1. Introduction
Complementing the classical debates on equilibrium, e.g., from d’Aspremont et al. [
1], and supplementing the early discussions on consumer distribution, e.g., Shilony [
2], this paper re-examines the best location problems from a fundamental perspective. We believe that scrutinizing the distribution pattern of consumers is necessary when performing market analysis. Given that the classical Hotelling’s dispute disappears when consumers are not uniformly distributed, this study demonstrates the local properties for equilibrium under arbitrary consumer distribution.
Motivated by the debate of the smartphone market, this study contends that the implementation of a differentiation strategy is strongly dependent on the concentration of consumers. For example, smartphones are usually sold in screen sizes of 3.0, 4.0, 4.3, 4.7, and 5.5 inches. If most consumers favor a 4.0-inch screen, the two duopolists will most likely change their products to 4.0-inch ones, as shown in Market A of
Figure 1. If consumers are distributed in this single product, the classical dispute on maximal and minimal differentiation vanishes [
2,
3]. If half of the consumers like 4.0 inches and the other half like 4.7 inches, the two companies may differentiate themselves in two market segments, as shown in Market B of
Figure 1. If consumers are randomly distributed, as shown in Market C of
Figure 1, companies may not choose locations as predicted by classical studies. In a conventional setup of spatial competition problems, consumers are assumed to equally prefer each variation of a product in the market, and the strategic choices of firms may be strongly influenced by the particular choice of the transportation cost function [
1,
4,
5]. In a real-world market, consumers are unlikely to be equally attracted to all kinds of products.
A viable prediction of competition intensity should also be contingent on the consumer distribution of the market, rather than a sole factor of consumer utility or transportation cost function. The analytic model in this study assumes that consumers are generically distributed along a “linear city” and considers the balance of two factors, namely, consumer acceptance (utility surplus) and consumer distribution (sales potentials). As highlighted in Calvó-Armengol and Zenou [
6] and Azar [
7], positioning a product in a non-uniform market is essential in marketing research. However, despite the long history and versatile results of ala Hotelling differentiation models, the extant literature does not sufficiently provide suitable location strategies for addressing the case in which consumers are not uniformly distributed in all locations. The dual-channel competition with price sensitivity leads to low profit for a supply chain [
8]. Cost-sharing contracts resolve channel conflict in asymmetric Nash bargaining products [
9]. Shilony [
2] suggests an existence condition for the equilibria of horizontal differentiation in which the demand distribution is confined within convex and concave distribution functions, and predicts that the equilibria should be located near the center of the uni-mode distribution density function. Neven [
3] confirms that firms should closely position themselves towards the center of a concentrated market. Studies by de Palma et al. [
10], Ansari et al. [
11] and Rhee [
12] develop alternative approaches where the purchase quantities of each product type are assumed to be random to represent the heterogeneity of consumer preferences. Their numerical results again confirm the previous conclusion that products will lie close as the market becomes concentrated. Despite these published studies, the location problems are analyzed under a restricted function form and no generic result has been found. This study offers a further understanding of the competition analysis on a generic consumer distribution.
This study demonstrates the existence of subgame perfect Nash equilibrium under generic distribution in consumer preference. We find that competition intensity is affected by the signs of local change rates of the consumer distribution at the endpoints of consumer segments.
2. Competition Model
Consumer tastes are assumed to be distributed arbitrarily with a density function along a market , which is defined as for and . Differentiability for is assumed for ease of analysis, although we permit any form of the density function. A subdifferential or Ito differential can be considered in future research.
The game starts from a situation in which firms compete by selecting location
and then determine the best price
with consideration of the total amount of purchase
. The locations assume that
for notational convenience. A consumer receives a utility of
if purchasing from company
i. A consumer
x makes a final decision to purchase from firm
i when
and
. The number of purchases accumulated in the covered market segment becomes the demand
for company
i. The market segment or horizontal coverage is defined as follows:
The two-player game must involve competition to preclude triviality. The interactions disappear and no competition exists, if market segments do not overlap. Therefore, we assume that segments should be adjacent to one other.
The classical Hotelling’s model is challenged regarding the existence of equilibrium and suffers from discontinuity in the demand function.
Figure 2A shows that the triangle shape of transportation cost functions gives rise to a possibility of discontinuity from line
to
, which is caused by the sudden change in the disappeared intersection between two parallel lines. A number of ala Hotelling models with many variations in the transportation function, such as the quadratic function, can effectively avoid discontinuity and have been proven to have equilibria [
1].
In this study, the particular choice of the transportation cost function is barely considered but the influence of consumer distribution is especially important. Given the analysis goal, the transportation cost function should be as simple as possible. A simple cost function does not only make the mathematical derivation tamable, but also highlights the influence of the arbitrary function form. The linear transportation function is thus employed, but the slopes of functions must be different in order to maintain the differentiability of the resulting demand functions. The consumer utility
is defined as
, where
is the cost of anti-preference in the location disparity.
Figure 2B shows that no sudden change in the intersection will be encountered if the triangles overlap properly. We establish the condition of equilibrium within an open set without having further restriction on decision variables. This open set is the neighborhood that excludes points in which the intersection of indifference points is non-existent.
The expected demand and total profit for firm
i are given by
and
By Stokes’ theorem,
and
become
, and
, respectively. The function
is the distribution function of
f, and
and
are the left and right endpoints, respectively. The values can be obtained by solving
. We therefore have
The two segments must be adjacent to each other, because we exclude situations with no competition. In particular, is the indifference location, where . Thus, .
3. Location Analysis
To characterize the property of consumer distribution, location and price equilibria are analyzed. Given the non-uniform distribution, we obtain results that are different from those of the previous analysis.
Proposition 1. If the consumer distribution function F is non-decreasing and concave, then the location-then-price subgame perfect Nash equilibrium exists and is unique.
Proposition 1 requires the consumer distribution to be non-decreasing and concave. By definition, the distribution function is non-decreasing. This result differs from that of the original Hotelling’s model. To be concave, the consumer preference density function should at least be a non-increasing function. That is, the consumers who prefer a lower segment outnumber those who prefer a higher segment.
Proposition 2. If equilibrium locations and exist, market segmentation can be characterized by the indifferent location that satisfies To rationalize the conditions in Propositions 1 and 2, we consider a situation in which two competing firms determine their best location in a market with non-uniform consumer distribution. If Firm 1 decides to produce a product that moves away from the center to occupy wider coverage, then consumers in the center become uninterested in Product 1, such that Firm 2 will most likely take over the vacancy. By contrast, if most consumers are located at the center market, both firms decrease their coverage span and stay close to the center market. However, a concentration on the competition in the center market may leave the far-end markets uncovered. Therefore, in addition to conventional conditions in competition intensity, consumer distribution also determines the location strategy of a firm. Therefore, market segmentation relies on consumer distribution, competition intensity and cost in anti-preference.
We characterize consumer distribution in Condition (
5). Steep changes in the consumer population give rise to narrow segments and a strong competitive market. However, if the consumer density is uniform, i.e.,
, then having distinct
a,
and
, that satisfy
, is impossible. Thus, this condition asserts that the classical Hotelling’s model fails to find equilibrium in a linear city.
Proposition 2 demonstrates two necessary conditions to identify the nature of the equilibrium. Condition (
5) excludes most situations in which the equilibria do not exist, which is similar to the case of uniform distribution. Condition (
6) further characterizes the possible span of two market segments in equilibrium. Without this condition, an interval can be infinitely small. We now investigate the relationship of the anti-preference cost to the location strategies.
Proposition 3. The competition between two firms weakens when the cost of anti-preference increases, , ifand Condition (
7) specifies the rates of changes in the consumer distribution function on the endpoints of market segments. Proposition 3 suggests that a higher anti-preference cost results in weaker competition, if the rates of changes of consumer density at the endpoints of market segments are either higher or lower than the rate at the center. Intuitively, the implication is true because consumers are unlikely to tolerate deviation from their true preferences. To retain the same segment length, equilibrium pricing should be decreased, and the location should be diversified. However, the maximum objectives may not be achieved under the same segment lengths, because the intuition involves a nonlinear optimizer, which is quadratic in price.
Proposition 4. The competition between two firms intensifies, , if Conversely, , if .
The findings in Proposition 4 are consistent with that of Shilony [
2], except that we have captured the local properties of the consumer distribution. If the local rate of change in the density function of the endpoints has the same sign as the central point for the two adjacent segments, the location strategy should follow a minimal or maximal differentiation principle, as shown in
Figure 3. A counteracting strategy is then recommended in the differentiation situation. Conversely, if the endpoints exhibit the opposite trend of changes in the density function, the location strategy follows a constant differentiation principle. A deterrence strategy is then employed to respond to the actions of the rival.
4. Conclusions
This study sheds new light on the necessity of considering the preference distribution of the consumer population. We show the condition in which the subgame perfect Nash equilibria exist when the consumer distribution function is arbitrary. Our analysis confirms that having SPNE is impossible for uniform distribution. We further provide two necessary conditions to characterize the equilibria, and suggest that the market can be bisected according to the local rates of the density function and the competition strategy. We suggest that a company should implement a minimal or maximal differentiation principle, if endpoints of consumer density function change in the same direction as the central point. Conversely, a company should implement a constant differentiation principle, if the directions are opposite.
This study offers an advantage for marketing managers. We clearly resolve the debate between differentiation and imitation for rival products. We successfully explain why some companies are profitable in selling imitative products but other companies fail in following competitors.
Although this study has relaxed the restricted function form of competitive strategies and offered further understanding of the competition analysis on a generic consumer distribution, the location problems still represent ample research topics for further analytics.
Author Contributions
Conceptualization, T.-Y.O. and Y.J.C.; methodology, Y.J.C.; software, Y.J.C.; validation, T.-Y.O. and Y.J.C.; formal analysis, T.-Y.O. and Y.J.C.; investigation, T.-Y.O. and Y.J.C.; resources, T.-Y.O.; data curation, T.-Y.O.; writing—original draft preparation, T.-Y.O. and Y.J.C.; writing—review and editing, T.-Y.O. and Y.J.C.; visualization, T.-Y.O. and Y.J.C.; supervision, T.-Y.O.; project administration, T.-Y.O.; funding acquisition, T.-Y.O. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.
Funding
This research was funded by the Ministry of Science and Technology, Taiwan grant number 109-2625-M-020-002 and 109-2410-H-992-018-MY2.
Institutional Review Board Statement
Not applicable.
Informed Consent Statement
Not applicable.
Conflicts of Interest
The authors declare no conflict of interest.
Appendix A. Theorem Proofs
Proof. (Proof of Proposition 1.) Recall that
. The indifference point
. For the
segment,
To prove the existence and uniqueness of subgame perfect Nash equilibria, we need to prove the problem having the submodular property is enough [
13,
14]. Because the payoff functions are lower semi-continuous, we can prove our position-then-price subgame is submodular by checking the property of increasing difference. Let
,
and
. We want to check the property of increasing difference
If either
or
, the function
is either 0 or 1, which satisfies the increasing difference properties. If
, it follows that the difference
becomes
If
F is monotonically non-decreasing and concave, from the subadditivity properties of
F, we have
It follows that the difference is greater than
Because and are non-negative, the expression is sufficiently greater than the difference. Because , the increasing difference property holds. □
Proof. (Proof for Proposition 2.) Given that the price difference satisfies
, for all
and
, the payoff functions are continuous differentiable. Let
. The total derivatives are
Because the cumulative distribution function
is monotone, therefore, we have
for all
i. We then obtain the first necessary conditions
From the first part of the proof, we have derived the conditions for ensuring the existence of
. We know
for all
i and by the condition
specified in (
A1), we have
□
Proof. (Proof for Proposition 3.) Concatenating two contiguous intervals of (
5), we have
Write (
A3) in terms of implicit function
and let
. The positioning strategy around the equilibrium can be analyzed by employing the implicit function theorem
.
If , then the condition in the theorem is followed. □
Proof. (Proof for Proposition 4.) Use the relation (
A3) as the implication function. The positioning strategy around the equilibrium can be seen by employing the implicit function theorem
The derivative
if
. □
References
- d’Aspremont, C.; Gabszewicz, J.; Thisse, J. On Hotelling’s Stability in Competition. Econometrica 1979, 47, 1145–1150. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Shilony, Y. Hotelling’s competition with general customer distributions. Econ. Lett. 1981, 8, 39–45. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Neven, D. On Hotelling’s competition with non-uniform customer distributions. Econ. Lett. 1986, 21, 121–126. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Economides, N. Quality variations and maximal variety differentiation. Reg. Sci. Urban Econ. 1989, 19, 21–29. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Hou, H.; Wu, X.; Zhou, W. The competition of investments for endogenous transportation costs in a spatial model. Econ. Model. 2013, 31, 574–577. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Calvó-Armengol, A.; Zenou, Y. The importance of the distribution of consumers in horizontal product differentiation. J. Reg. Sci. 2002, 42, 793–803. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Azar, O. Can more consumers lead to lower profits? A model of multi-product competition. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 2010, 76, 184–195. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Giri, B.C.; Dey, S. Game theoretic models for a closed-loop supply chain with stochastic demand and backup supplier under dual channel recycling. Decis. Mak. Appl. Manag. Eng. 2020, 3, 108–125. [Google Scholar]
- Panda, S.; Modak, N.M.; Cárdenas-Barrón, L.E. Does extended warranty depict competitive advantage to a retailer in a retail-e-tail channel supply chain. Comput. Ind. Eng. 2020, 149, 106770. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- de Palma, A.; Ginsburgh, V.; Papageorgiou, Y.; Thisse, J. The principle of minimum differentiation holds under sufficient heterogeneity. Econometrica 1985, 53, 767–781. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Ansari, A.; Economides, N.; Ghosh, A. Competitive positioning in markets with nonuniform preferences. Mark. Sci. 1994, 13, 248–273. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Rhee, B. Consumer heterogeneity and strategic quality decisions. Manag. Sci. 1996, 42, 157–172. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Fujishige, S. Theory of submodular programs: A Fenchel-type min-max theorem and subgradients of submodular functions. Math. Program. 1984, 29, 142–155. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Topkis, D. Supermodularity and Complementarity; Princeton University Press, Electronic: Princeton, NJ, USA, 1998. [Google Scholar]
| Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations. |
© 2021 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).