,241 (156)21,394 (78)14,402 (155)23,945 (80)17,657 (152)19,220 (78)17,551 (153)
Managed9190 (70)8885 (128)9773 (69)11,224 (129)11,626 (71)11,159 (131)13,411 (72)14,058 (133)12,665 (73)13,169 (135)
Note: FPH and NPH denote for-profit hospitals and nonprofit hospitals, respectively.
Table 8. Variables, Means, and Standard Deviations.
Table 8. Variables, Means, and Standard Deviations.
Variable (N = 244)MeanStandard Deviation
Market Share0.00180.0014
Proportion of Inpatients by Payer Type
Medicare
 Managed Care Medicare0.05750.0737
 Traditional Care Medicare0.39680.2055
Medicaid (Medi-Cal)
 Managed Care Medi-Cal0.05990.0652
 Traditional Care Medi-Cal0.20010.1683
Other Third Party
 Managed Care Other Third Party0.18000.1705
 Traditional Care Other Third Party0.05780.0976
 Self-Pay0.02940.0312
 Indigent Program0.01790.0235
Licensed Bed Utilizations by Type of Care
 Acute Care140.7398.115
 Psychiatric Care12.26322.628
 Chemical Dependency Care0.62333.5672
 Patient Rehabilitation4.36989.9876
 Patient Long-term Care10.97219.066
Direct Expenses
 Ambulatory Services4,097,9114,470,380
 Ancillary Services26,900,00025,900,000
 General Services9,958,6288,474,563
 Purchased Services11,500,00011,400,000
 Insurance-Hospital & Professional Malpractice1,243,2941,164,995
Table 9. Relative Market Share Equation of For-profit Hospitals.
Table 9. Relative Market Share Equation of For-profit Hospitals.
VariableRandom Effects CoefficientStandard Error
Proportion of Inpatients by Payer Type
 Medicare Managed Care0.0012 ***0.0005
 Medicaid (Medi-Cal) Managed Care0.0011 ***0.0004
 Other Third Party0.0012 ***0.0002
 Self-Pay−0.00020.0006
 Indigent Program0.00060.0009
Licensed Bed Utilizations by Type of Care
 Acute Care (in $100,000s)0.0536 **0.0236
 Psychiatric Care (in $10,000s)0.0469 **0.0198
 Chemical Dependency Care (in $1,000s)−0.02010.0138
 Patient Rehabilitation (in $1,000s)0.0102 **0.0464
 Patient Long-term Care (in $10,000s)0.03590.0232
Direct Expenses
 Ambulatory Services (in $1,000,000,000s)−0.01340.0089
 Ancillary Services (in $1,000,000,000s)0.0127 ***0.0289
 General Services (in $10,000,000,000s)0.0665 *0.0731
 Purchased Services (in $10,000,000,000s)0.01380.0395
 Insurance-Hospital & Professional Malpractice (in $100,000,000s)0.0121 ***0.0021
Constant0.0006 ***0.0001
Adjusted-R20.7078
Notes: ***, **, and * indicate statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Lee, S.; Chung, C.Y.; Sul, H.K.; Lee, Y. Determinants of Market Share of For-Profit Hospitals: An Empirical Examination. Soc. Sci. 2017, 6, 119. https://doi.org/10.3390/socsci6040119

AMA Style

Lee S, Chung CY, Sul HK, Lee Y. Determinants of Market Share of For-Profit Hospitals: An Empirical Examination. Social Sciences. 2017; 6(4):119. https://doi.org/10.3390/socsci6040119

Chicago/Turabian Style

Lee, Seungchul, Chune Young Chung, Hong Kee Sul, and Yunjae Lee. 2017. "Determinants of Market Share of For-Profit Hospitals: An Empirical Examination" Social Sciences 6, no. 4: 119. https://doi.org/10.3390/socsci6040119

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop