House Prices and the Effectiveness of Monetary Policy in an Estimated DSGE Model of Morocco
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Literature Review
3. The Dynamics of the Moroccan Housing Sector
4. The Model
4.1. The Borrowers
4.2. The Savers
- is the floating nominal exchange rate38,
- denotes the foreign bonds held by these households,
- is the interest rate prevailing in foreign financial markets,
- indicates the profits earned by patient households due to their ownership of intermediate firms.
4.3. The Intermediate Goods Firms
- : the degree of indexation to the inflation of the previous period.
- reflects the slope of the New Keynesian Phillips curve.
- is the marginal real cost in its log-linearized form.
4.4. The Final Goods Firms
4.5. The Tradable Goods Sector
4.6. Price Formation
- is the logarithm of the nominal effective exchange rate,
- is the log of the global price index of tradable goods.
4.7. International Risk-Sharing Mechanism
4.8. Monetary Policy Rule:
4.9. Equilibrium
5. Calibration and Estimation Procedure
Parameters | Definition | Source of the Calibration | Value |
---|---|---|---|
Discount factor of savers. | Funke et al. (2018) | 0.99 | |
Discount factor of borrowers. | Funke et al. (2018) | 0.98 | |
Elasticity of substitution between differentiated non-durable goods. | Funke et al. (2018) | 6 | |
Elasticity of substitution between differentiated durable goods. | Funke et al. (2018) | 6 | |
Depreciation rate of residential stock. | Funke et al. (2018) | 0.01 | |
LTV ratio. | (Rapport Annuel Sur La Stabilité Financière, 2017)52. | 0.69 | |
Share of housing in utility. | Calculated by the authors53. | 0.58 | |
Property tax. | CODE GENERAL DES IMPOTS (2024). | 0.04 | |
Degree of openness. | Calculated by the authors54. | 0,42 | |
Elasticity of substitution between goods produced in different foreign countries. | Funke et al. (2018) | 2 | |
Elasticity of substitution between domestic and foreign goods. | Funke et al. (2018) | 2 |
6. Results
7. Conclusions
Author Contributions
Funding
Institutional Review Board Statement
Data Availability Statement
Conflicts of Interest
1 | This viewpoint contrasts with that of Bernanke and Gertler (1999), who argued that monetary policy should not be guided by an approach aimed at reacting to fluctuations in asset prices. Instead, it should focus on responding to the macroeconomic effects resulting from these fluctuations. |
2 | Cf. (Ahir & Loungani, 2019). |
3 | Cf. (Bernanke & Gertler, 1999) |
4 | Indeed, monetary policy in Morocco has evolved over time in line with the country’s economic situation and objectives: from a policy focused on credit regulation and administered interest rates to one marked by the deregulation of the banking sector and the liberalization of interest rates, aiming to ensure a transition to an inflation-targeting regime. |
5 | According to Jordà et al. (2015), real estate bubbles fueled by credit are riskier, and the recessions that follow them are more severe and prolonged. |
6 | This approach will allow us to improve the model’s fit by incorporating priors that reflect the structure of the Moroccan economy, especially when the study is conducted with a limited sample size. |
7 | This viewpoint contrasts with that of Bernanke and Gertler (1999), according to which monetary policy should not be guided by an approach aimed at responding to fluctuations in asset prices, but rather it should address the macroeconomic effects arising from these fluctuations. |
8 | See note 2 above. |
9 | |
10 | In the sense that implementing a monetary policy characterized by lower interest rates to stimulate housing construction can shift them over time. |
11 | It should be noted that Leamer argued that residential properties follow a volume cycle rather than a price cycle. |
12 | Indeed, house prices reach their peak of 0.5% after 10 quarters following the monetary shock, and they only return to their trend after 20 quarters. |
13 | It should be noted that, in line with other studies, these authors tested the hypothesis suggesting that due to structural changes in the financial system and the monetary policy regime (during the 1980s), the relationship between monetary variables and housing prices has changed. Their results indicate a stronger relationship during the period 1985–2006. |
14 | Cf. (Miles & Zhu, 2023). |
15 | |
16 | These quarterly data, provided by the Bank for International Settlements, cover 20 countries and span the period from 1970 to 2018. |
17 | However, for them, this does not mean that it is always the optimal decision. Indeed, according to André et al. (2022), it is necessary to distinguish between two situations: the first is for an economy at full employment with an inflation rate exceeding the target rate, and the second is for an economy with underemployment, a low inflation rate, and coinciding with a rapid appreciation in housing prices. Implementing a restrictive monetary policy would be more costly in economic terms in the second situation than in the first. |
18 | Indeed, the increase in real housing prices resulting from an accommodative quantitative easing shock (4.56%) is larger than that produced by a conventional monetary shock (2.30%). |
19 | Due to the decrease in borrowing costs and the increase in demand for durable goods. |
20 | Cf. (Pierre, 2018). |
21 | |
22 | While noting that expenditures on durable goods are characterized by greater sensitivity compared to expenditures on non-durable goods. |
23 | Examples of these efforts include: providing financial assistance to buyers, the 250,000-dirham social housing program, and the low-value 140,000-dirham social housing program. |
24 | Cf. (Funke et al., 2018). |
25 | In 2023, the number of housing units produced reached 168,628 units. |
26 | As shown in Figure 4. |
27 | Cf. (Kiyotaki & Moore, 1997). |
28 | Through the imposition of a borrowing constraint on impatient households, this model allowed us to take into account the commitment of Bank Al-Maghrib to implement one of the crucial instruments of macroprudential policy aimed at preventing financial crises. This is the "loan-to-value" ratio, which requires this type of economic agent to borrow up to a determined fraction of the value of the new real estate acquisition. |
29 | It should be noted that, following other previous academic contributions such as (Monacelli, 2009), (Funke & Paetz, 2013), and Funke et al. (2018), we chose to neglect the modeling of the capital accumulation process. |
30 | |
31 | This exogenous process can be formulated as follows: . |
32 | With:. |
33 | It can be defined as
where
is the depreciation rate of the residential property stock. |
34 | Adjusted for LTV and amortization . |
35 | Note that we define
and as multipliers on Equations (5) and (6), respectively. |
36 | According to Monacelli, this value depends on three elements: the utility gain resulting from the consumption of an additional unit of durable goods , the additional utility provided by the relaxation of the collateral constraint , and the anticipated utility derived from future consumption financed by the sale of a real estate asset acquired in the middle of the previous period: |
37 | Except that they are not subject to a borrowing constraint. |
38 | Although Morocco has not yet fully liberalized its exchange rate regime, adopting an analytical framework based on the assumption of a floating nominal exchange rate has two implications: firstly, it reflects the commitment of the country’s monetary authorities to a gradual transition towards a more flexible exchange rate regime; secondly, it will allow us to capture the impact of this transition on the transmission of monetary policy in this economy. |
39 | For the other variables, we maintain the same notation as that used for the variables related to borrowers. |
40 | Where et . |
41 | Cf. (Funke & Paetz, 2013). |
42 | Where: . This equation, according to (Funke & Paetz, 2013), denotes the sector-specific cost shocks for each production sector. |
43 | For more details on the conditions under which purchasing power parity is upheld, the reader may refer to the work of Gali and Monacelli (2005). |
44 | Cf. (Funke & Paetz, 2013), (Funke et al., 2018). |
45 | This shock is defined by (Funke et al., 2018) as: . |
46 | We assume that Bank Al-Maghrib defines price stability as the main objective of its monetary decisions. |
47 | Indeed, the choice of this work as the calibration reference is explained by our observation that, for the Moroccan case, these values improve the model’s fit quality and the consistency of the impulse response functions. |
48 | As noted by Achour (2019), the choice of an estimation period starting from 2007 is justified by two reasons: first, this year, after the update of the Moroccan national accounting system, is established as the base year; second, it is possible that statistical methods related to the alignment of samples with different base years may lead to an incorrect specification of the model. |
49 | All these variables are seasonally adjusted using the X-13 ARIMA procedure. |
50 | Due to a lack of data on real housing investment, this variable was approximated by the number of completed housing units sourced from the database of the Ministry of National Territorial Planning, Urbanism, Housing, and City Policy. To align it with the quarterly frequency of the model, this annual data series was transformed into a quarterly format. |
51 | The variables for real GDP per capita, real consumption per capita, and employment are collected and processed from the database of the High Commission for Planning in Morocco. |
52 | |
53 | This value is obtained by calculating the average ratio of real residential investment to real GDP. |
54 | Obtained by calculating the average ratio of imports to GDP over the period 2014Q1–2023Q1. |
55 | The estimation of the posterior distribution is carried out using the Metropolis–Hastings algorithm. |
56 | The impulse responses are plotted for three assumptions regarding the shares of Moroccan borrowers: 0.12, as estimated by Funke et al. (Funke et al., 2018) 0.35 as in Iacoviello and Neri (2010) and 0.50 as in Monacelli (2009). |
57 | Noted in the figure as RHP. |
58 | The empirical finding of a negative impact of an increase in the policy interest rate on housing prices in Morocco aligns with the results obtained by Goodhart and Hofmann (2008), Musso et al. (2011), and André et al. (2022). However, it contrasts with the findings of Miles and Zhu (2023), who revealed the ineffectiveness of monetary policy in influencing housing prices. |
59 | This result is in agreement with what is suggested by Yassine Slaoui (2024) on the ability of housing prices, as a credit supply factor, to influence credit growth in Morocco. |
60 | It should be noted that the lenders in this economy reduce their consumption of non-residential goods in a less intense manner than the borrowers. |
61 | As demonstrated by Jordà et al. (2015), asset price bubbles fueled by credit increase the risk of financial crises. Moreover, the collapse of these prices generates deeper recessions and slower returns to equilibrium. |
62 | |
63 | Among these limitations, we can mention the failure to account for recession and expansion cycles, capital gains taxation, and legal depreciation requirements. In addition to an analysis conducted at the intensive margin rather than the extensive margin, the analytical framework of this model is characterized by limited heterogeneity. |
64 | As previously stated by André et al. (2022). |
References
- Achour, A. (2019). Réserves de change et fonctionnement de l’économie marocaine: Enseignements partir d’un modèle DSGE. Available online: https://www.bkam.ma/ (accessed on 11 March 2025).
- Ahearne, A. G., Ammer, J., Doyle, B. M., Kole, L. S., & Martin, R. F. (2005). House prices and monetary Policy: A cross-country study. Available online: https://www.federalreserve.gov/econres.htm (accessed on 11 March 2025).
- Ahir, H., & Loungani, P. (2019). Managing House Price Booms: Evolution of IMF Surveillance and Policy Advice. In Hot property: The housing market in major cities (pp. 83–95). Springer International Publishing. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- André, C., Caraiani, P., Călin, A. C., & Gupta, R. (2022). Can monetary policy lean against housing bubbles? Economic Modelling, 110, 105801. [Google Scholar]
- Bernanke, B., & Gertler, M. (1999). Monetary policy and asset price volatility. Available online: https://www.kansascityfed.org/documents/3539/1999-S99gert.pdf (accessed on 11 March 2025).
- Campbell, S. D., Davis, M. A., Gallin, J., & Martin, R. F. (2009). What moves housing markets: A variance decomposition of the rent-price ratio’. Journal of Urban Economics, 66(2), 90–102. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Chen, S. S., & Lin, T. Y. (2022). Revisiting the link between house prices and monetary policy’, B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics, 22(2), 481–515. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- CODE GENERAL DES IMPOTS. (2024). Available online: https://impots.cm/fr/document/code-general-des-impots-2024 (accessed on 11 March 2025).
- Costa, C. J. (2025). Understanding DSGE (1st ed.). Vernon Press. 2016. Available online: https://vernonpress.com/book/70 (accessed on 11 March 2025).
- Del Negro, M., & Otrok, C. (2007). 99 Luftballons: Monetary policy and the house price boom across U.S. states’. Journal of Monetary Economics, 54(7), 1962–1985. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- El Khalifi, A., Ouakil, H., & Torres, J. L. (2024). Efficiency and welfare effects of fiscal policy in emerging economies: The case of morocco. International Economic Journal, 38(3), 507–530. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- El Othmani, J. (2018). Estimation bayésienne d’un modèle néo-keynésien pour l’économie marocaine. Available online: www.bkam.ma (accessed on 11 March 2025).
- Funke, M., Kirkby, R., & Mihaylovski, P. (2018). House prices and macroprudential policy in an estimated DSGE model of New Zealand. Journal of Macroeconomics, 56, 152–171. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Funke, M., & Paetz, M. (2013). Housing prices and the business cycle: An empirical application to Hong Kong. Journal of Housing Economics, 22(1), 62–76. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gali, J., & Monacelli, T. (2005). Monetary policy and exchange rate volatility in a small open economy. The Review of Economic Studies, 72(3), 707–734. [Google Scholar]
- Galí, J., & Gambetti, L. (2015). The effects of monetary policy on stock market bubbles: Some evidence. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 7(1), 233–257. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gan, J. (2010). Housing wealth and consumption growth: Evidence from a large panel of households. Review of Financial Studies, 23(6), 2229–2267. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Goodhart, C., & Hofmann, B. (2008). House prices, money, credit, and the macroeconomy. Oxf Review of Economic Policy, 24(1), 180–205. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gupta, R., Jurgilas, M., Kabundi, A., & Miller, S. M. (2012). Monetary policy and housing sector dynamics in a large-scale Bayesian vector autoregressive model’. International Journal of Strategic Property Management, 16(1), 1–20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hatzius, J. (2008). Beyond leveraged losses: The balance sheet effects of the home price downturn. Brookings. [Google Scholar]
- Iacoviello, M. (2005). House prices, borrowing constraints, and monetary policy in the business cycle. American Economic Review, 95(3), 739–764. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Iacoviello, M., & Neri, S. (2010). Housing market spillovers: Evidence from an estimated DSGE model. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 2(2), 125–164. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Jarociński, M., & Smets, F. (2008). House prices and the stance of monetary policy. Available online: https://www.ecb.europa.eu/pub/pdf/scpwps/ecbwp891.pdf (accessed on 11 March 2025).
- Jordà, Ò., Schularick, M., & Taylor, A. M. (2015). Leveraged bubbles. Journal of Monetary Economics, 76, S1–S20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Justiniano, A., & Preston, B. (2010). Monetary policy and uncertainty in an empirical small open-economy model. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 25(1), 93–128. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kiyotaki, N., & Moore, J. (1997). Credit cycles. Journal of Political Economy, 105(2), 211–248. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kuttner, K. N. (2012). Low interest rates and housing bubbles: Still no smoking gun. In The role of central banks in financial stability, world scientific studies in international economics (Vol. 30, pp. 159–185). World Scientific Publishing. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Lastrapes, W. D. (2002). The real price of housing and money supply shocks: Time series evidence and theoretical simulations. Journal of Housing Economics, 11(1), 40–74. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Leamer, E. E. (2015). Housing really is the business cycle: What survives the lessons of 2008–09? Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 47(S1), 43–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Miles, W., & Zhu, X. (2023). Housing and the changing impact of monetary policy. International Review of Economics & Finance, 86, 587–603. [Google Scholar]
- Ministère de l’Aménagement du Territoire National. (2022). Ministère de l’Aménagement du Territoire National, ‘Évolution des indicateurs du secteur de l’immobilier: Dix ans de dynamisme (2012–2021). Available online: https://www.mhpv.gov.ma/fr/ (accessed on 11 March 2025).
- Monacelli, T. (2009). New Keynesian models, durable goods, and collateral constraints. Journal of Monetary Economics, 56(2), 242–254. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Moustabchir, A., Ouakil, H., El Ouazzani, H., & Lechheb, H. (2024a). A DSGE model approach to examining the impact of the Russian–Ukrainian War and oil shocks on the Moroccan economy. African Development Review, 36(S1), S94–S107. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Moustabchir, A., Ouakil, H., El Ouazzani, H., & Lechheb, H. (2024b). Modeling the circular economy in food production: Insights from a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium analysis. Elsevier B.V. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Musso, A., Neri, S., & Stracca, L. (2011). Housing, consumption and monetary policy: How different are the US and the euro area? Journal of Banking and Finance, 35(11), 3019–3041. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Nsafoah, D., & Dery, C. (2024). Effect of conventional and unconventional monetary policy shocks on housing prices in Canada. Journal of Housing Economics, 64, 101993. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Nsafoah, D., & Hashmi, A. R. (2021). International spillovers of new monetary policy. International spillovers of conventional versus new monetary policy. Working Papers 2021-03. Department of Economics, University of Calgary. Available online: https://ideas.repec.org/p/clg/wpaper/2021-03.html (accessed on 11 March 2025).
- Ouakil, H., Moustabchir, A., Lechheb, H., & El Ouazzani, H. (2024). Fiscal policy in the face of the health crisis: A simulation using a hybrid DSGE-SIR model. African Development Review, 3(3), 425–443. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Pierre, R. A. (2018). Analyse macroéconomique et politiques de stabilisation. 546. OCP Policy Center. [Google Scholar]
- Poterba, J. M. (1984). Tax subsidies to owner-occupied housing: An asset-market approach. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 99(4), 729–752. [Google Scholar]
- Rapport Annuel Sur La Stabilité Financière. (2017). Available online: https://www.bcc.cd/surveillance-des-intermediaires-financiers/publications/rapport-annuel-sur-la-stabilite-financiere/rapport-sur-la-stabilite-financiere-2017 (accessed on 11 March 2025).
- Rossi, B. (2021). Identifying and estimating the effects of unconventional monetary policy: How to do it and what have we learned? Economic Journal, 24(1), C1–C32. [Google Scholar]
- Slaoui, Y. (2024). Dynamique de l’offre de crédits et activité économique au Maroc. Available online: www.bkam.ma (accessed on 11 March 2025).
- Taylor, J. B. (2007). Housing and monetary policy. Available online: http://www.nber.org/papers/w13682 (accessed on 11 March 2025).
Parameter | Prior Mean | Reference | std | Posterior Mean |
---|---|---|---|---|
1.9 | (Achour, 2019) | 0.05 | 1.92 | |
1.72 | (Achour, 2019) | 0.05 | 1.63 | |
0.38 | (Funke et al., 2018) | 0.2 | 0.37 | |
0.4 | (Funke et al., 2018) | 0.05 | 0.06 | |
0.9 | (Achour, 2019) | 0.1 | 0.51 | |
1.25 | (Achour, 2019) | 0.7 | 1.39 | |
0.34 | (Achour, 2019) | 0.5 | 0.40 | |
0.8 | (Funke et al., 2018) | 0.05 | 0.91 | |
0.4 | (Funke et al., 2018) | 0.05 | 0.97 | |
0.5 | (Funke et al., 2018) | 0.1 | 0.26 | |
0.5 | (Funke et al., 2018) | 0.1 | 0.39 |
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content. |
© 2025 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Said, R.; Hicham, O. House Prices and the Effectiveness of Monetary Policy in an Estimated DSGE Model of Morocco. Economies 2025, 13, 87. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies13040087
Said R, Hicham O. House Prices and the Effectiveness of Monetary Policy in an Estimated DSGE Model of Morocco. Economies. 2025; 13(4):87. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies13040087
Chicago/Turabian StyleSaid, Roubyou, and Ouakil Hicham. 2025. "House Prices and the Effectiveness of Monetary Policy in an Estimated DSGE Model of Morocco" Economies 13, no. 4: 87. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies13040087
APA StyleSaid, R., & Hicham, O. (2025). House Prices and the Effectiveness of Monetary Policy in an Estimated DSGE Model of Morocco. Economies, 13(4), 87. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies13040087