Next Article in Journal
M-WDRNNs: Mixed-Weighted Deep Residual Neural Networks for Forward and Inverse PDE Problems
Next Article in Special Issue
Forecasting the S&P 500 Index Using Mathematical-Based Sentiment Analysis and Deep Learning Models: A FinBERT Transformer Model and LSTM
Previous Article in Journal
Effects of the Wiener Process and Beta Derivative on the Exact Solutions of the Kadomtsev–Petviashvili Equation
Previous Article in Special Issue
An Equilibrium Strategy for Target Benefit Pension Plans with a Longevity Trend and Partial Information
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

A Lower Bound for the Volatility Swap in the Lognormal SABR Model

1
Barcelona Graduate School of Economics, Universitat Pompeu Fabra, 08005 Barcelona, Spain
2
Independent Researcher, 2500 The Hague, The Netherlands
3
Graduate School of Economics, The University of Tokyo, Tokyo 113-0033, Japan
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Axioms 2023, 12(8), 749; https://doi.org/10.3390/axioms12080749
Submission received: 28 June 2023 / Revised: 25 July 2023 / Accepted: 27 July 2023 / Published: 29 July 2023
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Mathematical and Computational Finance Analysis)

Abstract

:
In the short time to maturity limit, it is proved that for the conditionally lognormal SABR model the zero vanna implied volatility is a lower bound for the volatility swap strike. The result is valid for all values of the correlation parameter and is a sharper lower bound than the at-the-money implied volatility for correlation less than or equal to zero.

1. Introduction

In their seminal work Carr and Lee [1] prove that for stochastic volatility models, with zero correlation between the spot price and its instantaneous volatility, general volatility derivatives can be priced in a model-free manner. This is a surprising and important result as prior to Carr and Lee’s result it was believed that volatility derivatives other than the log-contract are highly model-dependent. Indeed, precisely because of its model independence one of the first volatility derivatives to be traded in the market was the variance swap, which is equivalent to the log-contract.
When correlation is non-zero prices of general volatility derivatives do become model-dependent. Nevertheless, Carr and Lee proved that the model-dependence is of the order O ( ρ 2 ) . Theoretically, their result paves the way for pricing and replicating all European type volatility derivatives with an error of O ( ρ 2 ) . However, as shown by Friz and Gatheral [2] even in the zero correlation case, pricing volatility options using the Carr and Lee immunisation method leads to highly oscillatory integrals which need regularisation techniques to evaluate. Furthermore, even for the relatively simple but important volatility swap, the Carr-Lee’s pricing method requires a continuum of vanilla options (strikes from 0 to ).
A more recent and straightforward approximation for the volatility swap is given by Rolloos and Arslan [3]. In the aforementioned paper, it is shown that the so-called zero vanna implied volatility (ZVIV) approximates the volatility swap price. In contrast to the Carr-Lee method, the ZVIV approximation does not require a continuum of options, but only one option. It therefore simplifies the approximate pricing of volatility swaps and is not prone to extrapolation error.
The error between the exact volatility swap price and the ZVIV in the short time to maturity limit was made precise by Alòs et al. [4] for a class of models that include in particular the lognormal SABR, by making use of techniques from the Malliavin calculus. In their paper Alòs et al. quantify the error for general stochastic volatility models driven by fractional noise. Recent studies [5,6] have argued for the relevance of fractional noise in explaining the shape of the implied volatility skew.
In Alòs et al. numerical simulations also indicate that, in addition to approximating volatility swaps, the ZVIV is also a lower bound for the volatility swap. In this paper it is proved that for the lognormal SABR model (henceforth SABR model), this is indeed the case for all values of correlation in the short time to maturity limit. To the best of our knowledge this has not been proved yet in the literature on derivatives pricing. A proof for general SV models is a subject of future research.
The structure of the papaer is as follows. In Section 2, the working assumptions are stated and relevant notation introduced. Section 3 treats the zero correlation case. It is proved that both the at-the-money implied volatility (ATMI) and the ZVIV are lower bounds for the volatility swap in the short maturity limit in the SABR model. By making use of the result that the ZVIV is a better approximation than the ATMI, it follows that the ZVIV is a sharper lower bound. The nonzero correlation case is discussed in Section 4, wherein it is proved that in the SABR model the ZVIV is a lower bound for the volatility swap price for any value of correlation. Furthermore, it is shown that for non-positive correlation it is a sharper lower bound than the ATMI in the short time to maturity limit. To illustrate the different behaviours of the ATMI and the ZVIV, numerical results in Section 5 are presented for various values of correlation, volatility of volatility and time to maturity. Section 6 concludes.

2. Assumptions and Notation

We consider the log normal stochastic volatility model for the log-price of a stock under a risk-neutral probability measure P:
X t = X 0 1 2 0 t σ s 2 d s + 0 t σ s ρ d W s + 1 ρ 2 d B s ,
σ t = σ 0 + 0 t α σ s d W s ,
where X 0 is the current log-price, and W and B are independent standard Brownian motions defined on a complete probability space ( Ω , G , P ) . The initial volatility σ 0 and the volatility of volatility α are positive constants. We denote by F W and F B the filtrations generated by W and B and F : = F W F B . We assume the risk-free interest rate r is zero for simplicity. The same arguments of the results in this paper hold for r 0 .
Under this model, the value of the European call option with strike price e k is
V t = E t [ ( e X T e k ) + ] ,
where E t denotes the F t -conditional expectation with respect to P (that is, E t [ Z ] = E [ Z | F t ] ).
Also, we use the following notations:
  • v t = Y t T t , where Y t = t T σ u 2 d u .
    v is the future average volatility and is not an adapted process. E t v t is the fair strike of a volatility swap with the time to maturity time T t .
  • B S ( t , T , x , k , σ ) is the European call option price under the Black-Scholes model with the constant volatility σ , the stock price e x , the time to maturity T t , and the strike e k . In this setting,
    B S ( t , T , x , k , σ ) = e x N ( d 1 ( k , σ ) ) e k N ( d 2 ( k , σ ) ) ,
    where N is the cumulative distribution function of the standard normal distribution, and
    d 1 k , σ : = x k σ T t + σ 2 T t , d 2 k , σ : = x k σ T t σ 2 T t .
    We use the notation B S ( k , σ ) : = B S ( t , T , X t , k , σ ) for simplicity.
  • The inverse function B S 1 ( t , T , x , k , · ) of the Black-Scholes European call option pricing formula with respect to the volatility is defined as
    B S ( t , T , x , k , B S 1 ( t , T , x , k , λ ) ) = λ ,
    for all λ > 0 . We use the notation B S 1 ( k , λ ) : = B S 1 ( t , T , X t , k , λ ) for simplicity.
  • For any fixed t , T , X t , k , we define the implied volatility function I ( t , T , X t , k ) as
    B S ( t , T , X t , k , I ( t , T , X t , k ) ) = V t .
    Then, I ( t , T , X t , k ) = B S 1 ( t , T , X t , k , V t ) .
  • k t * denotes the ATM strike at time t, and I ( t , T , X t , k t * ) is the corresponding ATMI
  • k t ^ is the zero vanna strike at time t and satisfies
    d 2 ( k ^ t , I ( t , T , X t , k ^ t ) ) = 0 .
    I ( t , T , X t , k ^ t ) is called zero vanna implied volatility. The Black-Scholes vanna is proportional to d 2 , and that of plain vanilla options is zero at the zero vanna strike.
D W 1 , 2 denotes the domain of the Malliavin derivative operator D W with respect to W. For n > 1 , the domains of the iterated derivatives D n , W are denoted by D W n , 2 . Also, we define L W n , 2 = L 2 ( 0 , T ; D W n , 2 ) . Notice that the SABR variance σ 2 given by (2) is a process in L W 2 , 2 , and
D r σ u 2 = 2 α σ u 2 1 [ 0 , u ) ( r )
D s D r σ u 2 = 2 D s σ u D r σ u + 2 σ u D s D r σ u = 2 α 2 σ u 2 1 [ 0 , u ) ( r s ) + 2 α 2 σ u 2 1 [ 0 , u ) ( r s ) = 4 α 2 σ u 2 1 [ 0 , u ) ( r s ) .

3. The Uncorrelated Case

3.1. ATM Implied Volatility

Theorem 1. 
Consider the SABR model defined as in (1) and (2). Then, for zero correlation, the ATMI is a lower bound for the volatility swap in the short time to maturity limit.
lim T t I ( t , T , X t , k t * ) lim T t E t [ v t ]
Proof. 
This follows immediately from Theorem 3.2 of Alòs and Shiraya [7],
lim T t I t , T , X t , k t * E t v t ( T t ) 2 = 1 32 σ t lim T t 1 ( T t ) 3 E t t T E r r T D r W σ s 2 d s 2 d r 0 .

3.2. Zero-Vanna Implied Volatility

Theorem 2. 
Consider the SABR model defined as in (1) and (2). Then, for zero correlation, the ZVIV is a lower bound for the volatility swap in the short time to maturity limit.
lim T t I ( t , T , X t , k ^ t ) lim T t E t [ v t ]
Proof. 
In the uncorrelated case, since (B.3) of Alòs, Rolloos and Shiraya,
I t , T , X t , k ^ t = E t v t E t t T B S 1 k ^ t , Λ r ( D A ) r U r d r 1 2 E t t T B S 1 k ^ t , Λ r ( i v ) A r U r 2 d r . = E t v t B S 1 k ^ t , Λ t E t t T ( D A ) r U r d r + 1 2 B S 1 k ^ t , Λ t ( i v ) E t t T A r U r 2 d r + o ( ( T t ) 4 H + 1 ) = E t v t + T 1 + T 2 + o ( ( T t ) 3 )
where
Λ r : = E r B S t , T , X t , k ^ t , v t ,
A r : = 1 2 r T U s 2 d s ,
( D A ) r : = 1 2 r T D r W U s 2 d s , U r : = E r D r W B S ( t , T , X t , k ^ t , v t )
= E r B S σ ( t , T , X t , k ^ t , v t ) 1 2 v t ( T t ) r T D r W σ s 2 d s ,
Here,
B S 1 k ^ t , Λ t = ( 2 π ) 3 2 exp 3 X t + 3 2 ( Θ t ( k ^ t ) ) 2 ( T t ) ( T t ) 1 2 + o ( T t ) 1 2
B S 1 k ^ t , Λ t ( i v ) = 3 ( 2 π ) 2 Θ t ( k ^ t ) exp 4 X t + 2 ( Θ t ( k ^ t ) ) 2 ( T t ) ( T t ) 1 + o ( T t ) 1 .
where Θ r ( k ) : = B S 1 ( k , Λ r ) . Thus, ( B S 1 ) > 0 and ( B S 1 ) ( i v ) < 0 in the short time limit.
On the other hand,
E t t T A r U r 2 d r = 1 2 E t t T r T U s 2 d s U r 2 d r = 1 4 E t t T U r 2 d r 2 = 1 4 E t t T E r B S σ ( t , T , X t , k ^ t , v t ) 1 2 v t ( T t ) r T D r W σ s 2 d r 2 d s 2 > 0
Therefore, T 2 0 .
Next,
U s = E s B S σ ( t , T , X t , k ^ t , v t ) 1 2 v t ( T t ) s T D s W σ u 2 d u = 1 2 E s G ( t , T , X t , k ^ t , v t ) s T D s W σ u 2 d u ,
where G ( t , T , x , k , σ ) : = ( 2 x 2 x ) B S ( t , T , x , k , σ ) , and
D r W U s = E s [ 1 2 G ( t , T , X t , k ^ t , v t ) d 1 ( k ^ t , v t ) d 2 ( k ^ t , v t ) 2 v t 2 ( T t ) 1 2 v t 2 ( T t ) s T D s W σ u 2 d u r T D r W σ u 2 d u + 1 2 G ( t , T , X t , k ^ t , v t ) s T D r W D s W σ u 2 d u ] .
( D A ) r = 1 4 r T E s e k ^ t N ( d 2 ( k ^ t , v t ) ) v t T t s T D s W σ u 2 d u × E s e k ^ t N ( d 2 ( k ^ t , v t ) ) v t T t 1 2 v t 2 ( T t ) s T D s W σ u 2 d u r T D r W σ u 2 d u + r s T D r W D s W σ u 2 d u d s
Thus, we need to check
1 2 v t 2 ( T t ) s T D s W σ u 2 d u r T D r W σ u 2 d u + s T D r W D s W σ u 2 d u 0 ,
Since t T σ u 2 d u r T σ u 2 d u , (19) is
1 2 t T σ u 2 d u s T 2 α σ u 2 d u r T 2 α σ u 2 d u + r s T 4 α 2 σ u 2 d u r s T 2 α 2 σ u 2 d u + r s T 4 α 2 σ u 2 d u 0
Therefore, T 1 0 and the zero-vanna iv is a lower bound for the volatility swap. □

4. The Correlated Case

4.1. ATM Implied Volatility

Theorem 3. 
Consider the SABR model defined as in (1) and (2). Then, for ρ < 0 , the ATMI is a lower bound for the volatility swap strike in the short time to maturity limit.
lim T t I ( t , T , X t , k t * ) lim T t E t [ v t ]
Proof. 
From Theorem 4.2 in [7],
lim T t I ( t , T , X t , k t * ) E t [ v t ] ( T t ) = lim T t 3 ρ 2 8 σ t 3 ( T t ) 4 E t t T s T D s W σ r 2 d r d s 2 lim T t ρ 2 2 σ t 2 ( T t ) 3 E t t T s T D s W σ r r T D r W σ u 2 d u d r d s lim T t ρ 2 2 σ t ( T t ) 3 E t t T s T r T D s W D r W σ u 2 d u d r d s + lim T t ρ 4 ( T t ) 2 E t t T s T D s W σ r 2 d r d s = lim T t 3 ρ 2 8 σ t 3 ( T t ) 4 T 1 lim T t ρ 2 2 σ t 2 ( T t ) 3 T 2 lim T t ρ 2 2 σ t ( T t ) 3 T 3 + lim T t ρ 4 ( T t ) 2 T 4 .
In the log normal stochastic volatility model, since Schwartz’s inequality,
T 1 ( T t ) t T ( T s ) s T E t D s W σ r 2 2 d r d s = ( T t ) t T ( T s ) s T 4 α 2 E t σ 0 4 e 4 α W r 2 α 2 r d r d s = ( T t ) t T ( T s ) s T 4 α 2 σ 0 4 e 6 α 2 r d r d s = 4 α 2 σ 0 4 ( T t ) t T ( T s ) e 6 α 2 T e 6 α 2 s 6 α 2 d s = 4 α 2 σ 0 4 e 6 α 2 T ( T t ) 3 12 α 2 + e 6 α 2 t 36 α 4 ( T t ) 2 ( T t ) t T e 6 α 2 s 36 α 4 d s = 4 α 2 σ 0 4 e 6 α 2 T ( T t ) 3 12 α 2 + e 6 α 2 t 36 α 4 ( T t ) 2 e 6 α 2 T e 6 α 2 t 216 α 6 ( T t )
Here, we assume t = 0 and apply the Taylor expansion,
( 23 ) = 4 α 2 σ 0 4 1 + 6 α 2 T 12 α 2 T 3 + T 2 36 α 4 6 α 2 T + 1 2 36 α 4 T 2 + 1 6 216 α 6 T 3 216 α 6 T + O ( T 5 ) = 4 α 2 σ 0 4 1 2 T 4 1 6 T 4 + O ( T 5 ) = 4 α 2 σ 0 4 3 T 4 + O ( T 5 )
T 2 = t T s T r T E t D s W σ r D r W σ u 2 d u d r d s = t T s T r T 2 α 2 σ 0 3 E t e 2 α ( W u W r ) 2 α 2 ( u r ) E t e 3 α W r 1 2 9 α 2 r e α 2 u + 2 α 2 r d u d r d s = 2 α 2 σ 0 3 t T s T r T e α 2 u + 2 α 2 r d u d r d s = 2 α 2 σ 0 3 t T s T e α 2 T + 2 α 2 r e 3 α 2 r α 2 d r d s = 2 α 2 σ 0 3 t T e 3 α 2 T e α 2 T + 2 α 2 s 2 α 4 e 3 α 2 T e 3 α 2 s 3 α 4 d r d s = 2 α 2 σ 0 3 e 3 α 2 T ( T t ) 2 α 4 e 3 α 2 T e α 2 T + 2 α 2 t 4 α 6 e 3 α 2 T ( T t ) 3 α 4 + e 3 α 2 T e 3 α 2 t 9 α 6
Here, we assume t = 0 and apply the Taylor expansion,
( 25 ) = 2 α 2 σ 0 3 ( ( 1 + 3 α 2 T + 1 2 9 α 4 T 2 ) T 6 α 4 ( 2 α 2 T + 1 2 4 α 4 T 2 + 1 6 8 α 6 T 3 ) ( 1 + α 2 T + 1 2 α 4 T 2 ) 4 α 6 + 3 α 2 T + 1 2 9 α 4 T 2 + 1 6 27 α 6 T 3 9 α 6 ) + O ( T 4 ) = α 2 σ 0 3 3 T 3 + O ( T 4 )
T 3 = t T s T r T E t 4 α 2 σ 0 e 2 α W α 2 u 1 [ 0 , u ) ( r s ) d u d r d s = t T s T r T 4 α 2 σ 0 2 e α 2 u 1 [ 0 , u ) ( r s ) d u d r d s = 4 α 2 σ 0 2 t T s T e α 2 T e α 2 r α 2 d r d s = 4 α 2 σ 0 2 t T e α 2 T ( T s ) α 2 e α 2 T e α 2 s α 4 d s = 4 α 2 σ 0 2 e α 2 T ( T t ) 2 2 α 2 e α 2 T ( T t ) α 4 + e α 2 T e α 2 t α 6
Here, we assume t = 0 and apply the Taylor expansion,
( 27 ) = 4 α 2 σ 0 2 1 + α 2 T 2 α 2 T 2 1 + α 2 T + 1 2 α 4 T 2 α 4 T + α 2 T + 1 2 α 4 T 2 + 1 6 α 6 T 3 α 6 + O ( T 4 ) = 2 α 2 σ 0 2 3 T 3 + O ( T 4 )
T 4 = t T s T E t D s W σ r 2 d r d s = t T s T 2 α E t σ 0 2 e 2 α W r α 2 r d r d s = t T s T 2 α σ 0 2 e α 2 r d r d s = 2 α σ 0 2 t T e α 2 T e α 2 s α 2 d s = 2 α σ 0 2 e α 2 T ( T t ) α 2 e α 2 T e α 2 t α 4
Here, we assume t = 0 and apply the Taylor expansion,
( 29 ) = 2 α σ 0 2 1 + α 2 T α 2 T α 2 T + 1 2 α 4 T 2 α 4 + O ( T 3 ) = α σ 0 2 T 2 1 2 T 2 + O ( T 3 ) = α σ 0 2 2 T 2 + O ( T 3 )
Thus,
lim T 0 I ( 0 , T , X 0 , k 0 * ) E 0 [ v 0 ] T lim T 0 3 ρ 2 8 σ 0 3 T 4 4 α 2 σ 0 4 3 T 4 lim T 0 ρ 2 2 σ 0 2 T 3 α 2 σ 0 3 3 T 3 lim T 0 ρ 2 2 σ 0 T 3 2 α 2 σ 0 2 3 T 3 + lim T 0 ρ 4 T 2 α σ 0 2 2 T 2 + lim T 0 o ( T ) = ρ α σ 0 2 8
Thus, ATMI is a lower bound of the volatility swap if ρ < 0 . □

4.2. Zero-Vanna Implied Volatility

Theorem 4. 
Consider the SABR model defined as in (1) and (2). Then, for all values of correlation ρ, the ZVIV is a lower bound for the volatility swap strike in the short time to maturity limit.
lim T t I ( t , T , X t , k ^ t ) lim T t E t [ v t ]
Proof. 
From Theorem 4 in [4],
lim T t I ( t , T , X t , k ^ t ) E t [ v t ] ( T t ) = lim T t 3 ρ 2 8 σ t 3 ( T t ) 4 E t t T s T D s W σ r 2 d r d s 2 lim T t ρ 2 2 σ t 2 ( T t ) 3 E t t T s T D s W σ r r T D r W σ u 2 d u d r d s lim T t ρ 2 2 σ t ( T t ) 3 E t t T s T r T D s W D r W σ u 2 d u d r d s = lim T t 3 ρ 2 8 σ t 3 ( T t ) 4 T 1 lim T t ρ 2 2 σ t 2 ( T t ) 3 T 2 lim T t ρ 2 2 σ t ( T t ) 3 T 3 .
Since T 1 , T 2 , T 3 are the same as those in the proof of Theorem 3, we obtain
lim T 0 I ( 0 , T , X 0 , k ^ 0 ) E 0 [ v 0 ] T lim T 0 3 ρ 2 8 σ 0 3 T 4 4 α 2 σ 0 4 3 T 4 lim T 0 ρ 2 2 σ 0 2 T 3 α 2 σ 0 3 3 T 3 lim T 0 ρ 2 2 σ 0 T 3 2 α 2 σ 0 2 3 T 3 + lim T 0 o ( T ) = 0 .

5. Numerical Results

In the previous sections it has been proved that in the short time to maturity limit the ZVIV bounds the volatility swap price from below. For longer time to maturities the numerical experiments in this section suggests that the ZVIV remains a lower bound. A proof of this conjecture, however, is currently not known. For the numerical experiments the volatility swap strike, the ZVIV and the ATMI are calculated for various values of volatility of volatility and time to maturity:
α { 0.5 , 1 } , T { 0.5 , 1 } .
The values of correlation are set in 0.1 increments from −1 to 1, and the initial value of the volatility is σ 0 = 0.3 . In order to calculate the volatility swap strike, the ZVIV and ATMI, 10 7 simulations are carried out for each value of ρ , α and T. The results are depicted in Figure 1, Figure 2, Figure 3 and Figure 4.
As can be deduced from the figures, and in line with the results of the previous sections and in [4], the ZVIV is indeed a more accurate approximation for the volatility swap price than the ATMI. Furthermore the impact of correlation on ZVIV is almost of second order. The term ’almost’ is used since the ZVIV approximation is obtained by Taylor approximations in [3]. Thus there are still residual terms of O ( ρ ) that remain in the ZVIV. The impact of these terms is apparent for longer time to maturities, significant nonzero values for correlation, and high volatility of volatility as in Figure 4. We can also clearly see in Figure 4 that for ρ = 0 the ZVIV is not exactly equal to the volatility swap strike. This is another manifestation of the fact that there are small residual terms of O ( ρ ) present in the ZVIV.

6. Conclusions

It has been shown that in the conditionally lognormal SABR model, the ZVIV is a lower bound for the volatility swap strike for all values of correlation in the short time to maturity limit. This property, in addition to the results in [4], further cements the ZVIV as a more accurate model-free approximation for the volatility swap strike than the ATMI.
The results in this paper is a first step in analyzing the question for which models the ZVIV is a lower bound for the volatility swap strike. Further research into the ZVIV as a lower bound for the volatility swap strike will have to includes analyses along the dimensions of the Hurst parameter, correlation parameter and time to maturity.

Author Contributions

All authors have contributed equally. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

Elisa Alòs is supported by grant PID2020-118339GBI00 (Ministerio de Ciencia e Innovación). Kenichiro Shiraya is supported by the Center for Advanced Research in Finance (CARF).

Data Availability Statement

Not applicable.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Carr, P.; Lee, R. Robust replication of volatility derivatives. PRMIA award for Best Paper in Derivatives. In Proceedings of the MFA 2008 Annual Meeting, New York, NY, USA, 21 May 2008. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  2. Friz, P.; Gatheral, J. Valuation of volatility derivatives as an inverse problem. Quant. Financ. 2005, 5, 531–542. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Rolloos, F.; Arslan, M. Taylor-made volatility swaps. Wilmott 2017, 2017, 56–61. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Alòs, E.; Rolloos, F.; Shiraya, K. On the difference between the volatility swap strike and the zero vanna implied volatility. Siam J. Financ. Math. 2021, 12, 690–723. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Comte, F.; Renault, E. Long memory in continuous-time stochastic volatility models. Math. Financ. 1998, 8, 291–323. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Gatheral, J.; Jaisson, T.; Rosenbaum, M. Volatility is rough. Quant. Financ. 1998, 18, 933–949. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Alòs, E.; Shiraya, K. Estimating the Hurst parameter from short term volatility swaps: A Malliavin calculus approach. Financ. Stoch. 2019, 23, 423–447. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
Figure 1. σ 0 = 0.3 , α = 0.5 , T = 0.5 .
Figure 1. σ 0 = 0.3 , α = 0.5 , T = 0.5 .
Axioms 12 00749 g001
Figure 2. σ 0 = 0.3 , α = 0.5 , T = 1 .
Figure 2. σ 0 = 0.3 , α = 0.5 , T = 1 .
Axioms 12 00749 g002
Figure 3. σ 0 = 0.3 , α = 1 , T = 0.5 .
Figure 3. σ 0 = 0.3 , α = 1 , T = 0.5 .
Axioms 12 00749 g003
Figure 4. σ 0 = 0.3 , α = 1 , T = 1 .
Figure 4. σ 0 = 0.3 , α = 1 , T = 1 .
Axioms 12 00749 g004
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Alòs, E.; Rolloos, F.; Shiraya, K. A Lower Bound for the Volatility Swap in the Lognormal SABR Model. Axioms 2023, 12, 749. https://doi.org/10.3390/axioms12080749

AMA Style

Alòs E, Rolloos F, Shiraya K. A Lower Bound for the Volatility Swap in the Lognormal SABR Model. Axioms. 2023; 12(8):749. https://doi.org/10.3390/axioms12080749

Chicago/Turabian Style

Alòs, Elisa, Frido Rolloos, and Kenichiro Shiraya. 2023. "A Lower Bound for the Volatility Swap in the Lognormal SABR Model" Axioms 12, no. 8: 749. https://doi.org/10.3390/axioms12080749

APA Style

Alòs, E., Rolloos, F., & Shiraya, K. (2023). A Lower Bound for the Volatility Swap in the Lognormal SABR Model. Axioms, 12(8), 749. https://doi.org/10.3390/axioms12080749

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop