We are interested in estimating the effects of trade policy agreements, and their scope, on the level of bilateral GVC trade. Our point of departure for estimating these effects is a structural gravity equation with fixed effects. Gravity equations are premised on the idea that bilateral trade flows are related to the economic size of the two trading partners, and inversely related to trade barriers between them—usually proxied by distance. Structural gravity models qualify this view by introducing the idea of multilateral resistance. In structural gravity models, bilateral trade flows do depend on bilateral trade costs, but only relative to the average barrier of the two regions to trade with all their partners—their multilateral resistance—rather than to absolute trade barriers (
Anderson and van Wincoop 2003;
Baier and Bergstrand 2007). Our baseline estimating equation is
where
GVCtrade is a measure of GVC mediated value-added trade (or trade in intermediates) between country
i and
j at time
t, and
PTAscope captures the scope of trade policy cooperation between the two countries. These variables are described further below. The terms
αij,
αit, and
αjt represent country-pair, exporter-time, and importer-time fixed effects, respectively. These three terms control for potential endogeneity of the PTA variable. Self-selection into PTAs provides one source of endogeneity (
Baier and Bergstrand 2007), with country-pairs with existing large bilateral trade flows more likely to join in a PTA. In addition, the latter two terms control for multilateral resistance, that is, the observation that bilateral trade costs depend on bilateral barriers to trade and also on trade costs across all possible export and import destinations.
The use of fixed effects in structural gravity equations also addresses concerns raised by recent work on the gravity model which suggests that, in a context of value-added rather than gross trade, the mass variables risk being incorrectly specified (
Baldwin and Taglioni 2011). The gravity model typically employs the GDPs of destination and origin countries to proxy for, respectively, import demand and supply capacity. With the rise of intermediate trade, however, these proxies no longer fully reflect economic reality: a country’s demand for parts and components increasingly derives from its gross production rather than from its value-added in production. Using GDP as a proxy for economic mass is therefore more appropriate in a world where consumer goods trade dominates. To the extent that structural gravity models use fixed effects to control for the mass variables, however, these considerations need not apply (
Baldwin and Taglioni 2011).
We are particularly interested in two dimensions of the relationship between PTAs and GVC trade. First, we aim to understand whether there are differences in the sensitivity to increases in the scope of trade policy cooperation when we isolate trade flows that involve production sharing across borders (and that are therefore associated with GVCs) from ‘all’ trade flows. Second, we are interested in estimating the relative impact of different dimensions of PTA breadth on GVC trade. In
Section 3, we start by estimating our baseline model using data on ‘all’ trade and on GVC trade, respectively, as dependent variables, and compare the results. We then extend our model by disaggregating our PTA variables along different dimensions, and by including interaction terms to capture differences in the effect of PTAs across income groups.
3.1. Measuring the Scope of Trade Policy Cooperation
To measure the scope of trade policy cooperation, we build on a novel World Bank database covering the PTAs currently in force and notified to the World Trade Organization (WTO) up to the end of 2015 (
Hofmann et al. 2017). As a first measure, we use the count of legally enforceable provisions that are included in an agreement, as reported in the World Bank database. We define this as
Total breadthijt =
. As a second measure of breadth, we use the count of ‘core’ provisions, applying both at and behind the border, defined as
Core breadthijt =
. This is the approach employed by both
Falvey and Foster-McGregor (
2018,
2019) and
Laget et al. (
2018). Following these studies, we also implement a principal component analysis (PCA) to define an additional measure of breadth. This can be thought of as a weighted average of provisions, with the loadings associated to each variable of the first component as weights. We define this variable as
PCA depthijt =
, where
ωk represents the weights.
1Table 1 provides summary statistics for our variables capturing the scope of trade policy cooperation between countries. The summary statistics below refer only to the sub-sample of country pairs that do have a PTA in force. Of the total and ‘core’ number of provisions which are typically included in a PTA, the average trade agreement in our database contains, respectively, 23 and 12 provisions. More generally, it appears that on average it is more likely for PTAs to include a higher number of ‘core’ and WTO+ provisions than ‘non-core’ and WTO-X provisions. The same applies to provisions applying at the border, relative to provisions applying behind the border. The broadest PTA in our data contains a total of 48 provisions.
Table 1 also reports information on the geographical coverage of PTAs in our dataset. Approximately 68% of trade agreements in our data have been signed between country pairs or groups of countries belonging to the same region.
2 The remaining 32% of PTAs regulate trade between country pairs belonging to different regions. Additionally, it is worth noting that over half of the agreements in our data are between developing economies. PTAs between countries in the global North account for a little over 30% of agreements in our data, while those between industrialised and developing economies constitute around 18 percent of the total.
There are significant differences between these different types of PTAs in terms of breadth.
Table 2 above provides summary statistics for our core breadth variable across the different categories of PTAs in our data. Trade agreements signed between industrialised economies tend to be broader, on average, than PTAs involving developing economies.
3 The average north–north PTA contains 15 provisions, whereas a PTA between developing economies includes, on average, approximately 11 provisions. A similar pattern emerges with regard to trade agreements between partners belonging to different regions. Relative to intra-regional PTAs, inter-regional agreements include, on average, a larger number of provisions.
Section 3 investigates some of these differences empirically.
3.2. Measuring GVC Trade
We use data from different sources to measure bilateral GVC trade. We first use the EORA multiregional input-output (MRIO) tables to gather data on gross final exports and on the export of intermediates. Since intermediate exports are closely associated with trade in GVCs (
Johnson and Noguera 2012), we take this as a first indicator of GVC trade flows. We then construct two value-added measures of GVC trade, building upon the work of
Koopman et al. (
2014). The first is domestic value-added embodied in the final demand of a country’s trade partners, or
DVX. This measures the exports of intermediates that are used as inputs in the production of final goods by other countries, and thus captures the extent of a country’s forward participation in GVCs. The second is foreign value added embodied in a country’s own final demand (
FVA). Since this term captures imported intermediates that are then used to produce final goods domestically, it is a measure of backward GVC participation. In what follows, we describe the construction of these measures in further detail.
The calculation of foreign value added in trade requires an MRIO table, which builds on national input–output tables by breaking down the use of products by origin. The rows in an MRIO table indicate the use of gross output from a particular industry in a particular country and comprise two main components. The first is intermediate use, which provides information on intermediate use by both domestic industries and industries in other countries. The second is information on final demand, which is again split between demand for final goods from both domestic and foreign sources. The columns of the MRIO table provide information on the amounts of intermediates needed for the production of gross output. The column sum thus gives the sum of the domestic and foreign production of intermediates that are used in the production of output in a particular industry and country. Combining this sum with the sum of value added generated in each industry and country gives the value of gross output. The information given by an MRIO table can be translated into a standard input–output matrix form by stacking all industries and countries, such that we have (
) rows and columns, with
being the number of countries and
the number of industries. Gross output can then be expressed as
with
being gross output,
intermediate demand,
final demand,
the identity matrix,
the technological coefficient matrix (i.e., the ratio of intermediate use to gross output by intermediate) and
the Leontief inverse. Our indicators of trade in value added can then be calculated as
with
an
(diagonalized) row vector giving the value added per unit of output for each industry in country
,
the
Leontief inverse for country
, and
the
(diagonalized) row vector of final demand for each industry in country
. The first column of the trade-in value-added matrix describes the value added contained in the final demand of country 1 and can be split into a domestic and foreign component. The term
gives the domestic value-added content of final demand. The term
(
) gives the foreign value-added content of final demand of country 1 generated by country
, which provides a bilateral variable capturing backward GVC participation. An analogous interpretation holds for all other columns.
The trade-in value-added matrix can also be used to obtain information on the domestic value added that enters as an intermediate input in the final demand of other countries. This is found by looking at the rows (rather than the columns) of the matrix. The term for example, which can be written as , indicates the value of country 2’s finale demand that depends on value added from country 1, which can be used as a bilateral indicator of forward GVC participation.
Our variables of interest—the presence and the horizontal depth of a preferential trade agreement between two countries—are the same for any given pair of country i and country j, because if country i has signed a PTA with country j, the reverse is also true. Since our value-added indicators of GVC participation are extracted from the same input–output matrix of cross-country intermediate flows, the results from estimating a regression model with either DVX or FVA as the dependent variable would be identical for country i and country j. To overcome this issue, in our analysis, we construct an aggregate variable by taking the sum of these two indicators: GV C trade = DVX + FVA. This allows us to capture the level of GVC trade at the bilateral level in a way that is as complete as possible, as it includes both backward and forward GVC participation.
The EORA input–output tables have the distinct advantage of offering very wide country coverage when compared with other input-output databases: our sample includes 189 economies over the 1990–2015 period. EORA also has an important disadvantage, however. Data for countries where national input–output tables are not available are imputed from countries with similar economic characteristics. Moreover, EORA data only allows for a distinction between final and intermediate flows—not between different types of intermediates. We therefore complement EORA data with mirror data from UN-COMTRADE. We construct mirror flows by using imports into the partner country to measure exports from the reporter. When the mirror flow is not available, we use the raw export data instead. To proxy for GVC trade, we start by focusing on trade in intermediates. We then identify those trade flows involving parts and components. These are categories 42 and 53 of the broad economic classification (BEC).
Table 3 reports summary statistics on our GVC variables.