Next Article in Journal
A Tapestry of Ideas with Ramanujan’s Formula Woven In
Next Article in Special Issue
Characterization Results of Extremization Models with Interval Values
Previous Article in Journal
Constructive Conditions for a High-Dimensional Hilbert-Type Integral Inequality Involving Multivariate Variable Upper Limit Integral Functions and Optimal Constant Factors
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Multifunctional Expectile Regression Estimation in Volterra Time Series: Application to Financial Risk Management

by
Somayah Hussain Alkhaldi
1,
Fatimah Alshahrani
2,
Mohammed Kbiri Alaoui
1,
Ali Laksaci
1 and
Mustapha Rachdi
3,*
1
Department of Mathematics, College of Science, King Khalid University, Abha 62529, Saudi Arabia
2
Department of Mathematical Sciences, College of Science, Princess Nourah bint Abdulrahman University, P.O. Box 84428, Riyadh 11671, Saudi Arabia
3
Laboratoire AGEIS, Université Grenoble Alpes, UFR SHS, BP. 47, CEDEX 09, F-38040 Grenoble, France
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Axioms 2025, 14(2), 147; https://doi.org/10.3390/axioms14020147
Submission received: 24 January 2025 / Revised: 16 February 2025 / Accepted: 17 February 2025 / Published: 19 February 2025
(This article belongs to the Special Issue New Perspectives in Operator Theory and Functional Analysis)

Abstract

:
We aim to analyze the dynamics of multiple financial assets with variable volatility. Instead of a standard analysis based on the Black–Scholes model, we proceed with the multidimensional Volterra model, which allows us to treat volatility as a stochastic process. Taking advantage of the long memory function of this type of model, we analyze the reproduced movements using recent algorithms in the field of functional data analysis (FDA). In fact, we develop, in particular, new risk tools based on the asymmetric least squares loss function. We build an estimator using the multifunctional kernel (MK) method and then establish its asymptotic properties. The multidimensionality of the Volterra process is explored through the dispersion component of the convergence rate, while the nonparametric path of the risk tool affects the bias component. An empirical analysis is conducted to demonstrate the ease of implementation of our proposed approach. Additionally, an application on real data is presented to compare the effectiveness of expectile-based measures with Value at Risk (VaR) in financial risk management for multiple assets.

1. Introduction

Non-Markov models and integral equations have been widely used in financial mathematics to model memory effects and path-dependent dynamics (see [1] for previous studies or [2] for recent advances and results). This property makes them suitable for the description of rough volatility, volatility clustering, and heavy tails.
The main objective of this contribution is to assess financial risk using historical information as a multidimensional continuous process. It should be noted that the popularity of this topic is motivated by many considerations. However, the nonlinearity and long memory properties of the Volterra model are the main motivations for the membership of this model in the analysis of financial time series. The first substantial results on this topic were developed in [3]. The authors of [3] extended stochastic volatility models with long memory kernels for financial applications. In [4], Volterra-type equations were applied to analyze volatility surfaces. The rough Heston model that was studied in [5] improves derivative pricing by using Volterra equations to capture the effect of the rough volatility. Furthermore, in [6], the importance of non-Markov process models in financial markets was discussed. This work allows for the extension of the classical framework towards precise calibration of derivative pricing, volatility surface calibration, and risk management. Thus, assessing financial risk using historical information is a challenge for bankers and investors. From a statistical point of view, two models are used in this field. More precisely, the common models are vector autoregression (VaR) and expected shortfall (ES). However, it is well known that these two models are not relevant in some situations (see [7,8] for further discussion). In particular, the inconsistency and inelicitability of these standard models are intrinsic drawbacks.
Alternatively, in this contribution, we examine financial risk using the expectile function. The literature on the expectile model, in mathematical statistics, is still limited compared to that on VaR or ES. In fact, the financial risk was studied using parametric methods in [9]. Indeed, the authors of [9] analyzed the asymptotic behavior of multivariate expectiles of the Fréchet model. Moreover, they proposed extreme multivariate expectile estimators in the cases of asymptotic independence and co-monotonicity. It was also shown in [10] that the expectile is a robust alternative to VaR and ES, as it efficiently incorporates auxiliary information into risk estimation. The dynamic expectile, which is based on the expectile regression, has been considered in many applied fields such as econometrics, finance and, actuarial science (see, for example, [11] as a pioneering work or [12] for recent advances and references).
However, from a theoretical point of view, conditional expectiles are treated in the same way as classical regression. For example, in [13] conditional expectations were generalized to conditional expectiles by minimizing an asymmetric quadratic loss function, and the function’s main properties were given. In [14] estimators of regression quantiles were defined via an asymmetric absolute loss, and the same authors, in [15], introduced a new approach to regression quantiles that is based on estimating the coefficients of regression equations. Furthermore, in [16], the authors used expectiles to propose methods to estimate VaR and ES (or conditional VaR (CVaR)). Additional details and results on regression can be found in references such as [17,18,19,20]. Furthermore, in [20] the authors extended the expectile-based risk measures to multivariate parameters by presenting different approaches to construct such measures, and they discussed the consistency properties of multivariate expectiles. The same authors, in [20], studied the asymptotic behavior of multivariate expectiles for the Fréchet model, and they proposed estimators for extreme multivariate expectiles under the assumptions of asymptotic independence and co-monotonicity.
It must be said that although this work focuses on the finite-dimensional case, this study can be extended to the framework of the analysis of the effect of a functional covariate on a scalar response variable. Recall that the first results on this subject were presented in [21]. In this paper, the almost complete convergence and the asymptotic normality of the estimator that was obtained by the kernel method (KM) when the data are independent was proven. These results were then generalized to the case of dependent data by the same authors (see [22]). In addition, in [23], an alternative estimation method was proposed, where the dynamic expectile was estimated using a functional local linear approach. These authors also proved the Borel–Cantelli convergence of the functional estimator that was constructed. Functional data analysis (FDA), as highlighted in this last article, is essential for many application areas. For fundamental tools in this field, one can refer, for example, to the monographs in [24,25,26].
As explained above, the novelty of this contribution lies in the assessment of financial risk using a chaotic Gaussian Volterra model. This study thus offers several main advantages. First, by exploiting expectile regression, we provide an efficient risk model that combines the advantages of VaR and ES. A key advantage of this approach is its sensitivity to extreme values, allowing for more prudent and reactive risk management. Second, financial data are modeled as continuous Gaussian Volterra processes, which are particularly well suited for financial time series. These processes are powerful tools to capture memory effects and path-dependent dynamics in financial markets (see [4]). Specifically, the process kernel introduces nonlocal interactions and long-term dependence, making it very effective for describing stylized features of financial time series, such as approximate volatility, clustering, and heavy tails. The Volterra model also improves applications in derivatives pricing, volatility surface calibration, and risk management. Moreover, in nonparametric estimation, the Volterra model provides a flexible framework to reconstruct financial dynamics without imposing strict parametric assumptions.
All these features are explored and evaluated using simulated and real data examples. Of course, the practical use of this model requires a solid mathematical basis that allows one to justify its adoption. To this end, we have established almost complete consistency of the constructed estimator and specified its convergence rate, as well as the conditions necessary for ideal implementation.
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 sets out the general framework of this contribution. The results obtained are presented and discussed in Section 3. Section 4 is devoted to the empirical analysis, covering applications on both simulated and real data. In Section 5, we provide a general conclusion and outline some research perspectives for further investigations in this area. Finally, proofs of the auxiliary results are provided in the Section 6.

2. Functional Framework: Data, Model, and Its Estimator

2.1. Functional Data

We assume that the returns of d financial assets, R ( t ) , behave as a Gaussian Volterra process defined by
R ( t ) = R 1 ( t ) R 2 ( t ) R d ( t )
where
R i ( t ) = 0 t L ( t , s ) d B i ( s ) , t [ 0 , 1 ]
for i = 1 , , d with L denoting a kernel function and B denoting Brownian motion.
Such a consideration is standard in mathematical finance. It is motivated by the presence of a long memory in the financial dynamics of the stock market (see [27]). In our functional context, we consider the Cameron–Martin space associated with R ( t ) , which is defined as
H = h : f u n c t i o n   s u c h   t h a t , t h e r e   e x i s t s   h 1 L 2 [ 0 , 1 ] , I R d f o r   w h i c h h ( t ) = 0 t L ( t , s ) h 1 ( s ) d s f o r   t [ 0 , 1 ] .
The space H is endowed with the scalar product h , g = h , g L 2 [ 0 , 1 ] , R d and an orthonormal basis ( e n ) n N defined by
e n ( t ) = 0 t L ( t , s ) h n ( s ) d s for t ( 0 , 1 ) where ( h n ) i s   a n   o r t h o n o r m a l   b a s i s   i n   L 2 [ 0 , 1 ] , I R d .
We aim to analyze the eventual risk in the financial asset movement using historical information. The novelty here is to take into account the historical information in its continuous form. To perform this, we construct N input functional random variables ( I k ) k = 1 , , N such that, for all t [ 0 , 1 ] ,
I k i ( t ) = R i ( k 1 ) + t N for i = 1 , d .
The eventual risk is evaluated by forecasting certain future characteristics of these returns, such as the minimum or maximum values, the variation over a fixed period, and the predicted values at a fixed time t 0 , among others. From a mathematical point of view, we model these future characteristics through the function fu . In this sense, we consider output variables ( O k ) k = 1 , , N defined by
O k = fu ( I k i ) for k = 1 , , N and i = 1 , , d .
Finally, we wish to analyze the financial risk using Z k = ( I k , O k ) k = 1 , , N , which is a functional random variable sampled from the Volterra process according to (1) and (2). Such a sample satisfies a covariance inequality if the Volterra process has a kernel L ( . , . ) satisfying the hypothesis (Assumption 1) below.
Lemma 1.
Consider a Volterra process that has a kernel L ( · , · ) such that
Assumption 1.
The kernel L ( · , · ) is a Hölder continuous function where
( i ) The function t L ( t , s ) is differentiable with respect to t , and its derivative is L 2 - integrable , such that sup 0 s < t 1 L ( t , s ) t ( t s ) 3 / 2 < . ( i i ) The function t 0 t L ( t , s ) d s is of bounded variation .
Then, for all functions F and G that are bounded and Lipschitz-continuous, we have
C o v ( F ( Z k , k K 1 ) , G ( Z k , k K 2 ) ) # K 1 # K 2 L i p ( F ) L i p ( G ) η ξ
where # A denotes the cardinality of A , ξ = d i s t ( K 1 , K 2 ) = min k K 1 , k K 2 | k k | , and
η r = sup k K 1 k K 2 , | k k | r l = 1 l = 1 i = 1 d j = 1 d | C o v ( I k , l i , I k , l j ) |
+ | C o v ( O k , I k , l ) | + | C o v ( I k , l i , O k ) | + | C o v ( O k , O k ) | ,
where I k , l 1 = < I k 1 , e l 1 > .

2.2. Functional Model and Its Estimator

As an alternative to standard financial risk models (VaR or ES), we are interested in the dynamic expectile model. The latter is the solution to the following asymmetric least squares optimization problem:
X P p ( θ ) = arg min y R E p ( O y ) 2 1 I { ( O y ) > 0 } I = θ + E ( 1 p ) ( O y ) 2 1 I { ( O y ) 0 } I = θ
for p ( 0 , 1 ) and θ = θ 1 θ 2 θ d H , where 1 I A denotes the indicator function on set A.
By differentiating, we prove that X P p ( θ ) may be expressed as the ratio of the loss and the gain functions. In fact, the risk model X P p ( θ ) is the root of
E 1 ( y , θ ) E 2 ( y , θ ) p 1 p = 0 ,
where
E 1 ( y , θ ) = E ( O y ) 1 I { ( O y ) 0 } I = θ is the loss function E 2 ( y , θ ) = E ( O y ) 1 I { ( O y ) > 0 } I = θ is the gain function .
Now, the  quantity X P p ( θ ) is estimated by X P p ^ ( θ ) , which is the zero of the following equation:
E 1 ^ ( y , θ ) E 2 ^ ( y , θ ) p 1 p = 0
with
E 1 ^ ( y , θ ) = k = 1 N i = 1 d H ( a 1 θ i I k i ) ( O k y ) 1 I { ( O k y ) 0 } k = 1 N i = 1 d H ( a 1 θ i I k i ) , E 2 ^ ( y , θ ) = k = 1 N i = 1 d H ( a 1 θ i I k i ) ( O k y ) 1 I { ( O k y ) > 0 } k = 1 N i = 1 d H ( a 1 θ i I k i ) . ,
where H is a known measurable function, a : = ( a n ) is a sequence of positive real numbers, and  · denotes the L 2 ( 0 , 1 ) -norm.
Notice that the implementation of this estimator in practice requires some mathematical support to specify its convergence rate. The following section will give that.

2.3. The Mathematical Support

Let θ H . We denote by N θ a neighborhood of θ , and by C 1 , C 2 , C 3 , some strictly positive constants. Moreover, we set
E ( y , θ ) = E 1 ( y , θ ) E 2 ( y , θ ) and , we denote B ( θ , a ) = θ H : θ θ ) < a .
We consider the following assumptions:
Assumption 2.
The functions E 1 ( · , θ ) and E 2 ( · , θ ) are differentiable on R and satisfy that there exists h > 0 such that for all y X P p ( θ ) h , X P p ( θ ) + h , and all θ 1 , θ 2 F ,
| E 2 ( y , θ 1 ) E 2 ( y , θ 2 ) | C 1 i = 1 d θ 1 i θ 2 i b 1 , with E ( X P p ( θ ) , θ ) y > 0
and
| E 1 ( y , θ 1 ) E 1 ( y , θ 2 ) | C 2 i = 1 d θ 1 i θ 2 i b 2 , for b i > 0 , i { 1 , 2 } .
Assumption 3.
For all q 2 , the output variable O satifies
I E | O | q < C a n d i j I E | O i ± O j ± | I i , I j C < .
with O i = O i y 1 I O i y 0 and O i + = O i y 1 I O i y 0 .
Assumption 4.
For all a > 0 , and  λ > q / 2 b 2 , we suppose that I P I B ( θ , a ) : = ϕ ( d , θ , a ) > 0 , and for all i j ,
sup i j I P ( I j , I i ) B ( θ , a ) × B ( θ , a ) = O ϕ 1 + λ λ + 1 ( d , θ , a ) and η ξ = e λ ξ .
Assumption 5.
There exist ξ ( 0 , 1 )  and  ξ 1 , ξ 2 > 0 ,   s u c h   t h a t
log N 5 N 1 ξ ξ 1 ϕ ( d , θ , a ) 1 log N 1 + ξ 2 .
Assumption 6.
The function H ( · ) has a support within [ 0 , 1 ] and satisfies
0 < C 4 H ( · ) C 5 < for C 4 , C 5 > 0

2.4. Some Comments

Recall that all the assumed conditions are not very restrictive. The convergence rate of the estimator is stated under some standard assumptions for nonlinear functional time series. In particular, the assumption (Assumption 1) is necessary to explore the nonparametric path of the model X P p , while the condition (Assumption 2) is the standard integrability condition related to the endogenous variable O. On the other hand, the assumption (Assumption 3) concerns the Gaussian–Volterra model, and it is used to identify the orthonormal basis function on the Cameron–Martin space associated with the underlying process. The functional aspect of the input variable I is controlled by the condition (Assumption 4), which relates the Gaussian measure to the Hilbert structure of the variable as well as to its local dependence. The rest of the assumptions are technical assumptions that cover the kernel function and the bandwidth sequence, which has a pivotal role in the computational capacity of the kernel estimator X P p ^ ( θ ) . They are also used to specify its convergence rate (see [25] for the definition of convergence rate).

3. The Main Results

We present the asymptotic properties of the estimator X P p ^ ( θ ) under the above assumptions.
Theorem 1.
Under (Assumption 1)–(Assumption 6), we have that there exists ϵ 0 > 0 such that
N 1 P X P p ^ ( θ ) X P p ( θ ) > ϵ 0 a k 0 + log N N 1 ξ ϕ ( d , θ , a ) <
with k 0 = min ( b 1 , b 2 ) .
Proof of Theorem 1.
Observe that the function E ( y , θ ) is increasing. Therefore,
n 1 I P | X P p ^ ( θ ) X P p ( θ ) | > ϵ n 1 I P E ^ ( X P p ( θ ) ϵ , θ ) E ( X P p ( θ ) ϵ , θ ) | E ( X P p ( θ ) , θ ) E ( X P p ( θ ) ϵ , θ ) | + n 1 I P E ^ ( X P p ( θ ) + ϵ , θ ) E ( X P p ( θ ) + ϵ , θ ) | E ( X P p ( ( θ ) , θ ) E ( X P p ( θ ) + ϵ , θ ) | .
Since the function E ( · . θ ) is continuously differentiable and satisfies E ( X P p ( θ ) , θ ) y > 0 , there exists δ > 0 such that
inf y [ X P p ( θ ) δ , X P p ( θ ) + δ ] E ( X P p ( θ ) , θ ) y C > 0 for some constant C > 0 .
Thus,
n 1 I P | X P p ^ ( θ ) X P p ( θ ) | > ϵ N I P sup y [ X P p ( θ ) δ , X P p ( θ ) + δ ] | E ^ ( y , θ ) E ( y , θ ) | C ϵ .
Therefore, in order to complete the proof of Theorem 1 it suffices to state that
N I P sup y [ X P p ( θ ) δ , X P p ( θ ) + δ ] | E ^ ( y , θ ) E ( y , θ ) | C ϵ 0 a k 0 + log n N 1 ξ ϕ ( d , θ , a ) < .
Notice that the last statement is based on the following decomposition:
E ^ ( y , θ ) E ( y , θ ) = E ˜ 1 ( y , θ ) E ˜ 2 ( y , θ ) E 1 ( y , θ ) E 2 ( y , θ ) = 1 E ˜ 2 ( y , θ ) E ˜ 1 ( y , θ ) E 1 ( y , θ ) + E ( y , θ ) E ˜ 2 ( y , θ ) E 2 ( y , θ ) E ˜ 2 ( y , θ ) ,
where
E ˜ 1 ( y , θ ) = 1 N I E [ i = 1 d H ( a 1 θ i I i ) ] k = 1 N i = 1 d H ( a 1 θ i I k i ) ( O k y ) 1 I ( O k y ) 0 ,
and
E ˜ 2 ( y , θ ) = 1 N I E [ i = 1 d H ( a 1 θ i I i ) ] k = 1 N i = 1 d H ( a 1 θ i I k i ) ( O k y ) 1 I ( O k y ) > 0 .
Consequently, the proof of Theorem 1 is based on the following intermediate results.    □
Lemma 2.
Under Assumptions (Assumption 1) and (Assumption 3)(Assumption 6), we have
sup y [ X P p ( θ ) δ , X P p ( θ ) + δ ] E ˜ 1 ( y , θ ) I E E ˜ 1 ( y , θ ) = O a . c o . log N N 1 ξ ϕ ( d , θ , a ) ,
and
sup y [ X P p ( θ ) δ , X P p ( θ ) + δ ] E ˜ 2 ( y , θ ) I E E ˜ 2 ( y , θ ) = O a . c o . log N N 1 ξ ϕ ( d , θ , a ) .
Lemma 3.
Assume that hypotheses  (Assumption 2),  (Assumption 4), and  (Assumption 6)   are fulfilled. Then,
E E ˜ 1 ( y , θ ) E 1 ( y , θ ) = O ( a b 1 ) ,
and
E E ˜ 2 ( y , θ ) E 2 ( y , θ ) = O a b 2 .

4. Financial Time Series Analysis

4.1. Simulation Study

The main objective of this part is to examine the easy application of the estimator X P p ^ ( θ ) using simulated data. Recall that the use of X P p ^ ( θ ) is related to the easy choice of its parameters. In this context of kernel smoothing, the choice of the bandwidth parameter is a crucial issue. From a theoretical point of view, there are three common rules in nonparametric functional data analysis to answer this question. Examples include the symmetric least squares cross-validation rule in [28], the bootstrap approach in [29], and the Bayesian approach in [30]. In this simulation part, we introduce a new algorithm based on the asymmetric least squares loss function. Thus, we conduct a simulation study to examine the applicability of our procedure. In fact, the new rule is based on the following criterion:
A L S ( p ) = 1 N k = 1 N ρ p O k , X P p ( I k ) ,
where ρ p ( t ) = t 2 p 1 I t 0 is the scoring function of the expectile and H n is a given subset of positive real numbers.
We consider the functional input variables using the sampling rule (1). The sampling rule is constructed using the Volterra process. We generate the Volterra process using the routine code st.int from the R-package Sim.DiffProc. In order to cover different cases, we simulate the following two different kernels:
Shifted   fractional   Kernel   ( SK )   K 1 ( t ) = ( t + 0.5 ) ( 1 / 4 )
and
Exponential   Kernel   ( EK )   K 2 ( t ) = 2 4 exp ( t / 2 )
It is clear that the choice of the kernel has a significant impact on the covariance of the observations. Thus, a different choice of kernels allows one to cover many degrees of dependence. The shape of the different curves is illustrated in Figure 1.
Next, we consider the output variable O k = max t I k ( t ) . Furthermore, we check the behavior of X P p ^ ( θ ) using the quadratic kernel H ( · ) on ( 0 , 1 ) and the PCA metric associated with the third eigenvalue. For the selection of smoothing parameters, we optimize the rule (12) via two approaches:
  • The local k-Nearest Neighbors approach for which
    H = a 0 : i = 1 n 1 I B ( θ , a ) ( I i ) = k ,
    where k { 5 , 15 , 25 , , 0.5 n } .
  • The global approach for which the subset H is the quantile of the vector distances between the observations ( I k ) and the localization point θ . The order of the quantiles is { 0.05 , 0.1 , 0.15 , 0.20 , , 0.5 n } .
Finally, the performance of the financial risk model X P p ^ ( θ ) is verified using the backtesting criterion A L S ( p ) . Furthermore, the comparison results are summarized in Table 1, where we report the values of A L S ( p ) for different sample sizes, N = 50 , 150 , 250 ; different Volterra kernels; and for three values of p = 0.1 , 0.05 , 0.01 .
The obtained results confirm the good behavior of the X P p ^ ( θ ) estimator. It appears that the A L S ( p ) rule is well adapted to compute the X P p ^ ( θ ) estimator. Note that the behavior of the X P p ^ ( θ ) estimator is affected by the nature of the correlation of the functional data through the L ( · , · ) kernel. In particular, it is well documented that the shifted fractional kernel generates a non-Markovian semi-martingale process and that the Volterra exponential kernel process satisfies the Markovian property. Finally, we can see that the empirical results integrate the theoretical results of the X P p ^ ( θ ) estimator. More precisely, the performance of X P p ^ ( θ ) is improved as a function of the sample size N and the degree of dependence.

4.2. Real Data Application

One of the most challenging questions in financial risk management is how to find appropriate decision rules to trade off the return and loss of a financial asset. According to the definition of expectile regression as the ratio of loss and gain, it seems to be the right candidate to answer this question.
Note that the main feature of our approach is to analyze financial time series data using the nonparametric method that was recently considered in big data analysis. In particular, functional expectiles allow us to integrate the functional aspect of financial time series. The novelty here is to consider multifunctional data that allow us to adjust the risk of several assets. For this aim, we assume that d = 3 and we set R ( t ) as the daily rate (according to USD) of three major currencies, namely the euro, the pound sterling (gbp) and the Swiss franc (chf). The data are available at https://stooq.com/db/h/ (accessed on 8 December 2024).
We consider the data of the week (18–22 November 2024) with a time step of 5 min. The data for the three situations are presented in the following, Figure 2.
Often, investors are interested in the log-return, defined by
Z ( t ) : = 100 log r ( t ) log r ( t 1 ) ,
and they want to predict the extreme return at a time T giving the process Z ( t ) for t [ 0 , T [ .
It clearly seems that the Z ( T ) is centered and has great volatility-transformed series. Before processing this financial chronological series as functional data, we start by reproducing the Volterra process associated with Z ( t ) and we generate the functional sample using the sampling approach discussed in Section 2.2. We cut Z ( t ) in N = 118 curves, with each representing one hour.
We aimed to predict the maximum variations in O between the three currencies and we will compare the efficiency of the approach presented and the standard risk measures when V a R ( θ ) is estimated empirically.
In order to obtain a fair comparison between the two risk measures, we carry out our empirical analysis using the same criteria for selecting the fundamental parameters. In particular, for the functional expectile regression, we consider the quadratic kernel on [ 0.1 ] and the PCA metric based on the principal component analysis reduction method (see [28]), and we choose the best smoothing parameter a via the local k-Nearest Neighborhood approach. To examine the effectiveness of the two approaches, we split the observations into two parts: (i) a training sample (90 observations) and (ii) a test sample (28 observations). Then, we repeated this treatment 60 times.
These calculations allow us to present, in Figure 3, the percentage of the values exceeded for the two models, X P p ^ ( θ ) and V a R ( θ ) , each time. The latter quantifies violation cases when the process Z ( t ) exceeds X P p ^ ( θ ) and V a R ( θ ) .
It appears clearly that X P p ^ ( θ ) performs better at detecting the financial risk than its competitor model, V a R ( θ ) . This statement is confirmed by the frequency of exceeding, which is very close to the threshold, p. In other words, this is the percentage when z ( t ) > θ ^ ( t ) where θ ^ ( t ) means either X P p ^ ( θ ) or V a R ( θ ) . As expected, this superiority is justified by the fact that X P p ^ ( θ ) is constructed from the error of asymmetrically weighted least squares. This increases its sensitivity to outliers and simultaneously controls the gain and loss. This model then detects the violation when it occurs. Moreover, even though the alternative model V a R ( θ ) also performs well, its insensitivity to outliers reduces its interactivity with short-term risk.

5. Conclusions

Motivated by the need to develop an algorithm to instantly manage financial risk, we have proposed, in this contribution, new statistical algorithms adapted to high-frequency data, which are observed on a finer discretization grid (every 1 min). This new method constitutes an alternative approach to classical models based on the multivariate GARCH model. The proposed approaches are more informative than the classical model. Indeed, on the one hand, the multivariate GARCH model requires certain specific assumptions related to the distribution of the data that are generally not satisfied. On the other hand, the multivariate GARCH model does not allow to explore one the maximum amount of information in high-frequency data; it is, in reality, only usable for low frequencies. But with recent technological developments, the digitalization of financial risk management becomes inevitable and standard models must be modernized. An empirical analysis confirmed that the multifunctional expectile model is more efficient than empirical VaR. Besides its consistency and elicitability properties, the multifunctional expectile model is highly sensitive to outliers, which allows it to adapt to the volatility of the underlying financial data.
The theoretical part of the paper provides good mathematical support for the use of this expectile model as a financial risk. The asymptotic results obtained in this part are obtained under standard conditions of functional data analysis. They cover the main elements of nonparametric functional statistics, including data, model, and estimation techniques. As in the vector case, the curse of dimensionality related to the regressors’ components has a negative impact on the model accuracy. Thus, reducing this negative effect is a natural perspective of this contribution. In this context, combining our approach with the single index model or the partial linear model seems important to reduce this limitation.
Moreover, the present contribution opens other important avenues for the future. For example, it will be very important, in the future, to compare parametric estimation with the techniques of the nonparametric functional regime. Note that one of the important characteristics of expectile regression is that it can be estimated using the same ideas as quantile regression. It would also be interesting to extend this study to other financial time series, namely the spatial case or the multifunctional ergodic case.
Introducing another estimation approach to take into account missing observations or cases of incomplete data is also an interesting avenue for the future. Building an alternative estimator of quantile regression and mathematical expectation using the parametric or nonparametric estimator of the expectile model is also a good topic to explore. Of course, this list is not exhaustive and there are many other topics that can be developed.

6. Proofs of the Main Results

Proof of Lemma 1.
It is shown in [31] that under (Assumption 3), the Gaussian Volterra process, R ( t ) , satisfies, for all i = 1 , d , that
R i ( t ) = lim n k = 1 N e k i ( t ) 0 1 R i ( s ) e k i ( s ) d s , a l m o s t   s u r e l y ,
where 0 1 R i ( s ) e k i ( s ) d s is a Gaussian real random variable. Thus, the functional variables ( I k ( t ) ) k can be written as a Gaussian process, i.e., for all i = 1 , d ,
I k i ( t ) = l = 1 < I k i , e l i > e l i ( t ) .
Let
I k , l = I k , l 1 I k , l 2 I k , l d = < I k 1 , e l 1 > < I k 2 , e l 2 > < I k d , e l d >
According to [32], for any bounded Lipschitz-continuous functions F and G,
C o v F ( I k , l , k K 1 ) , G ( I k , l , k K 2 ) # K 1 # K 2 L i p ( F ) L i p ( G ) sup k K 1 k K 2 , | k k | r i = 1 d j = 1 d C o v ( I k , l i , I k , l j ) .
It follows that
C o v F ( I k , k K 1 ) , G ( I k , k K 2 ) # K 1 # K 2 L i p ( F ) L i p ( G ) sup k K 1 k K 2 , | k k | r l = 1 l = 1 i = 1 d j = 1 d C o v ( I k , l i , I k , l j ) .
Finally,
C o v F ( Z k , k K 1 ) , G ( Z k , k K 2 ) # K 1 # K 2 L i p ( F ) L i p ( G ) sup k K 1 k K 2 , | k k | ξ l = 1 l = 1 i = 1 d j = 1 d | C o v ( I k , l i , I k , l j ) | + | C o v ( O k , I k , l ) | + | C o v ( I k , l i , O k ) | + | C o v ( O k , O k ) | .
Proof of Lemma 2.
By the compactness property, we write
[ X P p ( θ ) δ , X P p ( θ ) + δ ] j = 1 d N t j l N , t j + l N ,
with l N = N 1 / 2 b 1 and d N = O N 1 / 2 b 1 .
Observe that
I E E ˜ 1 ( t j l N , θ ) sup y ( t j l N , t j + l N ) I E E ˜ 1 ( y , θ ) I E E ˜ 1 ( t j + l N , θ ) E ˜ 1 ( t j l N , θ ) sup y ( t j l N , t j + l N ) E ˜ 1 ( y , θ ) E ˜ 1 ( t j + l N , θ ) .
This implies that
sup y [ X P p ( θ ) δ , X P p ( θ ) + δ ] E ˜ 1 ( y , θ ) I E E ˜ 1 ( y , θ ) max 1 j d N max z { t j l N , t j + l N } E ˜ 1 ( z , θ ) I E E ˜ 1 ( z , θ ) + 2 b 1 C 2 l N b 1 .
(Assumption 5) gives
l N b 1 = o log N N ϕ ( d , θ , a ) 1 / 2 .
Thus, it suffices to evaluate
2 d N max 1 j d N max z { t j l N , t j + l N } I P E ˜ 1 ( z , θ ) I E E ˜ 1 ( z , θ ) > ϵ 0 log N N 1 ξ ϕ ( d , θ , a ) .
Indeed, define γ N = N λ / p , O i * = O i 1 I | O | < γ N ) and
E ˜ 1 * ( z , θ ) = 1 N I E [ i = 1 d H ( a 1 θ i I i ) ] k = 1 N i = 1 d H ( a 1 θ i I k i ) O i * .
So, we have to prove
d N max z G N E ˜ 1 ( z , θ ) E ˜ 1 * ( z , θ ) = O a . c o . log N N 1 ξ ϕ ( d , θ , a ) ,
d N max z G N I E [ E ˜ 1 * ( z , θ ) ] I E [ E ˜ 1 ( z , θ ) = O log N N 1 ξ ϕ ( d , θ , a ) ,
and
d N max z G N E ˜ 1 * ( z , θ ) ( θ , z ) I E [ E ˜ 1 * ( z , θ ) ] = O a . c o . log N N 1 ξ ϕ ( d , θ , a ) .
In order to obtain (13), we use Markov’s inequality. Thus, for all z G N and for all ϵ > 0 , we obtain
I P E ˜ 1 * ( z , θ ) E ˜ 1 ( z , θ ) > ϵ i = 1 N I P | O i | > N λ / p N 1 λ I E O q .
Since λ > 2 + 1 / 2 b 2 , we have
d N max z G N I P E ˜ 1 * ( z , θ ) E ˜ 1 ( z , θ ) > ϵ 0 log N N 1 ξ ϕ ( d , θ , a ) N 1 + 1 / 2 b 2 λ < C N 1 ν .
To obtain (14), for all z G N , we write
I E [ E ˜ 1 * ( z , θ ) ] I E [ E ˜ 1 ( z , θ ) C 1 ϕ ( d , θ , a ) I E O 1 I { | O | γ N } i = 1 d H ( a 1 θ i I k i ) .
We apply the Holder inequality for α = q 2 and β = α α 1 . So, for all z G N , we obtain
I E O 1 I { | O | γ N } i = 1 d H ( a 1 θ i I 1 i ) I E 1 / α O α 1 I { | O | γ N } I E 1 / β i = 1 d H β ( a 1 θ i I 1 i ) γ N 1 I E 1 / α O 2 α I E 1 / β i = 1 d H β ( a 1 θ i I 1 i ) C γ N 1 ϕ 1 / β ( d , θ , a ) .
Hence,
d N max z G N I E [ E ˜ 1 * ( z , θ ) ] I E [ E ˜ 1 ( z , θ ) N 1 / 2 b 2 λ / q ϕ ( 1 β ) / β ( d , θ , a ) .
Since λ > q / 2 b 2 , we obtain (14).
Now, we prove (15). Indeed, we have
I P E ˜ 1 * ( y , θ ) I E E ˜ 1 * ( y , θ ) > ε = I P 1 n I E i = 1 d H ( a 1 θ i I 1 i ) k = 1 N Γ k > ε I P i = 1 N Λ i ( z ) > ε N I E [ i = 1 d H ( a 1 θ i I 1 i ) ] .
where
Γ k = 1 N I E i = 1 d H ( a 1 θ i I 1 i ) χ ( I k , O k ) ,
with, for z H and w I R ,
χ ( z , w ) = Y ( w ) i = 1 d H ( a 1 θ i I i ) I E O i i = 1 d H ( a 1 θ i I 1 i ) ,
and Y ( w ) = w t y 1 I { w t y 0 } 1 I w t y γ N .
Observe that
χ 2 C H d γ N , Lip ( χ ) C ( a d γ N Lip ( K ) + H d ) C a d γ N Lip ( H )
Now, we apply Newmann’s inequality (see [33], page 2) on Γ k . We thus have to evaluate V a r k = 1 N Γ k and C o v ( Γ u 1 Γ u s , Γ v 1 Γ v t ) , for all ( u 1 , , u s ) I N s and ( v 1 , , v t ) I N v . For this, we have
V a r i = 1 N Γ i = i = 1 N j = 1 N C o v ( Γ i , Γ j ) = N V a r Γ 1 + i = 1 N j = 1 j i N C o v ( Γ i , Γ j ) .
Obviously,
I E O * 2 1 I | Y 1 * < γ N i = 1 d H 2 ( a 1 θ i I i I E i = 1 d H 2 ( a 1 θ i I i I E O 2 | I 1 C I E [ [ i = 1 d H 2 ( a 1 θ i I i ] .
Since
I E i = 1 d H j ( a 1 θ i I i ( x ) = O ( ϕ ( d , θ , a ) ) ,
then
V a r ( Γ 1 ) = O 1 N ϕ ( d , θ , a ) .
Concerning the term i = 1 N j = 1 j i N C o v ( Γ i , Γ j ) , we have
i = 1 N j = 1 j i N C o v ( Γ i , Γ j ) = i = 1 N j = 1 0 < | i j | m N N C o v ( Γ i , Γ j ) + i = 1 N j = 1 | i j | > m N N C o v ( Γ i , Γ j ) = : T I + T I I ,
where ( m N ) is a positive sequence of integers, which moves to infinity as n .
We combine (Assumption 4) and (Assumption 6) to deduce
C o v ( Γ i , Γ j ) C ϕ ( λ + 1 ) / λ ( d , θ , a ) + ϕ 2 ( d , θ , a ) .
Consequently,
T I C N m N ϕ ( λ + 1 ) / λ ( d , θ , a ) ,
and by using Lemma 1 we conclude that
T I I C N γ N a d Lip ( H ) e λ m N .
Therefore,
i = 1 N j = 1 j i N C o v ( Γ i , Γ j ) C N m N ϕ ( λ + 1 ) / λ ( d , θ , a ) + N γ N ( a ) d Lip ( H ) e λ m N .
Using m N = λ 1 log γ N a d Lip ( H ) λ ϕ ( λ + 1 ) / λ ( d , θ , a ) , we obtain
1 N ϕ ( d , θ , a ) i = 1 N j = 1 j i N C o v ( Γ i , Γ j ) 0 , a s n .
Finally,
V a r i = 1 N Γ i = O 1 n ϕ ( d , θ , a ) .
It remains to treat C o v ( Γ u 1 Γ u s , Γ v 1 Γ v t ) . Indeed, for the case of v 1 > u s , we have from Lemma 1 that
| C o v ( Γ u 1 Γ u s , Γ v 1 Γ v t ) | s t a d Lip ( H ) 2 C γ N n ϕ ( d , θ , a ) t + s e λ ( v 1 u s ) .
On the other hand, we have
| C o v ( Γ u 1 Γ u s , Γ v 1 Γ v t ) | ϕ ( λ + 1 ) / λ ( d , θ , a ) + ϕ 2 ( d , θ , a ) C γ N N ϕ ( d , θ , a ) s + t ϕ ( λ + 1 ) / λ ( d , θ , a ) .
Next, taking a 1 2 a + 1 -power of the first and a 2 a 2 a + 1 -power for the second, we obtain
| C o v ( Γ u 1 Γ u s , Γ v 1 Γ v t ) | s t ϕ ( d , θ , a ) C γ N N ϕ ( d , θ , a ) t + s e λ ( v 1 u s ) / ( 2 ( λ + 1 ) ) .
For the second case, where t 1 = s u , we obtain
| C o v ( Γ u 1 Γ u s , Γ v 1 Γ v t ) | ϕ ( d , θ , a ) C γ N N ϕ ( d , θ , a ) t + s .
Now, we apply Kallabis and Newmann’s inequality (see [32]) for
K N = C γ N N ϕ ( d , θ , a ) , M N = C γ N N ϕ ( d , θ , a ) a n d V a r k = 1 N Γ k = O 1 N ϕ ( d , θ , a )
to obtain
I P E ˜ 1 * ( y , θ ) I E E ˜ 1 * ( y , θ ) > ϵ 0 log N N 1 ξ ϕ ( d , θ , a ) I P | k = 1 N Γ k | > ϵ 0 log N N 1 ξ ϕ ( d , θ , a ) exp ϵ 0 2 log N / ( 2 N 1 ξ ϕ ( d , θ , a ) ) V a r k = 1 N Γ k + C γ N ( N ϕ ( d , θ , a ) ) 1 3 log N N 1 ξ ϕ ( d , θ , a ) 5 6 exp ϵ 0 2 log N C N ξ + γ N N ξ / 6 log 5 N N ϕ ( d , θ , a ) 1 6 C exp C ϵ 0 2 log N .
An adequate choice of ϵ 0 allows us to achieve the proof of
sup y [ X P p ( θ ) Γ , X P p ( θ ) + Γ ] E ˜ 1 ( y , θ ) I E E ˜ 1 ( y , θ ) = O a . c o . log N N 1 ξ ϕ ( d , θ , a ) .
Using similar arguments, we prove that
sup y [ X P p ( θ ) Γ , X P p ( θ ) + Γ ] E ˜ 2 ( y , θ ) I E E ˜ 2 ( y , θ ) = O a . c o . log N N 1 ξ ϕ ( d , θ , a ) .
Hence, the proof is complete. □
Proof of Lemma 3.
From the stationarity property, we obtain
E E ˜ 1 ( y , θ ) E 1 ( y , θ ) = 1 E i = 1 d H ( a 1 θ i I 1 i ) E i = 1 d H ( a 1 θ i I 1 i ) E 1 ( y , I 1 ) E 1 ( y , θ ) , = 1 E i = 1 d H ( a 1 θ i I 1 i E i = 1 d H ( a 1 θ i I 1 i E 1 ( t , I 1 ) E 1 ( y , θ ) 1 I B ( θ 1 , a ) × B ( θ d , a ) C a b 1 .
This implies that
E E ˜ 1 ( y , θ ) E 1 ( y , θ ) = O a b 1 .
Similarly, we obtain
E E ˜ 2 ( y , θ ) E 2 ( y , θ ) = O a b 2 .
Lemma 4.
Under the hypotheses of Lemma 2, there exists ϵ 0 > 0 such that
n 1 I P inf y [ X P p ( θ ) δ , X P p ( θ ) + δ ] | E ^ 2 ( y , θ ) | ϵ 0 < .
Proof of Lemma 4.
By taking into account the fact that E 2 ( y , θ ) > 0 , for all y R , we readily infer that
inf y [ X P p ( θ ) δ , X P p ( θ ) + δ ] | E ^ 2 ( y , θ ) | 1 2 E 2 ( y , θ )
which implies that
sup y [ X P p ( θ ) δ , X P p ( θ ) + δ ] | E ^ 2 ( y , θ ) E 2 ( y , θ ) | > 1 2 E 2 ( y , θ ) ,
and then
I P inf y [ X P p ( θ ) δ , X P p ( θ ) + δ ] | E ^ 2 ( y , θ ) | 1 2 E 2 ( y , θ ) I P sup y [ X P p ( θ ) δ , X P p ( θ ) + δ ] | E ^ 2 ( y , θ ) E 2 ( y , θ ) | > 1 2 G 2 ( y , θ ) .
An application of Lemma 2, with the particular choice ϵ 0 = 1 2 E 2 ( y , θ ) , gives
n 1 I P inf y [ X P p ( θ ) δ , X P p ( θ ) + δ ] | E ^ 2 ( y , θ ) | 1 2 E 2 ( y , θ ) < .
Hence, the proof is complete. □

Author Contributions

The authors contributed approximately equally to this work. Formal analysis, F.A.; Validation, S.H.A. and M.K.A.; Writing—review and editing, A.L. and M.R. All authors have read and agreed to the final version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research was funded by Princess Nourah bint Abdulrahman University Researchers Supporting Project number PNURSP2025R358, Princess Nourah bint Abdulrahman University, Riyadh, Saudi Arabia, and the Deanship of Scientific Research and Graduate Studies at King Khalid University through the Research Groups Program under grant number R.G.P.1/163/45.

Data Availability Statement

The data used in this study are available through the the following link: https://stooq.com/db/h/ (accessed on 8 December 2024).

Acknowledgments

The authors thank and extend their appreciation to the funders of this work: This work was supported by Princess Nourah bint Abdulrahman University Researchers Supporting Project number PNURSP2025R358, Princess Nourah bint Abdulrahman University, Riyadh, Saudi Arabia, and the Deanship of Scientific Research and Graduate Studies at King Khalid University through the Research Groups Program under grant number R.G.P.1/163/45.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflicts of interest.

References

  1. Bank, P.; Bayer, C.; Friz, P.K.; Pelizzari, L. Rough PDEs for local stochastic volatility models. Math. Financ. 2023; early view. [Google Scholar]
  2. Floros, C.; Gkillas, K.; Kountzakis, C. Generalized Stochastic Integration and Financial Modeling. Ann. Financ. Econ. 2024, 19, 2450014. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Comte, F.; Renault, E. Long memory in continuous-time stochastic volatility models. Math. Financ. 1998, 8, 291–323. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Alos, E.; León, J.A.; Vives, J. On the short-time behavior of the implied volatility for jump-diffusion models with stochastic volatility. Financ. Stoch. 2007, 11, 571–589. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Fouque, J.P.; Papanicolaou, G.; Sircar, K.R. Derivatives in Financial Markets with Stochastic Volatility; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 2000. [Google Scholar]
  6. Tankov, P. Financial Modelling with Jump Processes; Chapman and Hall/CRC: Boca Raton, FL, USA, 2003. [Google Scholar]
  7. Candia, C.; Herrera, R. An empirical review of dynamic extreme value models for forecasting value at risk, expected shortfall and expectile. J. Empir. Financ. 2024, 77, 101488. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Chen, J.M. On exactitude in financial regulation: Value-at-risk, expected shortfall, and expectiles. Risks 2018, 6, 61. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Maume-Deschamps, V.; Rullière, D.; Said, K. Extremes for multivariate expectiles. Stat. Risk Model. 2018, 35, 111–140. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Bellini, F.; Di Bernardino, E. Risk management with expectiles. Eur. J. Financ. 2017, 23, 487–506. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Kuan, C.M.; Yeh, J.H.; Hsu, Y.C. Assessing value at risk with care, the conditional autoregressive expectile models. J. Econ. 2009, 150, 261–270. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Ehm, W.; Gneiting, T.; Jordan, A.; Krüger, F. Of quantiles and expectiles: Consistent scoring functions, Choquet representations and forecast rankings. J. R. Stat. Soc. Ser. B Stat. Methodol. 2016, 78, 505–562. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Bellini, F.; Bignozzi, V.; Puccetti, G. Conditional expectiles, time consistency and mixture convexity properties. Insur. Math. Econ. 2018, 82, 117–123. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Koenker, R.; Bassett, G., Jr. Regression quantiles. Econometrica 1978, 46, 33–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Koenker, R.; Bassett, G., Jr. Robust tests for heteroscedasticity based on regression quantiles. Econometrica 1982, 50, 43–61. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Daouia, A.; Girard, S.; Stupfler, G. Estimation of tail risk based on extreme expectiles. J. R. Stat. Soc. Ser. B Stat. Methodol. 2018, 80, 263–292. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Efron, B. Regression percentiles using asymmetric squared error loss. Stat. Sin. 1991, 1, 93–125. [Google Scholar]
  18. Holzmann, H.; Bernhard, K. Expectile asymptotics. Electron. J. Stat. 2016, 10, 2355–2371. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Krätschmer, V.; Zähle, H. Statistical inference for expectile-based risk measures. Scand. J. Stat. 2017, 44, 425–454. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Maume-Deschamps, V.; Rullière, D.; Said, K. Multivariate extensions of expectiles risk measures. Depend. Model. 2017, 5, 20–44. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Mohammedi, M.; Bouzebda, S.; Laksaci, A. The consistency and asymptotic normality of the kernel type expectile regression estimator for functional data. J. Multivar. Anal. 2021, 181, 104673. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Almanjahie, I.M.; Bouzebda, S.; Kaid, Z.; Laksaci, A. Nonparametric estimation of expectile regression in functional dependent data. J. Nonparametr. Stat. 2022, 34, 250–281. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Alshahrani, F.; Almanjahie, I.M.; Elmezouar, Z.C.; Kaid, Z.; Laksaci, A.; Rachdi, M. Functional ergodic time series analysis using expectile regression. Mathematics 2022, 10, 3919. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Bosq, D. Linear Processes in Function Spaces: Theory and Applications; Lecture Notes in Statistics, 149; Springer: New York, NY, USA, 2000. [Google Scholar]
  25. Ferraty, F.; Vieu, P. Nonparametric Functional Data Analysis: Theory and Practice; Springer Series in Statistics; Springer: New York, NY, USA, 2006. [Google Scholar]
  26. Ramsay, J.O.; Silverman, B.W. Applied Functional Data Analysis: Methods and Case Studies; Springer Series in Statistics; Springer: New York, NY, USA, 2002. [Google Scholar]
  27. Lim, K.P.; Brooks, R.D.; Kim, J.H. Financial crisis and stock market efficiency: Empirical evidence from Asian countries. Int. Rev. Financ. Anal. 2008, 17, 571–591. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Rachdi, M.; Vieu, P. Nonparametric regression for functional data: Automatic smoothing parameter selection. J. Stat. Plan. Inference 2007, 137, 2784–2801. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Martínez-Miranda, M.D.; Raya-Miranda, R.; González-Manteiga, W.; González-Carmona, A. A bootstrap local bandwidth selector for additive models. J. Comput. Graph. Stat. 2008, 17, 38–55. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Shang, H.L. Bayesian bandwidth estimation for a functional nonparametric regression model with mixed types of regressors and unknown error density. J. Nonparametr. Stat. 2014, 26, 599–615. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Doukhan, P.; Louhichi, S. A new weak dependence condition and applications to moment inequalities. Stoch. Process. Their Appl. 1999, 84, 313–342. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Doukhan, P.; Neumann, M.H. Probability and moment inequalities for sums of weakly dependent random variables, with applications. Stoch. Process. Their Appl. 2007, 117, 878–903. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Kallabis, R.S.; Neumann, M.H. An exponential inequality under weak dependence. Bernoulli 2006, 12, 333–350. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. The curves I k = 1 , , 80 ( t ) and t j = 1 , , 60 [ 0 , 1 ] .
Figure 1. The curves I k = 1 , , 80 ( t ) and t j = 1 , , 60 [ 0 , 1 ] .
Axioms 14 00147 g001
Figure 2. The three components of the function R ( t ) .
Figure 2. The three components of the function R ( t ) .
Axioms 14 00147 g002
Figure 3. The percentage of the violation cases for both models: conditional expectile on the left and conditional VaR on the right.
Figure 3. The percentage of the violation cases for both models: conditional expectile on the left and conditional VaR on the right.
Axioms 14 00147 g003
Table 1. The A L S ( p ) for different parameter choices (cross-validation rules, Volterra Kernel, sample sizes, and orders of expectiles).
Table 1. The A L S ( p ) for different parameter choices (cross-validation rules, Volterra Kernel, sample sizes, and orders of expectiles).
Bandwidth ChoiceVolterra KernelN p = 0.1 p = 0.05 p = 0.01
Local choiceSK500.680.470.36
1500.320.240.12
2500.200.150.93
Local choiceEK500.820.740.61
1500.660.430.22
2500.510.340.18
Global choiceSK500.950.860.79
1500.720.640.57
2500.600.510.44
Global choiceEK501.561.331.17
1501.201.111.03
2501.121.461.38
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Alkhaldi, S.H.; Alshahrani, F.; Alaoui, M.K.; Laksaci, A.; Rachdi, M. Multifunctional Expectile Regression Estimation in Volterra Time Series: Application to Financial Risk Management. Axioms 2025, 14, 147. https://doi.org/10.3390/axioms14020147

AMA Style

Alkhaldi SH, Alshahrani F, Alaoui MK, Laksaci A, Rachdi M. Multifunctional Expectile Regression Estimation in Volterra Time Series: Application to Financial Risk Management. Axioms. 2025; 14(2):147. https://doi.org/10.3390/axioms14020147

Chicago/Turabian Style

Alkhaldi, Somayah Hussain, Fatimah Alshahrani, Mohammed Kbiri Alaoui, Ali Laksaci, and Mustapha Rachdi. 2025. "Multifunctional Expectile Regression Estimation in Volterra Time Series: Application to Financial Risk Management" Axioms 14, no. 2: 147. https://doi.org/10.3390/axioms14020147

APA Style

Alkhaldi, S. H., Alshahrani, F., Alaoui, M. K., Laksaci, A., & Rachdi, M. (2025). Multifunctional Expectile Regression Estimation in Volterra Time Series: Application to Financial Risk Management. Axioms, 14(2), 147. https://doi.org/10.3390/axioms14020147

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop