1. Introduction
In most countries, banks are chartered and highly regulated financial institutions that are authorized to accept deposits, make loans, and provide a permissible range of financial services. The scope of activities permitted to banks and the cost of regulatory compliance in different jurisdictions largely determines their operating environment and motivate the banking industry to seek the optimal organizational structure in different markets. In Europe, the universal banking model is a well-established feature of most banking systems. Universal banks have been operating in Germany and Switzerland for a very long time. In France, universal banking has become a dominant model after the Banking Act of 1984 abolished a strict separation between deposit banks and business banks. In this model, banks can provide an entire range of financial services, including commercial banking, securities trading, underwriting, general insurance, asset management, and private banking.
A bank holding company (“BHC”) is not a bank itself in the US definition that banks are authorized financial institutions to receive deposits, make loans, and provide checking and savings account services, and have access to the Federal Reserve System (central bank). A BHC is a company that owns, directly or indirectly, a controlling interest in one or more banks and thereby exercises a controlling influence over the management or policies of the bank or banks.
The existence of a holding company legally separates the assets and the owners resulting in a structure offering an added layer of liability protection. This separation protects BHCs from losses accrued by subsidiaries by further limiting the financial and legal liability exposure. In general, this added layer of protection should result in lower risk and, hence, is expected to lower the cost of debt financing for the holding companies compared to stand-alone ones.
While the formation of a holding company theoretically may help a better separation of a troubled subsidiary from the holding company and potentially allow the holding company to enjoy a lower cost of debt, in the case of bank holding companies, the reverse might be true in the post-financial crisis regulatory environment. There are EU-wide rules and strategies for bank recovery and resolution framework. Under the resolution plan, in the event of bank distress, the losses of a failing subsidiary bank will be transferred to the holding company, and the holding company is then recapitalized by converting subordinated debt and total loss-absorbing capacity-eligible debt into equity. Similarly, in the US, the Dodd–Frank Act also provides that the appropriate Federal banking agency shall require the bank holding company to serve as a “source of strength” for any subsidiary of the bank holding company that is a depository institution. In addition, as
Brahmbhatt (
2008) notes, there could be visible differences in defining a holding and subsidiary company since different countries take different stands on the issue mostly from a legal perspective. The cross-selling ability helps a BHC leverage its existing and potential customer base to increase its revenues and market share by offering additional financial products and services. A BHC framework provides opportunities to facilitate growth, achieve greater operating efficiencies, and manage risk in ways that are not possible for stand-alone banks. Subsidiaries of the same BHC can collaborate to offer a full range of financial services, including consumer savings, loans, insurance, personal investing, and commercial and investment banking. In the post-crisis regulatory environment, BHCs are subject to stricter capital and liquidity requirements, and therefore, their bank subsidiaries are expected to enjoy a lower cost of debt. The risk structure of a BHC depends, in part, on the risk of each of the subsidiaries, and, therefore, it is related to the specific risk of each subsidiary. This implies that, at the outset, the risk of a BHC could be greater or lower than that of a stand-alone bank. This work tries to deliberate the market-induced risk spread differential controlling the risk ranking and maturity of the included outstanding bonds.
The empirical evidence on BHCs’ impact on risk structure and, therefore, on the cost of debt is mixed. While BHCs benefit from managing interest rate risk through their trading desks and generating higher capital and profitability from issuing loans, they also introduce additional risks to their lending operations. As the complexity of the bank structure increases, the potential benefits of forming a BHC may diminish. Potentially, holding companies may exploit their subsidiaries; a holding-company structure makes it fairly difficult for the investors and creditors to keep track of all the subsidiaries in order to see an accurate picture of the financial health due to their formational complexity. Moreover, not having to own 100% of the shares might sometimes be considered a disadvantage as it may require the holding company to deal with minority owners. As a result, the net effect of combining an added layer of liability protection and serving as a source of strength for bank subsidiaries on the cost of debt is uncertain suggesting a largely unexplored empirical question of whether the perceived economic benefits of the BHC framework translate into lower cost of debt financing. However, no study has ever tested this hypothesis due to its technical and practical difficulties.
This paper
1, therefore, is an attempt to evaluate the risk structure of BHCs in comparison to stand-alone banks to understand the market-perceived risk reflection on the complexities mentioned above. Our contribution to the existing literature lies in two key areas. Firstly, by specifically examining the Spanish banking industry and incorporating control variables for bond characteristics in our estimation model, our study effectively filters out other bond risk factors such as industry-specific effects, macroeconomic conditions, and country-specific risk. This enables a clearer understanding of the impact of bank holding company structure on bond yields or the cost of debt financing. Secondly, we are among the first, to our knowledge, to employ option-adjusted spread analysis to explore a bank’s bond spread attributed to holding company structure. By adopting this approach, we can offer valuable insights into the implications of BHCs on financial risk within the Spanish banking sector.
In this paper, we empirically examine the Spanish banks’ cost of debts attributable to the ownership structure. Specifically, we evaluate the cost of debt of BHCs in comparison to stand-alone banks to understand the market-perceived risk reflection on the complexities mentioned above. As such, this work uses a state-of-the-art option-adjusted spread analysis to obtain the values of comparable spreads of callable and non-callable bonds to facilitate the main regression testing the hypothesis that BHCs have higher cost of debt.
Our analysis has two stages: The first stage uses an embedded option pricing model to obtain comparable spreads for all kinds of outstanding bonds that define callable bond price as the option-free or noncallable bond price minus the American call option price. This step enables us to obtain the yield spreads of option-embedded callable bonds and option-free noncallable bonds providing us with option-adjusted yield spreads of all ranked outstanding bonds. In the second stage, we regress the obtained spread values on an intercept and a binary variable that separates the ownership structure (i.e., holding companies versus the stand-alone ones) plus controls for the S&P rating class and maturity of those bonds. Using ordinary least square estimation we check the statistical and economic significance of the coefficient of the ownership or legal structure to evaluate the impact of it on bank holding companies cost of debt.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows.
Section 2 describes the hypothesis development.
Section 3 discusses the materials and methods applied in our empirical analysis.
Section 4 presents the data.
Section 5 shows the empirical analysis.
Section 6 discusses and concludes.
2. Literature Review
The literature is visibly divided into supporters and critics of BHCs. Consistent with
Anenberg et al. (
2018), supporters underline that BHCs are likely to spread fixed costs over a larger volume of output, achieve greater cost efficiencies, and pass some of the efficiencies through to competitive prices. They found that customers value the ability to use the same bank to underwrite and lend and that simultaneous lending and underwriting are associated with lower prices.
Comizio et al. (
2017) highlight that the formation of a holding company facilitates better separation of a troublesome subsidiary and effectively insulates the bank subsidiary from potential liability.
Hirtle (
2016) examines the disclosure of bank holding companies and finds that more disclosure is associated with lower idiosyncratic risk. Presumably, banks that are owned by BHCs are subject to more disclosure requirements and supervision by banking regulators. As a result, they should be less risky. In a sense, bank regulations work similarly to debt covenants. They constrain banks’ actions and thereby reduce the costs of conflicts between shareholders and creditors.
Galiay and Maurin (
2015) argue that higher prudential standards for bank capital and liquidity should be rewarded by markets, and thus lower the cost of borrowing. By creating indices of capital, leverage, and liquidity regulations, they provide evidence that changes in bank regulations significantly reduce the transmission of shocks to banks’ funding spreads. Similarly,
Ignatowski and Korte (
2014) also find that banks that are more affected by introducing the Orderly Liquidity Authority significantly reduce their overall risk-taking.
Demsetz and Strahan (
1997) find that while larger BHCs have better diversification with lower idiosyncratic risk, their systematic risk is high due to a lower capital ratio and larger loan portfolio.
Gong et al. (
2018) report that lower capitalization ratios are associated with higher riskiness at the BHC level.
Stiroh and Rumble (
2006) and
Yang and Brei (
2019) suggest that the benefits of diversification may be offset by an increase in exposure to nontraditional banking activities, which are riskier but do not generate higher returns.
Chami et al. (
2022) highlight the advantages of maintaining both lines of business, provided that overleveraging and aggressive behavior by the trading desk are effectively managed.
Cuong (
2021) investigates subsidiaries of BHCs and finds that the insolvency risk of BHC subsidiaries is not that high and attributes this to the complexity and risk associated with adopting more subsidiaries and lines of business within the structure, as implied by the complexity theory discussed by
Lee and Sabourian (
2007) and
Cetorelli and Goldberg (
2014). The structural complexity of BHCs is covered in several research papers (see, for example,
Correa and Goldberg (
2022);
Buch and Goldberg (
2022);
Goldberg and Meehl (
2020) and
Flood et al. (
2020)) as a risk-enhancing factor.
Chernobai et al. (
2021) demonstrate that U.S. banks experience increased operational risk with greater business complexity, especially for banks previously constrained by regulations.
Luciano and Wihlborg (
2018,
2023) analyzed the value and risk effect of a banking group’s organizational choice between branch and subsidiary structure with endogenous leverage and interest rates and a capital requirement constraint. They explain that BHCs should have a higher cost of debt due to their higher leverage compared to operating bonks. As underlined by
Boliari and Topyan (
2022), there are serious drawbacks with holding companies that may be overseeing and making major policy decisions for businesses or industries that they are not particularly familiar with. Additionally, as reported by
Brandao-Marques et al. (
2020), restricting banks’ range of activities ameliorates the link between government support and bank risk taking as this affects the banks’ willingness to take risk and has an impact on the cost of capital of BHCs.
4. Material and Methodology
To estimate the cost of debt financing, we employed an option-adjusted spread (OAS) instead of standard yield-to-maturity spreads. OAS accounts for the presence of embedded options in bonds, such as call provisions, which affect cash flows dependent on future interest rate levels and can impact yields differently from ordinary bonds. OAS analysis incorporates credit risk and contingent cash flow risk, providing insight into the determinants of corporate bond spreads. Previous research has utilized OAS to study various aspects, including corporate bond spreads in emerging markets (
Cavallo and Valenzuela 2010), dynamic behavior of credit spreads on corporate bond portfolios (
Bierens et al. 2003), mortgage spreads (
Boyarchenko et al. 2019), and assessment of bank capital adequacy considering market yield fluctuations and credit spread widening risk (
Letizia 2012).
4.1. Bank Holding Companies
Bank holding companies dominate the holding company counts in almost all countries where holding companies are allowed to operate. The most significant example is the US with BHC constituting 24 percent of all holding companies. This study is limited to the banks in Spain since Spain has a balanced number of bank holding and operating company bonds outstanding. As
Table 1 shows, holding and operating companies are not uniformly distributed among the countries and a meaningful comparison suggests using a country with a balanced number of operating company (opco) and holding company (holdco) bonds outstanding.
4.2. Banking System in Spain
Similar to the universal banking system in other European countries, a bank in Spain (also called a credit institution) can be authorized to conduct both commercial banking and investment banking activities. Therefore, Spanish banks are distinguished not based on their legal form but by the different services and activities they perform. The three types of banks in Spain are commercial banks (bancos), saving banks (cajas), which usually invest in local nonprofit projects and have dwindled after the restructuring and consolidations post-financial crisis of 2008, and credit union banks (cooperativas). Under Spanish law, the latter two types of credit institutions exist apart from banks though they can render banking services.
According to the European Banking Federation’s data, Spanish banking has ten banking groups representing more than 90% of the industry. In detail, there exist 48 private banks, 2 saving banks (cajas), and 61 credit unions (cooperativas). According to the Financial Stability Board’s list of Global Systematically Important Banks, currently, Banco Santander is the only Global Systematically Important Bank (G-SIB) in Spain and is required to hold the higher capital buffers by national authorities to meet the loss-absorbing capacity standard in addition to the regulatory capital requirements set out in the Basel III. Another other large bank holding company is BBVA, which also owns overseas subsidiaries. Other Spanish banks do not have significant global operations.
4.3. Yield Spreads and the Risk Structure
A bond’s yield spread reflects the risk taken by the lender and shows the investors’ assessments of those composite risk components. However, a bond’s yield spread is a composite indicator reflecting economy-specific issues such as the anticipated inflation rate, instrument-specific issues such as maturity and liquidity, and firm-specific issues such as the leverage and possibility of default. Accordingly, one can compare the holding and operating companies of a selected industry by classifying them using risk ratings, and maturities to investigate the yield spread differences to understand their riskiness. This process will help us obtain valuable insights into how the market actually reacts to the ownership structure differences. As such, this study is an attempt to investigate the market-determined option-adjusted yield spreads of bank-holding companies versus stand-alone operating banks in Spain, potentially reflecting bank-holding companies’ cost of debt in comparison to that of the operating banks.
4.4. Fixed Incomes
Fixed-income issuers are borrowers of capital who agree to pay interest and principal to lenders with the terms set in the bond’s prospectuses. Bondholders are the investors in such securities as creditors are typically exposed to numerous risks such as default, liquidity, sector, interest rate, reinvestment, and early redemption, among others. They are willing to accept these risks only if they believe that they are adequately compensated. Accordingly, the amount of incremental return demanded by potential investors also increases as the perceived level of risk and uncertainty associated with a given issue increases.
A bond’s return is usually expressed in terms of yield which measures the rate of return a purchaser would receive if the bond were held to a specific redemption date. The yield rate describes both the discount factor used in present-value computation using the bond’s cash flows and the assumed reinvestment rate for all the coupon payments received.
A bullet bond’s cash flows are independent of the level of interest rates. However, a majority of callable fixed-coupon bonds have interest-level-dependent payment streams making the actual payments connected to the interest rates prevailing at a particular point in time. The yield-spread analysis is a reliable method of measuring incremental return for bullet bonds with their simple cash flow structures that provide coupons, or interest payments at regular intervals and repay the full principal amount at maturity. Conventional bond valuation compares the yield of a bond with that available from a benchmark issue such as a risk-free government bond carrying a similar coupon and duration. The spread or the yield differential between a bond and a similar risk-free issue can therefore be viewed as the incremental return of the non-benchmark issue.
4.5. Option-Adjusted Spread and the Estimation Model
The option-adjusted spread is a measurement of the spread above risk-free rates, but it does not attempt to predict a bond’s likely redemption date. Instead, it treats a bond’s early redemption provisions built into the cash-flow structure as embedded options on its cash flows. The interpretation and calculation of OAS values are also significantly different compared to the traditional yield spread. The OAS computation for callable bonds considers the interest rate volatility since the cash flows of those bonds are sensitive to interest rate levels. We use a lattice model based on a consistent framework for valuing bonds with embedded options as well as noncallable, or bullet, bonds. Since a yield-based model would not use a single rate to discount all the cash flows of a bond with embedded options, the correct spot rate to discount each cash flow will be obtained using the forward rates produced by the lattice model. The OAS values are shown in basis points and interpreted as the spread connected to all possible potential redemption dates of the bond in question. For a noncallable bond, the spread is computed using the redemption at a specific point in time. Since the OAS values can be negative or positive, investors should be careful in interpreting the OAS values. When the OAS value is negative, it implies that the bond’s expected return is lower than that of the risk-free option after taking the redemption option into account. In more detail, although it is unlikely, an option-embedded bond’s return may be lower than that of a risk-free return of the same maturity due to the specifics of the embedded option, making the OAS negative.
The implications of an unknown redemption point are significant since the number of coupon payments and the payment date depend on the redemption date. It should be noted that the traditional price sensitivity measures such as duration and convexity are also connected to the redemption date. Not knowing the actual redemption date is a serious hurdle in evaluating noncallable bonds. Some researchers suggest predicting the future redemption date for the noncallable bonds to be able to value them, but this is as difficult as predicting the future interest rates.
Miller (
2007) defines this as “the most significant risk associated with a callable bond, arguably surpassing the default risk”. On the other hand, even if a predicted redemption date turns out to be accurate, it is virtually impossible to eliminate the uncertainty until shortly before the redemption.
Unlike standard yield-spread analysis, OAS analysis obviates the need to know or predict the redemption date of a callable bond. A bond’s early redemption provisions are treated as options embedded into a bond’s cash flows. Notably, while those provisions are hypothetical options they replicate the early redemption features of a bond. Investors routinely gauge the relative value of a particular bond by weighing its yield spread, or incremental return, against all incremental risks contained in the bond. For a given degree of incremental risk, the greater the yield spread, the more attractive the bond to a potential investor. In more detail, the OAS analysis assumes that the investor of a callable bond has two separate contracts. The first contract is an option-free bond purchased from the issuer that our investor pays and the second is the call option our investor sells to the issuer. In summary, our bond investor pays the market price of the bond and receives the market price of the option.
Once the spreads of operating banks and BHCs are obtained using the process explained above
2, we are ready to test the hypothesis that BHCs have greater cost of debt. The next step is to have a regression equation that has the obtained spread values as the dependent variable and regressing them on a binary ownership structure variable that takes the value of “1” if issued by a stand-alone operating bank and “0” if it is issued by a BHC. Since the bonds’ spread also depends on the riskiness of the bond as well as the maturity of the bond, we included a decimalized control for the maturity of the bond that takes values from 30 days (0.83) to 30 years (30).
In rating corporate bonds, rating agencies in general, and S&P Global Ratings in particular, typically begin with an evaluation of the creditworthiness of the issuer and then move to the credit quality of a specific debt issue. In individual debt issues, S&P Global Ratings evaluates the terms and conditions of the debt security, its legal structure, seniority of the issue, and priority of repayment in the event of default. Rating agencies also consider the existence of credit enhancements such as guarantees, insurance, and collateral.
Since all of our bonds are ranked as either A− or BBB+, we finally added a binary variable that takes the value of 1 if the bond is rated A− and zero otherwise. In summary, we employed a multiple regression equation in which the spread is regressed on the ownership dummy, S&P ranking dummy, and a decimalized maturity variable to test if the spread is economically and statistically significant. Equation (1) below is the main regression equation that tests the hypothesis that the ownership structure has any impact on the cost of debt.
Equation (1) regresses Si, the option-adjusted spread, for bond i on an intercept, α, the ownership structure dummy β so that Opcoi = 1 (0) if the company that issued bond i is an operating (holding) company, the maturity coefficient Φ, and the risk-ranking dummy θ and a stochastic disturbance term εi.
Equation (1) checks the value and statistical significance of the coefficient of our ownership structure binary variable, β that separates the bank-holding companies from the stand-alone banks. All other right-hand side variables are exogenous controls covering riskiness and terms of the bonds. The callable versus noncallable bond issues have been handled with the use of option-adjusted spread analysis.
7. Conclusions
Historically, there were a number of studies favoring the ownership structure of bank holding companies citing their risk-reducing characteristics while a number of other studies suggest the opposite due to the risk-raising features of holding companies as well as their generally higher leverage. The net effect of combining an added layer of liability protection with other weaknesses of bank holding companies on the cost of debt stayed uncertain, suggesting a largely unexplored empirical question of whether the perceived economic benefits of the BHC framework translate into lower cost of debt financing. In an attempt to understand the impact of ownership or legal structure on the cost of debt, this study uses a two-step model to measure the cost of debt differentials between bank-holding company-issued bonds and stand-alone bank-issued bonds.
After controlling bonds’ risk classes using S&P ranking and terms to maturity, our work finds that bank-holding companies in Spain, on average, have 74 basis points higher cost of debt compared to stand-alone banks greater cost of debt. The coefficient of the binary variable that separates the BHCs from the stand-alone ones is very significant, statistically (t = 5.58) and economically (74 basis points).
Our result is important since it suggests that bond investors consider BHCs riskier compared to stand-alone banks in Spain. This also implies that BHCs in Spain are not able to obtain lower-cost debt since the risk-enhancing issues in the bank-holding company structure offset the risk-reducing ones.
Our results support the theoretical foresight of
Luciano and Wihlborg (
2018,
2023) as they highlight that BHCs should have higher cost of debt because they are much more levered than the operating banks. They also note that several worldwide regulations such as the Volcker rule in the US, the Vickers proposal in the UK, and the Liikanen report in the EU “prohibits banks entering into transactions with the institutions they advise, and also from rescuing them.” (
Luciano and Wihlborg 2023, p. 9).
While Spanish regulation does not have the “source of strength” provision in the exact sense of the Dodd–Frank Act in the US that a BHC shall serve as a source of financial and managerial strength to its subsidiaries, the European Banking Authority has several rules and regulations in creating and monitoring the financial safety in BHC formations. Additionally, IMF’s January 2023 report on Spain (IMF Country Report No. 23/33, p. 20) highlights that since the Global Financial Crisis is a source of strength, there is a significant deleveraging in the Spanish private sector.
We suggest that future studies should deal with the potential reasons behind the results. We also suggest that future research should focus on studying the impact of the ownership structure of several different types of holding companies in different countries to see the impact of country-specific risks and legal issues that are potentially different around the world.