1. Introduction
Introducing (non-interest bearing) money in general equilibrium models with single or multiple assets that yield non-negative nominal interest rate is, understandably, not straightforward. In this regard, multiple modelling approaches exist to motivate the role of money in such models; for example, money in the production function, money in the utility, cash-in-advance, shopping time, money search, mandatory cash reserve requirements (see
Walsh 2017 for a detailed discussion of these models). Following
Diamond and Dybvig (
1983), an alternative approach to create a role of currency for transactions in general equilibrium models, even if money is dominated in the rate of return, is based on spatial separation and limited communication. In this context, economic agents are subject to random relocation (liquidity preference) shocks, and fiat money is the only asset available to relocating agents for smoothing consumption at the new location, since they would have given up their claims on returns to capital that they held at their old location.
By modelling money in this manner, a number of recent studies have analyzed the effects of traditional monetary policies, i.e., money growth rate and cash-reserve requirements (which the financial intermediaries in the model are subjected to), and fiscal policy on growth, inflation and welfare in endogenous growth models (see for example,
Espinosa-Vega and Yip 1996,
1999,
2002;
Gupta 2007;
Bose et al. 2007;
Ghosh and Neanidis 2017). Against this backdrop, our paper aims to build on this line of theoretical set-up of incorporating money, by introducing, for the first time in this literature, a monetary authority that targets the inflation rate rather than the money growth rate, given the growing importance of inflation-targeting across the world.
1Specifically speaking, we develop an overlapping generations (OLG) monetary endogenous growth (due to public expenditures in the firms’ production function) model with inflation-targeting, characterized by relocation shocks for young agents, which in turn generates a role for money (even in the presence of the return-dominating physical capital) and financial intermediaries. Given this model, we show that growth dynamics emerge, with the growth path being S-shaped. On one hand, this results in three equilibria, with the low and high-growth equilibria being stable, but both of which are found to be locally indeterminate. On the other hand, the medium-growth equilibrium is unstable. Since, government expenditure is productive in our model, a higher inflation-target would translate into higher growth, but under multiple equilibria, an increase in the inflation-target is not necessarily going to be growth-enhancing at the medium-growth unstable equilibrium, which cannot be ruled out due to indeterminancy of the two other stable equilibria.
Our paper, in the process, also adds to the recent literature of monetary endogenous growth OLG models with money being modelled either through the cash-in-advance constraint or cash-reserve requirements of banks, that has shown the existence of growth dynamics, multiple equilibria (with possibility of chaos), and local indeterminacy (see for example,
Gupta and Vermeulen 2010;
Gupta 2011;
Kudoh 2013;
Gupta and Stander 2018). However, unlike these papers, which rely on an ad hoc approach of modelling financial intermediaries, we are able to provide a solid reasoning of the existence of banks based on the liquidity shock characterizing our model. Further, in our framework, we are also able to analyze growth dynamics and the impact of changes in the inflation-target by accommodating for the existence of unofficial financial markets, which are widely witnessed within the financial system of many developing economies (see
Gupta 2008,
2009;
Goswami and Gupta 2009, and references cited therein for detailed discussion in this regard).
At this stage, it is important for us to highlight in greater detail, in terms of the structure of the model, as to how our paper differs from the closely related studies of
Gupta and Vermeulen (
2010),
Kudoh (
2013), and
Gupta and Stander (
2018). To create growth dynamics in their models,
Gupta and Vermeulen (
2010) and
Gupta and Stander (
2018) had to respectively introduce probability of survival as a function of private and public investment, and lagged inputs respectively, while
Kudoh (
2013) had to rely on lump-sum, rather than income taxation. In terms of introducing money,
Kudoh (
2013) used an ad hoc cash-in-advance model while the other two papers introduced cash-reserve requirements that the banks need to hold, though, unlike us without providing proper microfoundation to the existence of banks. While these studies, like in our paper also produces multiple equilibria and indeterminancy, our paper does the same in the context of an inflation targeting monetary authority, by without having to introduce additional features (like, endogenous probability of death, lagged input, or lump-sum tax) in a more realistic model of money and financial intermediation. While our model does not produce chaotic growth dynamics as in the papers of
Gupta and Vermeulen (
2010),
Kudoh (
2013), and
Gupta and Stander (
2018), we are able to incorporate an important feature of developing economies in our model in the form of unofficial financial markets. In sum, our framework caters to both developed and developing inflation targeting economies, with proper microfounadtions for an explicit role of money, and a motivation for the existence of a banking system required to intermediate capital. In sum, our model is more general than the works of
Gupta and Vermeulen (
2010),
Kudoh (
2013), and
Gupta and Stander (
2018). Having said this, future work within our framework would need us to incorporate features to produce chaotic dynamics, which in turn have been shown to be present in data associated with economic growth, as pointed out by
Kříž and Knězáčková (
2014).
The remainder of the paper proceeds as follows:
Section 2 outlines the economic environment.
Section 3 develops the benchmark version of the monetary endogenous growth OLG model, while
Section 4 provides several extensions of benchmark model, with which we analyze growth dynamics, as well as, impact of the changes in the inflation target.
Section 5 offers some concluding remarks.
2. The Economic Environment
The economy has four principal agents, namely two-period lived overlapping generations consumers, financial intermediaries (banks), firms and an infinitely-lived government. There exists an infinite sequence of two-period-lived overlapping generations, besides, an initial old generation. At each date
, young agents are assigned to one of two symmetric locations (indexed by
). Without loss of generality, each location is assumed to contain a continuum of young agents with unit mass. In each location, an individual firm produces a perishable consumption good
by employing physical capital
, labour
and a publicly-provided intermediate input
. Formally, the production function is as follows:
where
is a technology parameter,
is the elasticity of output with respect to capital and labour or productive government expenditure, respectively.
The firms’ unit of capital at time
is acquired out of forgoing a unit of the consumption good at time
t. Note that (1) is subject to constant returns to scale in
k and
n whereas there are increasing returns to scale in all the three inputs,
k,
n and
g. As in
Bencivenga and Smith (
1991,
1992), we assume that there are no retail markets for capital such that each firm uses only its own capital in production. Following
Barro (
1990), we assume that
g is non-rival and non-excludable and that each firm takes the level of
g as given while solving its own optimization problem. As such, (1) exhibits private diminishing returns. We also assume that except for the initial old, agents have no endowment of capital or consumption goods.
We assume that all young agents are ex ante identical and are endowed with one unit of labour which they supply inelastically in time
t and earn a real wage,
. They retire when old and only care about old-age consumption and as such they save all of the time
t wage income. We have that
is the age
i consumption of a representative agent of generation time
t such that the life-time utility is defined by a preference function of the form
As pointed out above, young agents are assigned to two symmetric locations (indexed by ) at each time period, t. At the beginning of each period, agents are completely separated by location and all transactions in goods, labour and assets are conducted in autarky within each location. The source of differences among young agents emanate from their locations ex post. In each of the two locations, a fraction of young agents are randomly relocated to the other location. The probability of relocation , is constant across periods, identically and independently distributed () across agents and is known to all agents.
The economy is populated by a finite number of banks that are regarded as being cooperative entities set up by an alliance of young-age consumers. By design, banks can exploit the law of large numbers whereas individuals cannot. Hence, if banks exist then all savings will be intermediated, as detailed in
Diamond and Dybvig (
1983). Banks accept deposits,
from young-age consumers at each time period
t and use them to acquire two primary assets available in the economy: fiat money,
, and capital,
. These two assets are created in order to maximize young-age consumers’ lifetime utility given by (2). Similar to the spatial separation form of OLG models of
Townsend (
1987),
Champ et al. (
1996),
Espinosa-Vega and Yip (
1996) and
Gupta (
2007), our model set-up implies that the stock of nominal money,
, is the only asset available to relocating young agents for consumption at the new location as they would have given up their claims on returns to their capital.
The government, which is assumed to be infinitely-lived and made up of only the inflation-targeting monetary wing for the sake of simplicity and without loss of generality, purchases units of consumption goods. Government expenditure is assumed to be a productive factor in the firms’ production function. Government’s productive consumption expenditure is wholly financed by seigniorage (inflation tax).
4. The Model with Compulsory Reserve Requirements
In this section, we subject banks to compulsory cash reserve requirements that are administered by the government. We follow
Bencivenga and Smith (
1992),
Espinosa-Vega and Yip (
1996) and
Gupta (
2007) in setting the obligatory reserve requirement as a cap on the portion of banks’ portfolio that can be held as capital. This implies that we restrict (9) to
, where
represents the obligatory reserve requirement.
In an environment with binding reserve requirements, banks are limited to set the fraction of their portfolio held as capital to
. In this set up, (13), which equates
to 1, may not hold. The implication of this is that banks will not be in a position to intermediate all the primary assets. The mandatory reserve requirements can be so severe to the extent that
. In that case, some investments would have to be financed internally. In the face of obligatory reserve requirements, the benchmark model resource constraints given by (7) and (8) change to
Even though banks are subjected to a repressive financial sector in the form of binding reserve requirements, from (13) and (17) we can establish the interval within which the government can facilitate that all agents be able to intermediate their entire savings through banks. Specifically, we can have if and only if .
In the case whereby banks are restricted to invest a fraction,
of their deposits into capital, the economy’s time
gross growth rate (
) is given by
We proceed to analyse the growth dynamics of the model with compulsory reserve requirements. According to (18), the economy’s growth dynamics are centred on the relationship between
and
, in that
. In this paper, we assume that the parameter values of
,
A,
, and
are such that the model will always produce steady-state(s).
2 There is a positive relationship between
and
in that an increase in
leads to an increase in the reserve-augmented seigniorage revenue for the government. This increases the ratio of real government expenditure to the real wage,
, and hence a higher gross growth rate,
emanating from higher government productive expenditure. The model’s possible growth path(s), including the position and equilibrium, is (are) dependent on the values of parameters
A,
,
and
, given
. The relationship between
and
can be inferred from the first derivative of
with respect to (w.r.t)
and is
According to (19),
. This confirms that (18) is an increasing function in that an increase in
is associated with an increase in
. The curvature of the gross growth path represented by (18) is dependent on the value of the parameter
. To show this, we proceed to compute the second derivative of
w.r.t
and is given by
From (20), the curvature of (18) is dependent on the value of
that can be derived from the last part of the right-hand-side of (20) in square-brackets, which is
. For values of
>
, (20) is negative, implying that the slope of the tangent line to (18) is decreasing as
increases. Next, for
<
, (20) is positive, thus the slope of the tangent line to (18) increases as
increases. Now the inflection point occurs when
=
, or alternatively at
=
. Given this,
Figure 1 plots the resultant growth path for
as a function of
. Note that, when
is equal one, i.e., zero net growth,
will be non-zero, with the positive vertical intercept of the
f locus being
.
As can be seen, the S-shaped growth path depicted in
Figure 1 produces multiple equilibria; three to be specific. The low and high-growth equilibria are stable under perfect foresight, since the
f loci intersects the 45 degree line from above, while the the medium-growth equilibrium is unstable, as the
f loci intersects the 45 degree line from below. Furthermore, although
is a state variable and cannot jump,
is not a state variable and, hence, can jump. This resultant jump then implies that there are infinitely many rational expectations paths to the low- and high-growth stable equilibria from any initial given value for
. Hence, the stable equilibria in this economy suffers from local indeterminacy, as there is still asymptotic convergence to the balanced growth path. It must be noted that, the equilibria at which the economy is likely to reside is conditional on
.
Finally note that depending on whether the level of the reserve requirement is
or
, there are two alternative gross growth rate paths for
:
and
We can show that for , or alternatively, for , we have . The other root of is obtained from or and , hence implausible.
4.1. The Model with Different Inflation Targets
Next we analyze the growth dynamics with binding reserve requirements and different inflation targets, focusing on the relationship between
and
as given by (18). The target inflation,
, determines the position of the gross growth path. Going by (18), the impact of increasing (lowering)
is to move the
gross growth curve up (down), which is understandable, given that seigniorage-financed government expenditure is productive. Formally, we infer the relationship between
and
from the first derivative of
w.r.t
and is
According to (23),
, and hence an increasing function of
. The resulting upward movement in the growth path following an increase in the inflation-target is illustrated in
Figure 2 below by the dashed curves.
3The policy implication of this result is that even if seigniorage-financed government expenditure is productively used, an increase in the inflation-target might not yield growth-enhancing effects, with the outcome being conditional on the threshold value of , i.e., . If , i.e., the elasticity of per capita output w.r.t per capita stock falls below the threshold, a higher inflation-target will not increase growth at the medium-growth equilibrium. Put differently, too much weight on productive public input (i.e., higher value of ) at the cost of private capital, could in fact reduce growth, given that in the presence of indeterminacy in the model, the high-growth stable equilibrium is not necessarily an obvious choice made by the agents in the economy. In other words, increasing the inflation target to segenerate more seigniorage-based revenue to be used productively, is not necessarily a growth-enhancing policy decision, and depends crucially on the elasticity of per capita output w.r.t per capita stock. Naturally, policymakers need to have a precise estimates for the elasticity parameters of the production function.
4.2. The Model with an Unofficial Financial Market (UFM)
Most developing economies’ financial markets are largely shallow, not organized and characterized by active and competitive UFMs, as discussed in
Gupta (
2008,
2009),
Goswami and Gupta (
2009).
4 These UFMs play a greater financial intermediation role in developing economies, compared to the official banking system. This is so since UFMs are not subjected to reserve requirement policies. In cases where banks are subjected to stringent reserve requirement policies, then only a part of the capital formation is done through the official banking system, i.e., we have
, indicating high reserve requirements, in particular, whenever
. When reserve requirements are very high, young agents will only save
with banks and the remaining in the UFM. This can be considered a rational decision considering that UFMs are free of any reserve requirements. Given that UFMs exist in developing economies, we analyse the growth dynamics in this context. Using (9) and (13), we have
where
. In the presence of UFMs, the size of investment in physical capital stock is given by
The first term on the right-hand-side of the expression represents the size of the self-financed capital investment while the second term gives the investment by financial intermediaries. Using (3), (11), (24) and (25) and the fact that only market equilibrium and government budget constraint hold, we can derive the expression for the gross rate of growth as follows:
Comparing with (18) when no UFM exists, the economy’s growth path with a UFM will yield similar growth dynamics. In other words, our theoretical results tend to carry over, and are robust to whether we are analyzing a developed inflation targeting economy or an underdeveloped one, with the latter characterized by UFM.