Next Article in Journal
Publisher’s Note – Received Date Error, Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2009, 6, 3105-3114
Next Article in Special Issue
What is Learned from Longitudinal Studies of Advertising and Youth Drinking and Smoking? A Critical Assessment
Previous Article in Journal
Quality Health Care in the European Union Thanks to Competition Law
Previous Article in Special Issue
Health Economic Assessment: A Methodological Primer
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

The Selection of an Appropriate Count Data Model for Modelling Health Insurance and Health Care Demand: Case of Indonesia

1
Faculty of Public Health, the University of Indonesia, Kampus FKM UI, Building F 1th Floor, Depok 16424, Indonesia
2
Poverty Reduction and Economic Management, the World Bank Office Jakarta, Jakarta Stock Exchange Building Tower 2, 12th Floor, Jl. Jend. Sudirman Kav. 52-53, Jakarta 12190, Indonesia
3
Health Economics Research Group, Brunel University, Uxbridge, Middlesex, UB8 3PH, UK
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2010, 7(1), 9-27; https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph7010009
Submission received: 30 November 2009 / Accepted: 20 December 2009 / Published: 29 December 2009
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Health Economics)

Abstract

:
We apply several estimators to Indonesian household data to estimate the relationship between health insurance and the number of outpatient visits to public and private providers. Once endogeneity of insurance is taken into account, there is a 63 percent increase in the average number of public visits by the beneficiaries of mandatory insurance for civil servants. Individuals’ decisions to make first contact with private providers is affected by private insurance membership. However, insurance status does not make any difference for the number of future outpatient visits.

Graphical Abstract

1. Introduction

Count data models have been widely used to estimate the predictors of health care demand [17]. Most analyses use household surveys collecting information about health care provider types and number of visits made to different types of providers during the recall period. An important issue to be considered in estimating the effects of health insurance on the demand for health care in these settings is therefore to establish whether the demand variable is generated as a discrete and mutually exclusive choice (e.g., types of providers visited in the event of an illness) or is in the form of a count or rate (e.g., number of visits made to a particular provider). The latter is usually modeled using count data models and their variants [8].
In estimating health care demand, complexities arise because the underlying behaviors driving health care utilization may have implications for the choice of the most appropriate model [7]. Further, as people demand both health insurance and health care depending on their health status, whether the model suffers from bias (due to endogeneity of the choice of insurance status and demand) should be scrutinized [9,10]. Deciding on a particular model appropriate for estimating health care demand is a difficult process that is often poorly documented in the health economics literature. The purpose of this paper is to document the complete process by which we developed guidelines for the selection of an appropriate count data model for health insurance and health care demand and to choose a particular count data model in estimating the number of outpatient visits.
In practice we will estimate the relationship between health insurance and the number of outpatient visits to public and private health care providers in Indonesia. There are previously published studies on health insurance and health care demand [911]; Indonesia deserves special attention as it is a developing country committed to universal coverage through a national health insurance program (NHIP). This article provides evidence on whether such a policy would be welfare-enhancing in terms of increasing access to formal health care in Indonesia.
This study also confronts directly the statistical tradeoffs associated with correcting for endogenous regressors (i.e., correcting for endogeneity when it is absent results in larger standard errors, loss of precision [10], and efficiency [12]). We explore two classes of count data models. The first class is characterized by a primary equation with a discrete dependent variable. This class includes standard count data models such as restricted Poisson, negative binomial zero-inflated, and hurdle models. The second class extends the features of the first class to accommodate endogenous regressors, including instrumental variables [12,13] and generalized method of moments [14] techniques.

2. Health Insurance Context and Potential Source of Endogeneity

Table 1 provides summary characteristics of health insurance schemes. The Indonesian government has mandated health insurance for civil servants (Askes) since 1968. This scheme covers all civil servants, civil servant and armed forces pensioners, and their families and survivors. Civil servants and pensioners are automatically enrolled in this scheme. Eligible dependents include spouse and the first two children, with the cut-off age for dependent children depending on education status. The contribution is 4 percent of basic salary shared equally by employees and the government as employer. The scheme, managed by a state-owned company (PT Askes), covers about 14 million beneficiaries. Since Askes is compulsory, people may choose civil service employment based on their health status. Therefore, endogeneity of insurance status and health care demand may arise for those with less favourable health status who choose civil service employment with compulsory health care insurance benefits. Similarly, healthier workers may be more likely to choose self-employment or smaller private firms to avoid mandatory health insurance premiums.
In 1992, the government passed a Social Security Act (SSA) mandating enrolment of private employees in either privately-provided insurance schemes or the government-provided Jamsostek insurance scheme (which includes provident funds, death benefits, and worker’s compensation in addition to health benefits). SSA regulations stipulate that private employers with total salary costs of more than 1 million Rupiah per month (roughly $100 at current exchange rates) are required to enroll their employees and dependents in qualified health insurance plans managed by PT Jamsostek. However, the health benefit as required by the SSA is compulsory but optional, that is employers who have a better scheme than the one covered by Jamsostek may opt out to this scheme. This policy makes this scheme covers only 3 million workers out of about approximately 100 million workers who are eligible [15]. Jamsostek covers spouses and up to three dependent children less than 21 years of age with benefits include outpatient and inpatient care at both public and public health care providers. Premiums, which are capped at 3percent of basic salary for unmarried and 6percent for married employees, are paid solely by employers so Jamsostek is non-contributory. This policy may lead employers to choose Jamsostek for their low income employees with health problems while healthier employees with higher incomes will opt out. Thus, it is likely that endogeneity is an issue for Jamsostek membership as well.
The government also enacted the Insurance Act in 1992 which allows private insurance firms to sell health insurance products. These schemes usually offer both public and private health providers in their provider networks. The consensus estimate of the number of people with private health insurance is 5 million [15]. The health insurance literature has documented selection bias in private insurance demand; therefore one should suspect endogeneity of insurance status while estimating health care demand given private insurance [10].
Even given public policy and this menu of insurance opportunities, in 2004 only a small fraction of the Indonesian population (<15 percent) was covered by any health insurance. Motivated largely by the expectation that health insurance improves access to health care, the president signed a National Social Security Law in 2004 which will used as a basis for introducing an NHIP in the country.

3. Methodology

3.1. Model Specifications

This study estimates the relationship between insurance status and the demand for health care. The variable capturing demand is the number of outpatient visits during the four weeks prior to a household interview. The discreteness and non-negativity of this variable call for count data modeling [58]. Furthermore, health insurance status may be codetermined in our non-experimental dataset [10], so we utilize models that accommodate possible endogeneity of the insurance choice.
The number of outpatient visits for an individual (Mi) is posited to be exponential function of health insurance (Ii), exogenous variables (xi), and a random error (u1i):
M i = exp ( I i α + x i β ) + u 1 i
where Mi represents the number of visits made; Ii is an individual’s health insurance attributes; xi represents a vector of health, socio-economic and demographic characteristics; and u1i captures variation in an individual’s unobserved characteristics as well as random error. The exponential function ensures non-negative integers.
Maximum likelihood (ML) estimation of Equation (1) yields consistent and efficient estimations when regressors Ii and xi are exogenous. If health insurance status is codetermined with demand Mi, outpatient visits and insurance status can be modeled with simultaneous equations [911]. Continuing from expression (1), an individual’s demand for insurance is modeled as follows:
I i * = γ z i + x i β + u 2 i
where I i * represents an individual’s inclination to have insurance; z is a row vector of observable determinants that influence insurance status but not number of visits (uncorrelated with u1); xi is defined as in Equation (1); and u2i is again random error also capturing unobservable insurance determinants. I i * (an indivdual’s propensity to choose insurance) is not observed; instead we observe the categorical insurance status variable Ii.
Equation (1) is the demand equation, and the reduced form Equation (2) for the suspected endogenous variable is the insurance equation. Bias in Equation (1) may arise if important unobserved determinants of insurance status Ii are correlated with the random error (u1) of the demand equation. For example, those who are less healthy may have a higher than average propensity to seek insurance as well as a higher than average propensity to seek care given illness. It is likely that unobservable factors influencing demand are positively correlated with the error term u1 which would mean u1 and u2 are correlated. This would imply correlation between insurance status I and the error term u1. In maximum likelihood estimation, correlation between I and u1 (E(u1|x) ≠ 0) will result in a biased estimate of α in (1), the demand equation [911].

3.2. Econometrics Approaches

The dependent variable takes only non-negative integer values, and thus the family of count data models provides appropriate estimation techniques [6,8]. Poisson specifications, in which the mean of the data distribution is assumed to equal the variance, are too restrictive: it has been found in most health economics applications that the variance of the data exceeds the mean (overdispersion), the data contains a large number of zeros (see [4,5,16]), and there is a long right tail. For such data, Poisson regressions provide consistent estimates of the coefficients but not of their standard errors.
A variant of the Poisson is the negative binomial (NB) model [2]. However, with a large proportion of zeros, both Poisson and NB predictions exceed typical predictions of such models in the absence of zero values. Two common solutions accommodate excess zeros [17]. First is the zero-inflated variant of either Poisson (ZIP) or negative binomial (ZINB) distributions. The second variant is called a hurdle model, also known as a two-part model. In hurdle specifications, the first part is a binary outcome model and the second part is a truncated count data model. This study explores both ZINB and hurdle models. For the latter, we use a logit model to estimate the probability that the individual visits an OP provider (part one) and a truncated-at-zero NB model to estimate the number of visits (part two).
Following Deb and Trivedi [4], the first part of the two-part hurdle model is specified as:
P r h [ y i > 0 | x i ] = ( ψ h , i λ h , i + ψ h , i ) ψ h , i   and   P r h [ y i = 0 | x i ] = 1 ( ψ h , i λ h , i + ψ h , i ) ψ h , i
where yi indicates the number of visits; the λi is the conditional mean of the count, defined as λi = exp(xiβ)and the precision parameter ( ψ i 1) defined as ψ i = ( 1 / α ) λ i k with k as an arbitrary constant; the subscript h indicates parameters associated with the hurdle distribution.
The second part of the hurdle model is assumed to follow the density for a truncated negative binomial [4]:
f ( y i | x i , y i > 0 ) = Γ ( y i + ψ i ) Γ ( ψ i ) Γ ( y i + 1 ) [ ( λ i + ψ i ψ i ) ψ i 1 ] 1 ( λ i λ i + ψ i ) y i
where Γ(.) is the gamma distribution function. The parameters in the second stage were estimated using the sub-sample of observations with positive values of yi, denoted as:
P r h [ y i > 0 | x i ] = 1 ( ψ i λ i + ψ i ) ψ i
We use the above count data models to estimate Equation (1) with maximum likelihood techniques. In anticipation that we might have misspecified the true (but unknown) population density, we choose robust standard error procedures.
However, maximum likelihood yields consistent estimates only if regressors are exogenous. Here we suspect the regressors to be endogenous, so we consider both linear instrumental variables (IV) and generalized method of moments (GMM) estimators for both Equations (1) and (2) simultaneously. IV and GMM allow consistent parameter estimates when unobserved heterogeneity is correlated with regressors. One downside of IV is that standard errors are inconsistent in the presence of unknown heteroskedasticity, yielding invalid inference. GMM estimators using orthogonality conditions to allow for efficient estimation in the presence of heteroskedasticity of unknown form do not share this weakness. Windmeijer and Silva [14] provides a useful overview of the theoretical basis of the GMM. Mullahy [13] uses non-linear IV (or GMM) in a model of cigarette smoking behaviour.

3.3. Specifications Test

We carry out several tests in order to evaluate the overall specification of the model. Figure 1 illustrates our operational framework by summarizing what we check and what we do when assumptions are not met. It shows three main steps for choosing the most appropriate econometric technique among the six alternatives explored in this study.
The first step is testing endogeneity assumptions. To test the endogeneity of insurance status, Hausman specification tests (Wu-Hausman and Durbin-Wu-Hausman, or DWH) were carried out for each regression. In our case, this test can be interpreted as summarizing the consequences of employing different estimation methods on the same equation, not as a test for the endogeneity of regressors per se. If there is significant difference between coefficients from ML and GMM or IV, the null hypothesis of exogeneity can be rejected, suggesting either IV or GMM is necessary. Given that IV-estimated standard errors are inconsistent in the presence of unknown heteroskedasticity, we carry out various flavors of Pagan and Hall's test for heteroskedasticity [18] in step 2a. These tests are used to inform the choice between linear IV and GMM estimators; rejecting the null hypothesis of homoskedasticity suggests that GMM is preferable to IV.
Unfortunately, the consistency of the endogeneity test as well as coefficient estimates of IV and GMM depend on the validity of the instruments z in the insurance Equation (2). The z refer to the variables that have an impact, both theoretically and conceptually, on the suspected endogenous variable (insurance status) but that do not otherwise affect the demand for health care (M). Identification of the effect of insurance status on health care demand will be achieved if the z are uncorrelated with the structural error but correlated with the endogenous regressors, i.e., health insurance variable. If the instruments are only weakly related to the endogenous variable “the resulting parameter estimates will be biased toward standard models even if the instruments are not correlated with the error term of the demand equation” [19,20].
To evaluate whether potential instruments are weak and whether the instruments are orthogonal to the error process, several tests were employed. First, the relevance of the instruments (to suspected endogenous variables) was assessed by evaluating the R2 value and the F-test for the joint significance of the instruments in the first-stage regressions. The first-stage regressions are reduced-form regressions of the endogenous variables on the full set of instruments and other exogenous regressors. As our models have two suspected endogenous variables, relying only on R2 and F statistics may not be enough to detect the relevance of the instruments. We therefore used a Shea partial R2 measure, which takes into account correlations among the instruments [21,22]. The smaller the value of the partial R2, the more inconsistent the IV estimates will be whenever the instruments are not perfectly exogenous. Even when the instruments are exogenous, a small value of the partial R2 will mean increased asymptotic standard errors and therefore reduction in the power of the F-test.
Second, the validity of the instruments was tested by an over-identification test [14]. Hansen's J-statistic and the Sargan statistic were used for GMM and IV respectively [22]. The former test is distributed as χ2 in the number of overidentifying restrictions. The Sargan statistic is distributed as χ2 with the degrees of freedom calculated as N*R2 from a regression of IV residuals on the full set of instruments. The joint null hypothesis of both Hansen and Sargan tests are that the excluded instruments are valid instruments (i.e., uncorrelated with the error terms), and that they are correctly excluded from the estimated equation.
Finally, to satisfy an orthogonal requirement of the instruments, i.e., the z should be exogenous, we tested a subset of instruments using the C-statistic [22] that allow us to test a subset of the original set for exogeneity conditions. In the case of IV, this C-statistic was computed as the difference between two Sargan statistics, whilst for efficient GMM, it was computed as the difference between two J-statistics). The C-test, distributed χ2 with degrees of freedom equal to the loss of overidentifying restrictions, has the null hypothesis that the specified variables are proper instruments.
When null hypotheses of exogenous regressors were not rejected, we used count data models that ignore endogeneity. A number of approaches were employed to select a specification that could appropriately accommodate overdispersion and excess zeros. First, to discriminate between Poisson and NB, we used a regression based approach [2] to calculate a likelihood ratio (LR) statistic as well as two traditional selection criteria based on the penalized log-likelihood, the Akaike Information Criteria (AIC) and Bayesian Information Criteria (BIC). Second, we tested the excess-zero assumption. A Vuong test was used to discriminate between the standard NB and ZINB models. The Vuong test has a standard normal distribution with large positive values favoring the ZINB model and large negative values favoring the NB model [23]. To discriminate between the HNB model and restricted NB model, following Gerdtham [24] we applied the likelihood ratio (LR) test defined as: λ = 2(lnLlogit + lnLtruncNB − lnLNB). Both AIC and BIC measures were again utilized; models yielding the smallest values of the AIC and BIC are preferred [7,16].

4. Data and Variables

The data for this study come from the second round of the Indonesian Family Life Survey (IFLS2) carried out by the RAND Corporation. The first round of survey (IFLS1) included interviews with 22,347 individuals from 7,224 households. The IFLS2 re-contacted the same households and succeeded in re-interviewing 93.5percent of IFLS1 households (6751 households with over 33,000 individuals). An overview of the survey is described in [25] for IFLS1 and [26] for IFLS2.
This study considers two mutually exclusive measures of OP visits: public and private providers. Not all insurance schemes offer health care services from both public and private providers and sample distributions of these variables (presented in Table 2) show that approximately 85 percent of IFLS individuals had zero visits to public OP and about 92 percent had zero private OP visits. The sample means for the number of visits to public and private OP were 0.28 and 0.15 respectively while the sample variances were 0.67 and 0.43 respectively. The ratio between the sample variance and the sample mean for the number to public and private OP visits were 2.39 and 2.87, respectively. These averages indicate the observed data is over-dispersed.
Two insurance variables, Askes and Private, enter demand Equation (1) as dummy variables. Askes represents mandatory insurance for civil servants and entitles beneficiaries to comprehensive health care from public providers only. Private represents both Jamsostek (insurance for private employees) and private insurance schemes and therefore may be entitling beneficiaries to care from both public and private providers. Since the effects of health insurance on health care demand might differ across income groups, an interaction term for insurance and income was included in the demand model. This interaction allows one to test whether income has different effects of insurance on the number of outpatient visits.
In demand Equation (1), the health-status vector consisted of dummy variables indicating the presence of symptoms, self-assessed general health (GHS) and severity of illness. A score assessing physical ability in the performance of daily activities (ADLs) was also included (with higher scores indicating worse ability). The vector of demographic variables consisted of age (years), gender (1/0), marital status (1/0), dummies for education, income (log natural), electricity usage (1/0), and the natural log of one-way travel time and travel cost to health facilities. To control for regional differences we used dummy variables for urban and seven regions (rural and Jakarta serving as the reference groups). Summary statistics for the variables used in the demand Equation (1) are presented in Table 3.
The endogeneity test as well as IV and GMM estimators can only be applied if one finds appropriate instruments. We propose candidate instrumental variables z that may satisfy two requirements [14]: they should be correlated with the endogenous variable(s) and they should be orthogonal to the error process. The proposed z are presented in Appendix A.
We estimated reduced form regressions of the endogenous variables on the full set of instruments (Equation (2)) using a probit model. The main objective was to generate the predicted values of insurance to be included as an additional instrument in IV and GMM techniques. The basic conclusion was that the insurance decision was more determined by income, education, age and location variables. All the proposed instruments in Appendix A except household head’s employment type had a positive correlation with choice of Askes insurance (p-value < 0.01). For Private insurance, only four of the proposed instruments (household head’s employment type, spouse, if active in community meetings and if housing occupied) had significant positive correlations. R2 reveals that the covariates in the Askes insurance estimates explained 30 percent of the overall variation, but only 20 percent of Private insurance variation. The joint Wald statistics shows all covariates were jointly significant in either insurance equation at the one percent level. After trying different specifications, we have selected from the proposed z two different subsets as final instruments for the Askes and Private equations (see Appendix A). These subsets of z were included in the estimation of insurance model (Equation (2)) but excluded from the demand model (Equation (1)).

5. Results

5.1. Model Selections

5.1.1. Public outpatient visits

For public OP visits, the endogeneity test was rejected at 1 percent level (Table 4), suggesting that the ML estimators of standard count data model would result in inconsistent parameter estimates. Therefore, a further consideration was to select either IV or GMM estimator. The Pagan and Hall's test in GMM-estimates (χ2(40) = 1140.59) and in IV-estimate (χ2(40) = 1147.01) rejected the null hypothesis of homoskedasticity at 1 percent level. This result suggests that GMM estimator is preferable to model the number of public OP visits.
An appropriate set of instruments are prerequisites to employ the endogeneity test as well as to estimate a model using IV and GMM estimators. A number of tests were therefore employed to test the relevancy, validity and orthogonality requirements of the instruments. Table 5 provides summary statistics used in testing the relevance of the instruments. The R2 shows that the models explained a high proportion of the variation for Askes and Private insurance in both public and private OP visits. Note however that if an estimated equation yields a large value of the Partial R2 and a small value of the Shea measure, one may conclude that the instruments lack sufficient relevance to explain all the endogenous regressors and the model may be essentially unidentified [19]. In our case, the values of Partial R2 and Shea partial R2 were similar for both Askes and Private insurance, indicating that our model is well identified.
The relevance of the instruments was also investigated using the F-test to determine whether the instruments were correlated with the potentially endogenous variable [19]. The null hypothesis of the F-test that the parameters of the covariates are jointly equal to zero was rejected in both insurance types, indicating that all the instruments were jointly significant in the insurance choice equation. A conservative rule of thumb for a single endogenous regressor would suggest that a less than 10 F-value could be an indicator of a weak instrument [19].
The validity of the instruments was performed by applying a standard test for the over-identifying restrictions. We could not reject the null hypothesis of correct specification in public outpatient visits. The value of the Hansen's J-statistic (GMM-estimates) and Sargan's statistic (IV-estimates) tests was 1.921 (p-value = 0.383) and 1.846 (p-value = 0.397), respectively. This suggested that the models are reasonably well specified and the instruments are valid.
The orthogonality condition of the instruments was assessed using the C-statistic. The value of the test was 0.224 with p-value = 0.636, suggesting that the instruments used are exogenous. All empirical evidence described above led us to conclude that the selected instruments were appropriate enough to run the demand models.

5.1.2. Private outpatient visits

For private OP visits, we could not reject the exogeneity hypothesis (p-value = 0.585). Therefore, we considered the ML estimators for standard count data models. Table 6 presents model selection criteria applied to choose the most appropriate econometric technique. We first used the results of over-dispersion measures (LR, AIC and BIC) to discriminate between the Poisson and NB models. The estimated over-dispersion parameter calculated from the NB was positive, α = 7.07, indicating the presence of over-dispersion. This is also corroborated by the results of the LR test −311.28 [2 × (1203.21 − 1047.57)]. As this was significant at 1 percent level, the Poisson was rejected in favor of the NB. Both AIC and BIC values also favored the NB. However, the NB ignores the existence of excess zeroes (non-users), which in private OP visits account for 92 percent (Table 2), and also treats users and non-users identically. This motivated us to consider further specifications in the regime of models that take into account excess-zeros. Possible alternatives were either ZINB or HNB.
In order to select whether NB or ZINB could be used, the Vuong test was employed. The result shows that the test was highly significant in favor of the ZINB. However, there were very large standard errors of the coefficients in the ‘inflation’ equation. This implied a definite lack of fit in case of the ZINB (results from the inflated equation are not presented here but are available from the first author).
Another option to model excess-zeros is to apply HNB. We based the comparison of this specification on the LR test and AIC values. The resulting LR test statistic χ2(29) for the NB model against the HNB model was 70.18 {2 × [1,047.57 − (866.94 + 145.54)]}, and was significant at 1 percent level, indicating that the HNB model could be justified well. This was also supported by the AIC, i.e., this model had the smallest value of AIC among the four standard count data models. Finally, we tested the truncated Poisson model against the truncated NB model. The resulting LR statistic χ2(1) was 8966.5 and was significant at 1 percent level, indicating that the truncated Poisson model must be rejected against the truncated NB model. The LR test does not appear in Figure 1 since we did not explore the truncated Poisson model. The test provides an additional justification on the use of HNB.

5.2. Model Estimation Results

Putting together all of the above evidence, we concluded that the HNB specification is preferable to estimate the number of private OP visits. We describe below the results obtained from GMM estimation for public OP visits and HNB for private OP visits.

5.2.1. Number of public outpatient visits

The first column of Table 7 presents the results from GMM estimation of the number of public OP visits. Given that the equation for the number of visits is non-linear, there is a slightly different interpretation for dummy- and continuous-variable coefficients. For coefficients on the Askes dummy variable, as E[Mi] = exp(Iiα+xiβ), then E [ M i | I i = 1 ] E [ M i | I i = 0 ] = exp ( a ) 1 + α. For α small enough, it can be interpreted as the proportionate increase in the mean of the visits owing to the Askes insurance effect [2]. Since α is 0.63, then on average individuals with Askes coverage would have approximately 63 percent more visits to public outpatient care. For continuous variables such as age, ADL scores, and family size, the relation that holds is [27]: d M i d x i k x i k M i = β k x i k, so the elasticity of Mi with respect to xik is linear in coefficient βk.
Coefficients on insurance dummies (Askes and Private) are positive for both schemes but significant only for Askes (one percent level). The coefficients on interaction terms between insurance status and income are not significantly different from zero, suggesting such interactions are not important for predicting health care demand. All health status measures have important effects on public OP demand and the effects are statistically significant (p-value < 0.01). Individuals who were suffering from symptoms, had higher ADL scores, and were seriously ill are more likely to have public OP visits. Relative to very good health, individuals with self-rated good and poor health are likely to have more visits. The effect of poor health is larger than the corresponding effect of good health (36 percent vs. 5 percent).
Women are 11 percent more likely to have more visits to public OP than men. Being married increased the average number of visits by five percent. With the exception of elementary school, the estimated effect of education is significantly negative. This indicates that higher levels of education lead to a reduction in the number of visits to public OP care (holding health status and all other covariates constant). Income elasticity for public visits was 0.03 (p-value < 0.01). Having electricity in the household leads to increases in public OP visits by about 11 percent (p-value < 0.01). The coefficients on log travel cost and time were positive but significant only in the case of the latter (p-value < 0.05). Urban dwellers are likely to have 11 percent fewer visits to public OP than rural residents. Jakarta’s inhabitants were likely to have a significantly lower average number of public OP visits than individuals who live in Bali, West Nusa Tenggara or Kalimantan.

5.2.2. Number of private outpatient visits

The results from HNB estimation of private OP visits are presented in the second column of Table 7. The first-part estimate (binary logit) represents contact decisions while the second-part estimate (truncated-NB) represents the frequency decision. The estimated effect of the dummy for Askes is negative in both decision stages while for Private the coefficient is positive in both decision stages but only significant in the contact decision (p-value < 0.01). Negative coefficients on the interaction term between private insurance and income in first-part estimates imply that the probability of private OP visits, with other covariates held constant, is greater among low income groups.
With regard to health status, gender, household size, income, electricity, travel cost and time, and age, coefficients are similar to those in the public OP demand regressions described above. For example, the estimated effects of all health status measures were significantly positive in the first-part (contact decision) suggesting that individuals with a lower health status have a higher probability of visiting private OP providers.
The estimated effects of the four education dummies (elementary, junior, senior and high) were all positive and significant at 1 percent level in the contact decision. Living in an urban area increased the probability to visit a private OP by 25 percent and the frequency of private OP visits by 28 percent. East Java residents were more likely to contact private OP (36 percent) and make more subsequent visits (55 percent) compared to Jakarta inhabitants.

6. Discussion

This study has estimated the relationship between health insurance and the number of public and private outpatient visits in Indonesia. We have explored two econometric classes of count data models: a specification that ignores endogeneity of insurance choice and a specification that considers endogeneity of insurance choice. Although both IV and GMM estimators allow for controlling endogeneity of the insurance in the estimation [13,14], they are generally less efficient than the ML estimation of standard count data [12]. Hence, there was a trade-off between loss of precision and having biased parameter estimates [10]. Since arriving at the choice of most appropriate econometric technique is often a difficult process but not often documented in the literature in great detail, in this paper we have described criteria that helped us select most appropriate econometric technique.
We observed evidence for endogeneity (of insurance status) in the number of public OP visits. This led us to conclude that the GMM estimator is the best to model the number of public outpatient visits. Comparison of estimation results obtained from all econometric techniques explored in the study (complete results available upon request) reveals that the parameter estimates for the Askes insurance after controlling for endogeneity were higher than without controlling for it. This suggests that estimates of demand given insurance might depend on the empirical econometric specification used in the analysis. If the final model is not chosen based on stringent criteria as applied in this case, the calculation of premiums and prediction of financial sustainability of an insurance scheme might be underestimated. Our findings confirm empirical studies done in Ecuador and Ireland. Waters [10] found that after controlling for endogeneity of insurance, the beneficiaries of general health insurance programmes in Ecuador significantly increased their demand for curative health care by about 30 percent, whilst not controlling for endogeneity of insurance the demand effect was only 11 percent. In Ireland, Harmon and Nolan [28] found that treating insurance as exogenous, the probability of having a hospital stay was 3 percent higher for those with health insurance. When insurance was treated endogenously, the effects approximately double (6 percent).
In the case of private visits, several statistical tests suggested that the HNB hurdle specification is superior to the standard one-part specification. The use of HNB is justified by the fact that health care use in this study is measured by number of contacts instead of the total cost of all contacts [7]. Our finding is line with previous studies [3], and confirms the importance of distinguishing between factors that affect the propensity for contacting health care providers and factors that determine the volume of utilization once contact has been made [16]. Bogu [29] also suggests that count data models most commonly used are the hurdle model and the finite mixture negative binomial. The validity of hurdle specification is suspect if individuals have multiple illness episodes or multiple first contacts or the first contact belongs to an illness episode of the preceding illness [3,14,16]. Since utilization data in this study is derived from a 4-week recall period, both multiple illness episodes and multiple first contacts seem unlikely here. In addition, this study included several measures of current health conditions and an ADL score reflecting long-term health status. As they were not significant in the second stage of the HNB model, the HNB retains its superiority over other candidate models.
The HNB estimates confirm that Askes insurance exhibited a negative relationship in both contact and frequency decisions for private OP which is consistent with a priori expectations as the scheme entitles beneficiaries to services at public providers only. For Private insurance, the coefficients show positive relationships in both decision stages but are significant only in the contact decision. The motivation of the hurdle model comes from ‘principal-agent’ theories of the demand for health care [4]. In this regard, however, our results do not support the possibility of supplier-induced demand due to insurance. This might be the result of a strict utilization review program managed by the insurer. In addition, our results show that the main determinants of the frequency decision are need-based. This is consistent with previous studies that found no evidence of such behavior [3].
Another way to look into the evidence of supply induced demand (SID) for health care is to examine how the doctors’ density affects demand. Physician density in Indonesia is higher in urban areas. Physicians practicing in urban areas facing negative income shocks could use their dual role—both as evaluator and supplier—to induce demand [30]. In our models, the urban dummy turned out to be positive and significant in both decisions for visits to private OP, suggesting there is evidence SID where private provider competition is likely. However, future research is needed to validate our finding by including a variable that measures physician density directly.
The finding that insurance increases individuals’ propensity for health care utilization is important for policy makers, particularly in Indonesia where current debate is dominated by discussions regarding improving access to care and the introduction of national health insurance scheme. Although such findings have been reported elsewhere [911,28], our results are specific to two different types insurance (Askes with public providers only and Private with both public and private providers). The large effect observed in the use of private providers compared with public ones by Private insurance beneficiaries may be explained in the light of perceived quality of care. Theoretically, insurance reduces the effective price that beneficiaries pay for health care [30]. Insured people, given provider networks, choose the alternative that yields the highest satisfaction (utility). As this would mean increasing perceived quality and decreasing prices, the ultimate choice of provider actually reflects the relative trade-off between price and quality that individuals prefer. By offering private providers (perceived to have better quality), Private insurance reduces the relative price of quality, and hence the beneficiaries were more likely to use private providers. If there is a quality effect, our findings would imply that public providers may need strategies that would change people’s perceptions about their quality of care.
Another finding from this analysis bears more discussion. A negative (and statistically significant) relationship to health care demand of Private insurance/income interaction in the HNB estimates indicates the effects of Private insurance on contact decisions is more pronounced among the poor. One possible reason is that the poor have a higher price elasticity of demand, and hence the reduction in the effective price of health services due to insurance coverage increases utilization to a greater extent among poorer than among richer individuals. From a public health perspective these findings are of substantial interest, suggesting current policy on introducing the NHIP will have a stronger impact on increasing health care demand among the poor. The introduction of a demand-side subsidy to include the 76.4 million poor in the NHIP in Indonesia is supported by the findings of this study.

Acknowledgments

The authors are grateful to the RAND Corporation for providing us with the IFLS data. We would also like to thank the guest editor, Ulf-G. Gerdtham, and to two anonymous referees for helpful comments that improve this paper substantially. Finally, we thank Jon Jellema for correcting English errors. All views expressed and errors encountered are the sole responsibility of the authors.

Appendix A.

The proposed instruments (zi) and the selected zi.
The proposed instruments (zi) and the selected zi.
The proposed instruments ziThe selected zi in estimating the number of outpatient visits to:
Public providersPrivate providers
If household head government employee (1/0)
If household head private employee (1/0)
If active in community meetings (1/0)
If active in cooperative meetings (1/0)
If active in women group organizations (1/0)
If housing occupied (1/0)
If spouse (1/0)
The predicted value of Askes insurance*
The predicted value of Private insurance*
*generated from the prediction of the first-stage regression estimation (Equation 2); marked √ indicates the proposed zi was selected in the IV and GMM estimations.

References and Notes

  1. Cameron, AC; Trivedi, PK. Econometric models based on count data: comparisons and applications of some estimators and tests. J. Appl. Econom. 1986, 1, 29–53. [Google Scholar]
  2. Cameron, AC; Trivedi, PK; Milne, F; Pigott, JA. Microeconometric model of the demand for health care and health insurance in Australia. Rev. Econ. Stud. 1988, 55, 85–106. [Google Scholar]
  3. Pohlmeier, W; Ulrich, V. An econometric model of the two-part decision making process in the Demand for health care. J. Hum. Resour. 1995, 30, 339–361. [Google Scholar]
  4. Deb, P; Trivedi, PK. Demand for medical care by the elderly: a finite mixture approach. J. Appl. Econom. 1997, 12, 313–336. [Google Scholar]
  5. Gurmu, S. Semi-parametric estimation of hurdle regression models with an application to medicaid utilization. J. Appl. Econom. 1997, 12, 225–242. [Google Scholar]
  6. Trivedi, PK. Introduction: econometric models of event counts events. J. Appl. Econom. 1997, 12, 199–201. [Google Scholar]
  7. Deb, P; Holmes, AM. Estimates of use and costs of behavioural health care: a comparison of standard and finite mixture models. Health Econ 2000, 9, 475–489. [Google Scholar]
  8. Jones, AM. Health econometrics. In Handbook of Health Economics; Culyer, AJ, Newhouse, JP, Eds.; Elsevier: Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 2000; Volume 1A, pp. 265–344. [Google Scholar]
  9. Vera-Hernandez, AM. Duplicate coverage and demand for health care. The case of Catalonia. Health Econ 1999, 8, 579–598. [Google Scholar]
  10. Waters, HR. Measuring the impact of health insurance with a correction for selection bias—a case study of Ecuador. Health Econ 1999, 8, 473–483. [Google Scholar]
  11. Schellhorn, M. The effect of variable health insurance deductibles on the demand for physician visits. Health Econ 2001, 10, 441–456. [Google Scholar]
  12. Hadley, J; Polsky, D; Mandelblatt, JS; Mitchell, JM; Weeks, JC; Wang, Q; Hwang, YT. An exploratory instrumental variable analysis of the outcomes of localized breast cancer treatments in a medicare population. Health Econ 2003, 12, 171–186. [Google Scholar]
  13. Mullahy, J. Instrumental variable estimation of count data models: Applications to models of cigarette smoking behaviour. Rev. Econ. Stat. 1997, 79, 586–593. [Google Scholar]
  14. Windmeijer, FAG; Santos-Silva, JMC. Endogeneity in count data models: an application to demand for health care. J. Appl. Econom. 1997, 12, 281–294. [Google Scholar]
  15. Thabrany, H. Private health sector in Indonesia: opportunities and progress. J. Indonesian Med. Assoc. 2001, 5, 1–13. [Google Scholar]
  16. Jimenez-Martin, S; Labeaga, JM; Martinez-Granado, M. Latent class versus two-part models in the demand for physician services across the European Union. Health Econ 2002, 11, 301–321. [Google Scholar]
  17. Mullahy, J. Specification and testing of some modified count data models. J. Econom. 1986, 33, 341–365. [Google Scholar]
  18. Pagan, AR; Hall, D. Diagnostic tests as residual analysis. Econometric Rev 1983, 2, 159–218. [Google Scholar]
  19. Bound, J; Jaeger, DA; Baker, RM. Problems with instrumental variables estimation when the correlation between the instruments and the endogeneous explanatory variable is weak. J. Am. Stat. Assoc. 1995, 90, 443–450. [Google Scholar]
  20. Staiger, D; Stock, JH. Instrumental variables regression with weak instruments. Econometrica 1997, 65, 557–586. [Google Scholar]
  21. Shea, J. Instrumental relevance in multivariate linier models: a simple measure. Rev. Econ. Stat. 1997, 79, 348–352. [Google Scholar]
  22. Baum, CF; Schaffer, ME; Stillman, S. Instrumental variables and GMM: estimation and testing. Stata J 2003, 3, 1–31. [Google Scholar]
  23. StataCorp, Stata Statistical Software: Release 7.0.; StataCorp Inc: College Station, TX, USA, 2001.
  24. Gerdtham, UG. Equity in health care utilization: further tests based on hurdle models and Swedish micro data. Health Econ 1997, 6, 303–319. [Google Scholar]
  25. Frankenberg, E; Karoly, L. The 1993 Indonesia Family Life Survey: Overview and Field Report Publication No DRU-1195/1-NICHD/AID; RAND Corporation: Los Angeles, CA, USA, 1995. [Google Scholar]
  26. Frankenberg, E; Sikoki, B; Suriastini, W; Thomas, D. Household Survey Questionnaires for the Indonesia Family Life Survey. Publication No. DRU-2238/3-NIA/NICHD; RAND Corporation: Los Angeles, CA, USA, 2000. [Google Scholar]
  27. Mullahy, J. Much ado about two: reconsidering retransformation and the two-part model in health economics. J. Health Econ. 1998, 17, 247–281. [Google Scholar]
  28. Harmon, C; Nolan, B. Health insurance and health services utilization in Ireland. Health Econ 2001, 10, 135–145. [Google Scholar]
  29. d'Uva, TB. Latent class models for utilisation of health care. Health Econ 2006, 15, 329–343. [Google Scholar]
  30. Feldstein, PJ. Health Care Economics, 4th ed; Delmar: Albany, New York, NY, USA, 1993. [Google Scholar]
Figure 1. Framework to select econometric techniques for modeling the relationships between health insurance and the number of outpatient visits.
Figure 1. Framework to select econometric techniques for modeling the relationships between health insurance and the number of outpatient visits.
Ijerph 07 00009f1
Table 1. Characteristics of health insurance schemes in Indonesia.
Table 1. Characteristics of health insurance schemes in Indonesia.
Main CharacteristicsHealth Insurance Schemes
AskesJamsostekPrivate
RegulationGov’t Regulation 69/91Social Security Act #3/1992Insurance Act #2/1992
InsurerPT Askes (Persero), state-owned companyPT Jamsostek (Persero), state-owned companyPrivate insurance firms

MembershipMandatoryOptional-mandatoryVoluntary

EligibilityCivil servants, pensioners of civil servants and armed forcePrivate sector employeeVaries, depend on the contract

BeneficiariesSpouse and 2 oldest children (<21 years if unemployed & unmarried, or <25 years if a student)Spouse and 3 oldest children <21 years of ageVaries

Premium rate4% payroll deduction (regardless of marital status)Payroll deduction (single 3%; married 6%)Varies, depend on the risk and the benefits

Premium policyContributoryNon-contributoryFull Contributory

Benefits, providers networkOP and IP at public providersOP at both public and private providers; IP at public providers onlyUsually OP and IP, and mostly in the private providers networks
Note: OP = outpatient health care services; IP = Inpatient health care services.
Table 2. Sample frequency distribution of the number of public and private outpatient visits (number of observations = 13639).
Table 2. Sample frequency distribution of the number of public and private outpatient visits (number of observations = 13639).
Number of visitsPublic outpatient visits
Private outpatient visits
Freq.PercentFreq.Percent
011,58984.9712,57392.18
11,0617.785624.12
25443.992691.97
32461.801180.87
41501.10810.59
5150.1150.04
6170.1260.04
770.0570.05
8-80.06
9--
10100.07100.07

y(mean)0.280.15
s2y(variance)0.670.43
S2y/y2.392.87
Table 3. Summary statistics of the variables used in the demand equation.
Table 3. Summary statistics of the variables used in the demand equation.
VariableDefinitionMeanStd. Dev.
Askes insurance1 if govt-employ insurance; 0 otherwise0.0980.298
Private insurance1 if priv-employ insurance; 0 otherwise0.0520.223
Askes*incomeInteraction Askes and income0.1650.775
Private*incomeInteraction Jamsostek and income0.0730.419
Symptoms1 if had ≥ 1 symptom; 0 otherwise0.9630.189
Score ADLsPhysical ability to perform daily activity0.2950.456
Very good GHS RVery good health status
  GHS is goodGeneral health status was good0.7880.409
  GHS is poorGeneral health was bad & very bad0.1350.342
Serious illness1 if had serious ill; 0 otherwise0.1270.333
Female1 if female; 0 otherwise0.5740.495
Household sizeNumber of household members5.8782.594
Married1 if married; 0 otherwise0.8420.365
No-schoolingRHad no education
  ElementaryHad some primary education0.4750.499
  JuniorHad some secondary education0.1360.343
  SeniorHad some senior education0.1960.397
  HighHad some higher education0.0690.254
Age (years)Individual age in years36.98811.654
Ln. IncomeLog natural per-capita income (Rp)11.0990.855
Electricity1 if had electricity; 0 otherwise0.8700.336
TravCost publicLog one way travel-costs to public health post6.6885.868
TravCost privateLog one way travel-costs to private health post3.2784.792
TravTime publicLog one way travel-time to public post8.0531.769
TravTime privateLog one way travel-time to private post6.9752.353
Urban1 if urban; 0 otherwise0.4880.500
Jakarta RegionRJakarta residence
  SumatraLived in Sumatra0.1950.396
  West JavaLived in West Java0.1780.383
  Central JavaLived in Central Java0.1880.391
  East JavaLived in East Java0.1210.326
  Bali & WNTLived in Bali and WNT0.1120.316
  KalimantanLived in Kalimantan0.0490.216
  SulawesiLived in Sulawesi0.0560.229
Ris the reference group.
Table 4. Endogeneity tests.
Table 4. Endogeneity tests.
Endogeneity test:Public outpatient visits
Private outpatient visits
Statisticsp-val.Statisticsp-val.
HausmanF(2,13607) = 10.2830.00003F(2) = 0.5370.585
Durbin Wu Hausmanχ2(2) = 20.5840.00003χ2(2)=1.0760.584
Table 5. Tests for the relevance of instruments.
Table 5. Tests for the relevance of instruments.
Test statisticPublic outpatient visits
Askes insurancePrivate insurance
Pseudo R2
Unadjusted R20.49730.5697
Adjusted R20.49620.5688
Partial R20.05610.0213
Shea Partial R20.05180.0197
F-tests:
  Wald test (a)434.24581.22
  Wald test (b)202.2674.17
(a)F-test all instruments F(31,13607);
(b)F-test excluded instruments F(4,13607);
significant 1%.
Table 6. Selection criteria of the standard count data models: private outpatient visits.
Table 6. Selection criteria of the standard count data models: private outpatient visits.
PoissonNBZINBHurdle Negative Binomial (HNB)
1st part: Logit2nd part: Truncated NB
Observation (n)13,63913,63913,63913,6391,066
LR test (29)a1,203.211,047.57779.22866.94145.54
−Log-L5,829.724,735.274,712.283,271.521,346.48
Overdispersion testb12.48n.an.an.an.a
Vuong test cn.an.a3.3n.an.a
Alphadn.a7.074.17n.a0.53
AIC11,719.459,532.559,504.566,603.052,752.95
BIC1,970.47588.42533.08661.79
LR vs. Poisson testen.an.an.an.a8,966.49
aLog ratio test of the joint significance of the regressors (in ZINB, number of regressors are 38);
bOverdispersion test for Poisson vs. NB model;
cVuong test for standard NB vs. zero-inflated NB model;
dAn ancillary parameter alpha (α) is an estimate of the degree of overdispersion in the data;
eLog ratio test for truncated NB vs. truncated Poisson;
n.a = not available, and
significant at 1%.
Table 7. Estimation results of the GMM and HNB models.
Table 7. Estimation results of the GMM and HNB models.
Variable[1]
[2]
Public outpatient visits: GMM
Private outpatient visits: HNB
1st part: Logit
2nd part: NB
Coef.a(se) bCoef.a(se) bCoef.a(se)b
Askes insurance0.631(0.154)−0.017(0.135)−0.298(0.219)
Private insurance0.197(0.281)1.274(0.184)0.272(0.210)
Askes*income0.003(0.040)−0.023(0.044)0.033(0.064)
Private*income−0.145(0.114)−0.319(0.107)0.075(0.153)
Symptoms0.287(0.024)3.174(0.717)16.314(0.000)
Score ADLs0.098(0.021)0.345(0.079)0.077(0.100)
GHS very goodR
  GHS is good0.050(0.021)0.414(0.149)0.471(0.174)
  GHS is poor0.355(0.032)1.390(0.164)0.738(0.216)
Serious illness0.086(0.024)0.721(0.083)0.493(0.170)
Female0.118(0.015)0.147(0.074)0.289(0.086)
Household size0.006(0.003)0.046(0.013)0.029(0.020)
Married0.055(0.022)−0.286(0.102)−0.117(0.155)
NoschoolingR
  Elementary−0.019(0.024)0.362(0.142)0.357(0.160)
  Junior−0.091(0.033)0.455(0.169)0.117(0.186)
  Senior−0.083*(0.046)0.505(0.164)−0.246(0.193)
  High−0.262(0.056)0.756(0.185)0.175(0.234)
Age (years)−0.001(0.001)0.003(0.004)−0.001(0.004)
Ln income0.031(0.012)0.383(0.051)−0.034(0.062)
Electricity0.106(0.022)1.003(0.198)0.107(0.263)
TravCost(ln)0.002(0.001)0.015(0.007)−0.004(0.007)
TravTime (ln)0.009(0.004)0.029*(0.018)0.065(0.026)
Urban−0.109(0.021)0.228(0.083)0.276(0.112)
Jakarta RegionR
  Sumatra0.027(0.034)−0.327(0.127)0.077(0.204)
  West Java−0.047(0.034)−0.112(0.116)0.302(0.132)
  Central Java−0.034(0.032)0.089(0.122)0.141(0.152)
  East Java0.052(0.037)0.509(0.135)0.554(0.157)
  Bali & WNT0.076(0.036)0.150(0.143)0.015(0.170)
  Kalimantan0.136(0.054)−1.080(0.257)0.360(0.425)
  Sulawesi0.042(0.042)−0.648(0.242)0.092(0.289)
Constant−0.730(0.129)−12.743(1.002)−17.923(1.097)

Number observations13639136391066
aThe estimated parameters; superscript ,, and * indicate significance at 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively;
bRobust standard errors in (parentheses);
Ris the reference group.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Hidayat, B.; Pokhrel, S. The Selection of an Appropriate Count Data Model for Modelling Health Insurance and Health Care Demand: Case of Indonesia. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2010, 7, 9-27. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph7010009

AMA Style

Hidayat B, Pokhrel S. The Selection of an Appropriate Count Data Model for Modelling Health Insurance and Health Care Demand: Case of Indonesia. International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health. 2010; 7(1):9-27. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph7010009

Chicago/Turabian Style

Hidayat, Budi, and Subhash Pokhrel. 2010. "The Selection of an Appropriate Count Data Model for Modelling Health Insurance and Health Care Demand: Case of Indonesia" International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health 7, no. 1: 9-27. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph7010009

APA Style

Hidayat, B., & Pokhrel, S. (2010). The Selection of an Appropriate Count Data Model for Modelling Health Insurance and Health Care Demand: Case of Indonesia. International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health, 7(1), 9-27. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph7010009

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop