Next Article in Journal
How Does Value Co-Creation Behavior Affect Destination Loyalty? A Role Switching Perspective
Previous Article in Journal
A Study on the Factors Influencing Users’ Online Knowledge Paying-Behavior Based on the UTAUT Model
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Information Acquisition and Its Incentives in an E-Commerce Supply Chain under the Offline Showroom Model

1
School of Economics and Management, Chongqing University of Posts and Telecommunications, Chongqing 400065, China
2
School of Economics and Business Administration, Chongqing University, Chongqing 400044, China
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
J. Theor. Appl. Electron. Commer. Res. 2021, 16(5), 1791-1804; https://doi.org/10.3390/jtaer16050100
Submission received: 2 April 2021 / Revised: 26 May 2021 / Accepted: 28 May 2021 / Published: 3 June 2021

Abstract

:
Recently, the showroom model has developed fast for allowing consumers to evaluate a product offline and then buy it online. This paper aims at exploring the optimal information acquisition strategy and its incentive contracts in an e-commerce supply chain with two competing e-tailers and an offline showroom. Based on signaling game theory, we build a mathematical model by considering the impact of experience service and competition intensity on consumers’ demand. We find that, on the one hand, information acquisition promotes supply chain members to obtain demand information directly or indirectly, which leads to forecast revenue. On the other hand, information acquisition promotes supply chain members to distort optimal decisions, which results in signal cost. The optimal information acquisition strategy depends on the joint impact of forecast revenue, signal cost and demand forecast cost. Notably, in some conditions, the offline showroom will not acquire demand information even when its cost is equal to zero. We also design two different information acquisition incentive contracts to obtain Pareto improvement for all supply chain members.

1. Introduction

Global e-commerce has developed rapidly in recent years. As the largest two markets for global e-commerce, online retail sales of China reached 1815.76 billion dollars in 2020, and eMarketer forecasts that US retail ecommerce sales will reach 908.73 billion dollars in 2021. Despite its rapid growth, online retail faces a challenge, i.e., e-tailers deliver product information only through word and picture and lack physical experience. Namely, consumers cannot make sure whether the product fits their needs before receiving the product. This results in the fact that some product categories, which need to be touched and felt, such as household products, apparel and accessories, are confronted with large amounts of returns [1,2].
Under this background, the offline showroom model (showroom for short) emerges to solve the high return rate issue of the online channel. In the showroom model, showrooms provide a physical experience for products sold by e-tailers instead of selling competing products directly. Then, consumers can touch and feel these products in showrooms before buying them from e-tailers directly. In practice, many e-tailers have adopted this channel cooperation model. For example, Warby Parker, a fashion eyewear brand in America, cooperates with local retailers to showcase all glasses sold online [3]. Further, some showrooms serve more than one e-tailer to satisfy consumers’ heterogeneous demand. For example, Home Times, a showroom of household products opened by Yintai Retails (a leading traditional retailer in China) provides experience service for many brands.
Besides, as the market environment becomes more uncertain, showrooms face huge challenges on operational decisions. For example, if showrooms are too optimistic about the market condition, it may result in overinvestment. In a word, acquiring demand information is crucial to showrooms. In practice, Home Times invests in big data to analyze consumers’ purchasing behaviors. However, showrooms must invest large sums of money in the information gathering system, demand forecast system and so on, leading to higher operational costs. Thus, showrooms need to make the trade-off between cost and revenue of information acquisition. For competing e-tailers, information can also guide their operational decisions. Thus, they have the incentive to encourage showrooms to acquire and share the information. However, it may intensify competition between e-tailers, which may lead to new interest conflict. Therefore, it has practical and theoretical values for channel cooperation to study information acquisition strategy and its incentives.
Based on this background, this paper aims at solving the following questions.
(1)
What is the impact of information acquisition on the e-commerce supply chain members?
(2)
What is the optimal information acquisition strategy of the showroom?
(3)
How do the competing e-tailers design the optimal information acquisition incentive contract to obtain Pareto improvement?
The contribution of this paper is twofold. First, this paper studies operational decisions under the competition scenario where the showroom exerts experience service for two competing e-tailers, while the existing research studies mostly focuses on the scenario without competition. Second, the existing research on information acquisition and its incentives mainly focuses on the traditional supply chain in which manufacturers cooperate with retailers through a wholesale model. Differently, this paper explores information acquisition and its incentives in an e-commerce supply chain, where a showroom cooperates with two competing retailers through an agent model.
The rest of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 reviews the related literature. Section 3 describes how to build the mathematical model, and Section 4 gives the methodology on how to solve the mathematical model. Section 5 and Section 6 study the optimal information acquisition strategy of the showroom and the optimal information acquisition incentive contract of competing e-tailers, respectively. Section 7 provides the discussion and conclusion of this paper.

2. Literature Review

2.1. Literature on Showroom Model

Literature on the showroom model can be divided into two streams. In the first stream of literature, some retailers are forced to be showrooms due to showrooming (the behavior that consumers examine products offline and then buy them from e-tailers at lower prices). Therefore, scholars mainly focused on the impact of showrooming [4,5,6,7] and how to cope with showrooming [8,9,10,11,12]. Later, some scholars considered the vital role of manufacturers in the distribution channel and introduced them to this research stream [13,14,15].
As more and more consumers use both online and offline channels to purchase, some scholars put forward a showroom mechanism from the aspect of channel cooperation [16]. This stream of literature on showroom mainly includes two aspects: the aspect of a single firm and the aspect of a supply chain. From the aspect of a single firm, some scholars investigated the impact of a showroom on the e-tailer [3]; some scholars studied operational decisions of the retailer operating both an online channel and a showroom, such as inventory decision [17], product placement strategy [18,19,20,21], pricing decision [22,23]. From the aspect of a supply chain, some scholars examined the cooperation strategy of supply chain members without competition, such as Liu et al., who explored how to open the online and showroom channel in a supply chain with a manufacturer and a retailer [24]; Li et al. studied the cooperative advertising contract design of the e-tailer to the showroom [25]. Some scholars considered the scenario with competition. For instance, Zhang et al. investigated a retailer’s information service decision and two competing manufacturers’ pricing decisions when the retailer operates both the online channel and showroom [26]; Li et al. studied whether a showroom cooperating with an existing e-tailer introduces a competing e-tailer under information asymmetry [27]; Zhang et al. studied an online manufacturer’s response strategy to a retailer when it introduces a competing product in its showroom [28].
The second stream of literature under competition is more related, but Zhang et al. [26] mainly focused on the competition between manufacturers, and the online channel and showroom belong to one retailer; Li et al. [27] mainly studied whether a showroom introduces a competitor; Zhang et al. [28] focused on product competition in a one-to-one supply chain. Differently, we consider a supply chain with a showroom and two competing e-tailers, and explore information acquisition and its incentives of supply chain members.

2.2. Literature on Information Acquisition and Its Incentives

This paper also relates literature on information acquisition and its incentives, which can be divided into scenarios without competition and with competition. In the first stream of literature, some scholars mainly focused on information acquisition decisions [29]; some scholars investigated the impact of information acquisition at different timing [30,31]; some scholars designed different contracts to encourage the retailer to acquire information [32,33].
In the second stream of literature, some scholars studied information acquisition and its incentives with downstream competition. For instance, in a supply chain with a supplier and two or more competing retailers, Shin and Tunca examined the reason for the retailers’ overinvestment in information acquisition, and designed a contract based on market behavior [34]; Li et al. considered that the supplier can obtain information by itself and the retailers, and explored the optimal information acquisition decision and side payment contract of the supplier [35]. Besides, some scholars considered a supply chain with channel competition. For instance, Huang et al. studied the optimal information acquisition incentive contract of the manufacturer and information acquisition decision of the retailer in a dual-channel supply chain [36].
This paper relates more on information acquisition and its incentives under competition. However, these research studies mainly focused on the traditional supply chain where suppliers cooperate with retailers through a wholesale model. Differently, we focus on the supply chain where e-tailers cooperate with the showroom through an agent model.
Table 1 summarizes the difference between this paper and the most relevant research studies.

3. Mathematical Model Building

Consider a supply chain with a showroom ( s ) and two competing e-tailers ( i = 1 , 2 ). E-tailer i sells product i to consumers at selling quantity q i . The showroom exerts experience service to attract consumers to experience products offline and then buy them online, and charges a certain proportion of revenue for each transaction as commission. Let e and γ denote experience service level and commission rate. We draw Figure 1 to illustrate the supply chain structure intuitively.
Experience service does not deliver product information, rather, it brings a unique experience to consumers; therefore, e can increase market demand. Besides, consumers always prefer different channels to purchase [19]. Thus, we assume that there exist consumers preferring online channel and consumers preferring offline channel. Meanwhile, this paper mainly focuses on the cooperation problem where the showroom exerts experience service to attract consumers preferring offline channel to touch and feel products. Therefore, similar to [37], we assume that the demand of consumers preferring online channel is exogenous, which is normalized to 0. Then, we have inverse demand function of e-tailer i :
p i = α + e q i θ q 3 i ,   i = 1 , 2 ,
where p i denotes market-clearing price of product i , α denotes base market demand of consumers preferring offline channel (base market demand for short), θ denotes competition intensity between the e-tailers. Considering the impact of market uncertainty, we assume base market demand α is random, which can be either high (H type) or low (L type) with equal probability, i.e., P r H   = P r L   = 1 / 2 . Further, we assume H = α ¯ 1 + δ and L = α ¯ 1 δ , where α ¯ denotes the mean of base market demand, δ denotes demand uncertainty and satisfies 0 < δ < 1 . The showroom and e-tailers only know the prior distribution type of α .
Due to serving consumers directly, the showroom always possesses extensive data. Then, before the selling season, the showroom can obtain demand forecast information Y at a fixed cost C . Information Y has two states: Y = h and Y = l , which correspond to the two demand states H and L , respectively. Besides, it is an unbiased estimator of the real demand state, i.e., P r h   = P r H P r h H   +   P r L P r h L   = P r H , P r l   = P r H P r l H   +   P r L P r l L   = P r L ; and also satisfies regularity conditions, i.e., P r h H   +   P r l H   = 1 and P r l L   +   P r h L   = 1 . In real life, the showroom can only forecast limited information, and we define forecast accuracy as η = P r h H   +   P r l L 1 , and η 0 , 1 . Then, we have:
P r H h   = P r L l   = 1 + η 2 ,   P r H l   = P r L h   = 1 η 2 ,
E α h   = α ¯ 1 + η δ ,   E α l   = α ¯ 1 η δ
From Equation (3), η δ is the combination of forecast accuracy and demand uncertainty, which measures how much the expected demand varies from the showroom’s forecast. Thus, we refer to η δ as forecast variability for convenience.
Let T i denote side payment offered by e-tailer i to incent the showroom to acquire and share the information. Besides, considering the increasing marginal cost of experience service, we assume that the cost function of experience service is c e   = e 2 / 2 . Then, we have profit functions of supply chain members:
π s = γ p 1 q 1 + p 2 q 2   +   T 1 + T 2 C e 2 / 2 ,
π i =   1 γ p i q i T i ,   i = 1 , 2 .
Before the selling season, the e-tailers decide whether to provide information acquisition incentives, if provided, then decide side payment T i . Then the showroom makes the information acquisition decision. At the beginning of the selling season, the showroom decides the experience service level e ; then e-tailer i decides product quantity q i . At the end of the selling season, demand is achieved and supply chain members obtain their profit.
Besides, we acknowledge some constraints of our model. First, this paper mainly studies information acquisition decision of the showroom and information acquisition incentive contract design of the e-tailers. As a result, the mathematical model is only applied to the product categories which require touch and feel, such as household products, apparel and accessories. Second, in this model, the showroom does not sell competing products directly; therefore, this model may not fit for the scenario where offline stores sell competing products and consumers exhibit price comparison behavior. Third, this paper mainly focuses on cooperation instead of competition between showroom and e-tailers. Thus, this model cannot apply to the scenario where offline and online channels are significantly different, i.e., the different return date and return methods between online and offline channels.

4. Methodology

For convenience, let F and N strategies represent the showroom acquire information and does not acquire information, respectively.

4.1. Methodology under F Strategy

Under F strategy, we use backward induction to solve our mathematical model based on signaling game theory. The reason is as follows. Under F strategy, the showroom does not share information Y to e-tailer i , i.e., e-tailer i does not know Y . However, e-tailer i can make a rational inference through experience service. Anticipating this reaction, the showroom may distort information to maximize profit. Signaling game between the showroom and e-tailer i happens. There always exist separating equilibrium and pooling equilibrium in a signaling game. When more than one equilibrium result exists, it is necessary to refine the equilibrium results. Due to intuitive criterion, a classical equilibrium refinement tool proposed by Cho and Kreps [38], it is easy to verify that the pooling equilibrium cannot survive the intuitive criterion [27,39,40]. Thus, the rest of this paper mainly focuses on the separating equilibrium.
In the separating equilibrium, the showroom exerts different levels of experience service e due to information Y . E-tailer i upgrades its belief on the type of Y after observing e . Intuitively, with higher base market demand, the showroom tends to exert a higher e . Therefore, belief structure of e-tailer i satisfies the rules: if e < e ^ , e-tailer i regards information as Y = l ; otherwise, e-tailer i regards information as Y = h , where e ^ denotes threshold of experience service level. Based on this belief structure, e-tailer i can infer the true type of Y . Then, the expected profits of supply chain members are:
E π i e   =   1 γ q i E α e   +   e q i θ q 3 i ,   i = 1 , 2 ,
E π s Y   = γ i = 1 2 q i E α Y   +   e q i θ q 3 i C e 2 / 2 .
Solving the above optimization problems, we have Theorem 1.
Theorem 1. 
e h F = 4 γ α ¯ 1 + η δ 2 + θ 2 4 γ , e l F = e ^ ,   w h e n   η δ < η 1 4 γ α ¯ 1 η δ 2 + θ 2 4 γ ,   w h e n   η δ η 1 , q i h F = α ¯ 1 + η δ + e h F 2 + θ , q i l F = α ¯ 1 η δ + e l F 2 + θ , where e ^ = 2 α ¯ 2 γ 1 + η δ + θ η δ 2 + θ Z 1 2 + θ 2 4 γ , Z 1 = 2 γ η δ 2 γ η δ 2 η δ η δ θ + θ , η 1 = θ 2 + θ , i = 1 , 2 ; and when η δ < η 1 , e l F = e ^ F < 4 γ α ¯ 1 η δ 2 + θ 2 4 γ .
Proof of Theorem 1. 
Due to backward induction, we first derive the optimal selling quantity decisions. It is easy to verify that E π i e is concave in q i . Let E π i e / q i = 0 , we have q i N e Y . Next, we derive the optimal experience service level. Due to the belief structure of e-tailer i , there exists a unique perfect Bayesian equilibrium of the signaling game if and only if the following constraints are satisfied:
Constraints   1 :   max e   E π s e e ^ h   max e   E π s e > e ^ h ,
Constraints   2 : max e   E π s e e ^ l   max e   E π s e > e ^ l ,
where E π s e e ^ h denotes expected profit of H type showroom which mimics as L type; E π s e > e ^ h denotes expected profit of H type showroom which delivers its true information; E π s e e ^ l denotes expected profit of L type showroom which delivers its true information; E π s e > e ^ l denotes expected profit of L type showroom which mimics as H type. The above two constraints ensure that the showroom cannot obtain higher profit by mimicking as the other type.
From E π s e > e ^ h   = 2 γ α ¯ 1 + η δ + e H 2 2 + θ 2 e H 2 2 C , we can easily obtain that the optimal experience service level is 4 γ α ¯ 1 + η δ 2 + θ 2 4 γ . Then, the optimal expected profit of H type showroom is E π s e > e ^ h   = 2 γ α ¯ 2 1 + η δ 2 2 + θ 2 4 γ C . It is also easy to obtain that E π s e e ^ h   = 2 γ α ¯ 1 + η δ + e 2 2 + θ 2 e 2 2 C . Then, Constraint 1 equals to 2 γ α ¯ 1 + η δ + e 2 2 + θ 2 e 2 2 C 2 γ α ¯ 2 1 + η δ 2 2 + θ 2 4 γ C . To guarantee this inequality, experience service level of L type should satisfy e 2 α ¯ 2 γ 1 + η δ + θ η δ 2 + θ Z 1 2 + θ 2 4 γ ; otherwise H type showroom can always obtain higher profit by mimicking as L type. Thus, under the perfect Bayesian equilibrium, e-tailer i has the unique belief structure, i.e., e ^ = 2 α ¯ 2 γ 1 + η δ + θ η δ 2 + θ Z 1 2 + θ 2 4 γ . Besides, it is easy to verify that Constraint 2 is always satisfied. Therefore, we have the optimal experience service level of L type showroom as 4 γ α ¯ 1 η δ 2 + θ 2 4 γ without constraint. Combined with the belief structure of e-tailer i , if 4 γ α ¯ 1 η δ 2 + θ 2 4 γ e ^ , L type showroom will choose the optimal experience service level as e ^ ; otherwise, L type showroom will choose the optimal experience service level as 4 γ α ¯ 1 η δ 2 + θ 2 4 γ . □
Theorem 1 shows that L type showroom has to lower e l F when forecast variability η δ is relatively small. The reason for this downward distortion is as follows. When η δ is relatively small, H type showroom has the incentive to mimic L type. Anticipating this incentive, e-tailer i will infer showroom when its experience service level is higher than e ^ F , as H type further increases product selling quantity. This will intensify competition between e-tailers under L type demand and result in a profit loss of L type showroom. Then, to avoid being misunderstood, L type showroom has to lower e l F . This reveals that under information asymmetry, the showroom has to pay a certain signal cost to deliver its true information.

4.2. Methodology under N Strategy

Under N strategy, all supply chain members are not aware of the actual demand state. Thus, we use backward induction to solve the mathematical model based on the expected profit maximization. Then, the expected profits of supply chain members are:
E π s   = γ q 1 E α   +   e q 1 θ q 2   +   q 2 E α   +   e q 2 θ q 1 e 2 / 2 ,
E π i   =   1 γ q i E α   +   e q i θ q 3 i ,   i = 1 , 2 .
Solving the above optimization problems, we have the equilibrium decisions in Theorem 2.
Theorem 2. 
e N = 4 γ α ¯ 2 + θ 2 4 γ ; q i N = α ¯ + e N 2 + θ .
Proof of Theorem 2. 
Due to backward induction, we first solve the optimal selling quantity decisions. It is easy to verify that E π i is concave in q i . Let E π i / q i = 0 , we have q i N e . Then we can verify that E π s is concave in e . Let E π s / e = 0 , we have e N . □

5. Results

5.1. The Optimal Information Acquisition Strategy

Let Δ E π s   = E π s F E π s N and Δ E π i   = E π i F E π i N , where Δ E π s and Δ E π i denote value brought by information acquisition to the showroom and e-tailer i . Substituting equilibrium results in Theorems 1 and 2, we have:
Δ E π s   = F s + S s C ,
Δ E π i   = F i + S i ,
where F s and F i denote forecast revenue brought by information acquisition to the showroom and e-tailer i , S s and S i denote signal cost brought by information asymmetry to the showroom and e-tailer i , and F s = 2 γ η 2 δ 2 α ¯ 2 2 + θ 2 4 γ , S s = α ¯ 2 2 γ η δ Z 1 2 2 + θ 2 4 γ ,   when   η δ < η 1 0 ,   when   η δ η 1 ; F i = η 2 δ 2 α ¯ 2 1 γ 2 + θ 2 2 + θ 2 4 γ 2 , S i = 2 α ¯ 2 1 γ Z 1 2 γ η δ 2 + θ 1 η δ + 2 γ η δ Z 1 2 + θ 2 4 γ 2 ,   when   η δ < η 1   0 ,   when   η δ η 1 .
Analyzing the impact of information acquisition on supply chain members, we have Proposition 1.
Proposition 1. 
(1) Forecast revenue: if γ γ 1 , then F i F s > 0 , F i η δ F s η δ > 0 ; if γ > γ 1 , then F s > F i > 0 , F s η δ > F i η δ > 0 ; (2) Signal cost: if η δ > η 1 , then S s = S i = 0 ; if η δ < η 1 , γ γ 2 and η 3 η δ η 2 , then  S s < S i < 0 .
Where γ 1 = 2 + θ 6 + 3 θ 2 + 3 θ 2 + 24 θ 16 , γ 2 is the solution of Z 2 = 0 , Z 2 = 4 γ 3 4 θ 2 4 γ 2 48 10 θ 2 + θ 4 16 2 + θ 2 + γ 192 + 96 θ 28 θ 2 + 20 θ 4 + 8 θ 5 + θ 6 ; η 2 = Z 3 + 6 6 γ + 4 θ + θ 2 γ Z 2 2 2 + θ 12 γ 3 2 γ 2 10 + 15 θ + 4 θ 2 + γ 4 + 28 θ + 24 θ 2 + 8 θ 3 + θ 4 + 4 + 2 θ , η 3 = Z 3 6 6 γ + 4 θ + θ 2 γ Z 2 2 2 + θ 12 γ 3 2 γ 2 10 + 15 θ + 4 θ 2 + γ 4 + 28 θ + 24 θ 2 + 8 θ 3 + θ 4 + 4 + 2 θ , η 3 < η 2 < η 1 , Z 3 = 12 γ 3 4 θ + 4 γ 2 28 + 6 θ 5 θ 2 2 θ 3 + 4 2 + θ 2 γ 80 + 52 θ 16 θ 2 24 θ 3 8 θ 4 θ 5 .
Proof of Proposition 1. 
From Equations (10) and (11), we have:
F s F i = η 2 δ 2 α ¯ 2 8 γ 2 + 2 γ 2 + θ 2 2 + θ 2 2 + θ 2 4 γ 2
From the above equation, we have sign F s F i   = sign 8 γ 2 + 2 γ 2 + θ 2 2 + θ 2 . Due to the nature of the quadratic function, we have F s F i 0 when γ γ 1 ; F s F i > 0 when γ > γ 1 . The proof of sign F s / η δ F i / η δ , as well as the proof of Proposition 1(2) is similar to that mentioned before. □
To illustrate Proposition 1 intuitively, we used Matlab-R2017a to draw Figure 2 based on α ¯ = 10 and θ = 0.8 . Proposition 1(1) shows that information acquisition always brings positive forecast revenue to supply chain members, which is also illustrated in Figure 2a. It is noteworthy that when commission rate is low, forecast revenue of the e-tailers is higher than that of the showroom. Proposition 1(1) also shows that forecast variability η δ has a positive effect on forecast revenue. Proposition 1(2) indicates that when η δ is small, information asymmetry generates signal cost to supply chain members, which is also illustrated in Figure 2b, and when γ is high and η δ is medium, signal cost of the showroom is higher than that of the e-tailers.
Analyzing Δ E π s , we have the optimal information acquisition decision of the showroom in Proposition 2.
Proposition 2. 
(1) When η δ < η 4 , for any C > 0 , N strategy is optimal to the showroom; (2) When η δ η 4 , if C F s + S s then F strategy is optimal to the showroom; otherwise, N strategy is the optimal strategy; where η 4 = θ 3 + θ 2 2 γ 3 + θ 2 8 γ < η 1 .
Proof of Proposition 2. 
The proof of Proposition 2 is similar to that of Proposition 1. □
Proposition 2 shows that the optimal information acquisition strategy depends on the joint impact of forecast revenue, signal cost and information acquisition cost. To be more specific, when forecast variability η δ is small, signal cost dominates forecast revenue. Thus, even when information acquisition cost approaches 0, the showroom will not acquire information. As η δ becomes bigger, forecast revenue dominates, then the showroom will acquire information if the information acquisition cost is no larger than its total value. This suggests whether the showroom should acquire information needs to consider information asymmetry besides information acquisition cost.

5.2. The Optimal Information Acquisition Incentive Contract

Analyzing the impact of the optimal information acquisition strategy on the e-tailers, we have Proposition 3.
Proposition 3. 
The impact of the optimal strategy on the e-tailers is given in Table 2.
Proof of Proposition 3. 
The proof of Proposition 3 is similar to that of Proposition 1. □
Proposition 3 indicates that the optimal information acquisition strategy benefits the e-tailers in some conditions but hurts them in others, and there exist three different reasons for profit loss. In region R2, low commission rate makes that revenue forecast of the e-tailers dominates their signal cost. Thus, information acquisition brings higher profits to them. In region R4 and region R9, information acquisition always generates higher profits for the e-tailers. In region R6, high commission rate makes forecast revenue of the e-tailers lower than signal cost. Thus, information acquisition hurts the e-tailers.
When the optimal strategy hurts the e-tailers, they have incentives to encourage the showroom to change its strategy. However, only when the increased profit of e-tailers can offset profit loss of the showroom caused by changing the optimal strategy is information acquisition incentive contract feasible. Thus, it is necessary to analyze the impact of the optimal strategy on the whole supply chain. Let Δ E π s c   = E π s c F E π s c N , where Δ E π s c denotes value brought by information acquisition to the whole supply chain. From Equations (10) and (11), we have Δ E π s c   = F s c + S s c , where F s c and S s c denote forecast revenue and signal cost of the whole supply chain, and F s c = F s + F 1 + F 2 , S s c = S s + S 1 + S 2 . Analyzing the impact of the optimal strategy on the whole supply chain, we have Proposition 4.
Proposition 4. 
The impact of the optimal strategy on the whole supply chain is given in Table 3.
Proof of Proposition 4. 
The proof of Proposition 4 is similar to that of Proposition 1. □
Proposition 4 indicates that only in regions R2b, R4a, R6a and R9a, the e-tailers can design contract to encourage the showroom to change its strategy.
In region R6a, the e-tailers encourage the showroom not to acquire information; in regions R2b, R4a and R9a, the e-tailers encourage the showroom to acquire information. For convenience, we refer to SN contract and SF contract as the two contracts.

5.2.1. SN Contract

In practice, firms always determine side payment by negotiation. Thus, we assume that side payment T i is determined by one-to-one negotiation. Let ϕ i denote bargaining power of e-tailer i to the showroom. Under SN contract, the Nash bargaining problem is:
Max T i E π i SN E π i F T i ϕ i E π s SN E π s F / 2 + T i 1 ϕ I s . t .   E π i SN E π i F T i 0 E π s SN E π s F / 2 + T i 0 ,
where i = 1 , 2 , E π i S N = m a x q i 1 γ q i E α + e q i θ q 3 i T i , E π s S N = m a x e γ i = 1 2 q i E α + e q i θ q 3 i + T 1 + T 2 e 2 / 2 .
Due to backward induction, we obtain the equilibrium SN contract in Proposition 5.
Proposition 5. 
(1) e S N = 4 γ α ¯ 2 + θ 2 4 γ ; q i S N = α ¯ + e N 2 + θ ; T i S N =   1 ϕ i F i S i   +   ϕ i F s + S s 2 ; (2) When F s + S s 2 + F i + S i > 0 , T i S N ϕ i > 0 ; otherwise, T i S N ϕ i 0 .
Proof of Proposition 5. 
Due to backward induction, we first solve the optimal sell quantity decisions and the optimal experience service level decision during the selling season, which is similar to the proof of Theorem 2. Then, we solve the optimal side payment in Equation (12) without constraint, and we have T i S N =   1 ϕ i F i S i   +   ϕ i F s + S s / 2 . It is easy to verify that T i S N can satisfy the constraint in Equation (12), i.e., T i S N is the optimal Nash negotiation solution. It is easy to prove the solution in Proposition 5(2). □
To illustrate Proposition 5 intuitively, we use Matlab-R2017a to draw Figure 3 based on α ¯ = 10 , θ = 0.8 and η δ = 0.15 . Comparing Theorem 2 and Proposition 5(1), SN contract only changes the optimal information acquisition strategy. Proposition 5(2) indicates that when information acquisition value of the showroom is relatively high ( F s + S s > 2 F i S i ), side payment increases as bargaining power of the e-tailers increases, which is also illustrated in Figure 3.

5.2.2. SF Contract

Under SF contract, if the showroom accepts side payment, it will acquire and share the information to the e-tailers. Then, the Nash bargaining problem is:
m a x T i E π i S F E π i N T i ϕ i E π s S F E π s N / 2 + T i 1 ϕ i s . t .   E π i S F E π i N T i 0   E π s N E π s S F / 2 + T i 0   ,
where i = 1 , 2 , E π i S F = m a x q i 1 γ q i E α Y + e q i θ q 3 i T i , E π s S F = m a x e γ i = 1 2 q i E α + e q i θ q 3 i + T 1 + T 2 C e 2 / 2 .
Due to backward induction, we obtain the equilibrium SF contract as shown in Proposition 6.
Proposition 6. 
(1) e h S F = 4 γ α ¯ 1 + η δ 2 + θ 2 4 γ ; e l S F = 4 γ α ¯ 1 η δ 2 + θ 2 4 γ ; q i h S F = α ¯ 1 + η δ + e h S F 2 + θ ; q i l S F = α ¯ 1 η δ + e l S F 2 + θ ; T i S F =   1 ϕ i F i ϕ i F s 2 ; (2) When ϕ i > 1 γ 2 + θ 2 + 4 γ 2 + θ 2 + 4 γ 1 2 γ , T i θ > 0 ; otherwise, T i θ 0 .
Proof of Proposition 6. 
The proof of Proposition 6 is similar to that of Proposition 5. □
To illustrate Proposition 6 intuitively, we use Matlab-R2017a to draw Figure 4 based on α ¯ = 10 , θ = 0.8 and η δ = 0.25 . Comparing Theorem 1 and Proposition 6(1), SF contract does not encourage the showroom to change the optimal strategy, but also changes the optimal decisions. Proposition 6(2) shows that when the bargaining power of the e-tailers is strong, the showroom can get higher side payment with higher competition intensity. On the one hand, it is easy to verify that F i / θ < 0 and F s / θ < 0 , which indicates that the increase of competition intensity has a negative impact on forecast revenues. On the other hand, when the bargaining power of the e-tailers is strong, the negative impact of competition on forecast revenue of the showroom dominates that of the e-tailers. As a result, the showroom can get higher side payment with higher competition intensity.

6. Discussion

This paper studies the impact of information acquisition on the optimal decisions of supply chain members, and finds that information acquisition generates both positive forecast revenue and negative signal cost. These results are in line with literature [29] and [36], i.e., information acquisition may distort the optimal decisions of supply chain members and lead to negative signal cost. However, comparing with the literature considering the traditional supply chain with supplier(s) and retailer(s), our study points out that the negative signal cost may hurt the showroom more severely than the e-tailers in the e-commerce supply chain. To be more specific, the reason for the generation of signal cost is that the showroom lowers the optimal experience service level to deliver true forecast information under information asymmetry, leading to lower demand and lower profit of supply chain members. Notably, high commission rate means high signal cost shared by the showroom. Meanwhile, the decrease of experience service level can lower the operational cost of the showroom to a certain extent. Thus, when forecast variability is medium, the showroom suffers higher signal cost than the e-tailers.
This paper also studies the optimal information acquisition incentive contract for e-tailers to achieve Perato improvement. The existing literature mainly explores how suppliers design different contracts to encourage retailers to forecast demand information [32,33,34,35]. Differently, in SN contract, the e-tailers offer contracts to encourage the showroom not to acquire demand information. This is because in the SN contract region, forecast revenue of the showroom dominates its signal cost, but the profit the showroom obtained by acquiring information cannot offset the negative effect on the e-tailers. Besides, we also find that SF contract can eliminate the ill effect of signal cost; as a result, side payment is negative when commission rate is high.

7. Conclusions

In recent years, showrooms have developed fast to provide experience service for e-tailers, which can solve consumers’ fit uncertainty when purchasing online. However, with the increasing uncertainty of the market, the mismatch between demand and supply brings a considerable challenge to supply chain members. How to acquire information is crucial for channel cooperation. Under this background, this paper considered a supply chain consisting of a showroom and two competing e-tailers, and examined the optimal information acquisition and its incentives.
The main results are summarized as follows. On the one hand, information acquisition prompts the showroom to adjust experience service level, which further delivers information to the e-tailers indirectly and then prompts them to adjust their optimal decisions. As a result, all supply chain members obtain positive forecast revenue. On the other hand, when forecast variability is relatively small, the showroom needs to lower the optimal experience service level to deliver true information. This leads to lower consumers’ demand and then generates negative signal cost to supply chain members. The optimal information acquisition strategy of the showroom depends on the joint impact of forecast revenue, signal cost and information acquisition cost. Specifically, in some conditions, even information acquisition cost approaches 0, and the showroom will not acquire information. In some conditions, the optimal strategy harms profits of the e-tailers and the whole supply chain. Then, we design SN and SF contracts to encourage the showroom to change its optimal strategy.
The above conclusions have important implications. From the perspective of the enterprise itself, the more demand information it has the better. However, from the perspective of the whole supply chain, information asymmetry among supply chain members may hurt the one possessing more demand information. Therefore, when making demand acquisition decisions, showrooms should consider their relationship with other supply chain members, especially the information asymmetry and the cooperation model among them.
It is notable that in some conditions information acquisition hurts the whole supply chain due to negative signal cost caused by information asymmetry. Under this condition, the e-tailers should offer side payment to encourage showrooms not to acquire demand information. The existing literature mainly explores how to design contracts to encourage information acquisition behavior. Therefore, this finding is also the contribution of our paper to the theory.
We acknowledge some limitations in this paper. First, e-tailers may cooperate with more than one showroom in practice, but we only consider the competition issue between e-tailers in this paper, which is one of the limitations of this paper. As a result, studying how e-tailers cooperate with more than one showroom will be an interesting direction. Second, in this paper we find that the showroom possessing more demand information may obtain lower profits, which indicates that the showroom can strategically share its information to obtain more profits. However, limited by the length of the article, this paper fails to explore forecast information sharing in the e-commerce supply chain, which is another limitation of this paper. Thus, future research can explore how showrooms strategically share information with e-tailers in an e-commerce supply chain.

Author Contributions

M.L.: conceptualization, methodology, formal analysis, validation, software, writing—original draft preparation, funding acquisition; X.Z.: supervision, writing—review and editing, funding acquisition. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research was funded by the National Natural Science Foundation of China [Grant number 71572020], Chongqing Social Science Planning Fund [Grant number 2020BS50], Humanities and Social Science of Chongqing Education Commission [Grant number 21SKGH078], Research Foundation for Advanced Talents of Chongqing University of Posts and Telecommunications [Grant number E012K2020208], and Ministry of Education of Humanities and Social Science [Grant number 19YJC630084].

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Acknowledgments

The authors are grateful to the editors and the four anonymous reviewers for their constructive comments and valuable suggestions, which improved the quality of this paper.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Dzyabura, D.; Jagabathula, S.; Muller, E. Accounting for discrepancies between online and offline product evaluations. Market. Sci. 2019, 38, 88–106. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Letizia, P.; Pourakbar, M.; Harrison, T. The impact of consumer returns on the multichannel sales strategies of manufacturers. Prod. Operat. Manag. 2018, 27, 323–349. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Bell, D.R.; Gallino, S.; Moreno, A. Offline showrooms in omnichannel retail: Demand and operational benefits. Manag. Sci. 2018, 64, 1629–1651. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Balakrishnan, A.; Sundaresan, S.; Zhang, B. Browse-and-switch: Retail-online competition under value uncertainty. Prod. Operat. Manag. 2014, 23, 1129–1145. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Flavian, C.; Gurrea, R.; Orus, C. Combining channels to make smart purchases: The role of webrooming and showrooming. J. Retail. Consum. Serv. 2020, 52, 101923. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Rapp, A.; Baker, T.L.; Bachrach, D.G.; Ogilvie, J.; Beitelspacher, L.S. Perceived customer showrooming behavior and the effect on retail salesperson self-efficacy and performance. J. Retail. 2015, 91, 358–369. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Samuel, J.; Zheng, Z.E.; Xie, Y. Value of local showrooms to online competitors. MIS Quart. 2020, 44, 1073–1106. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Basak, S.; Basu, P.; Avittathur, B.; Sikdar, S. A game theoretic analysis of multichannel retail in the context of “showrooming”. Decis. Supp. Syst. 2017, 103, 34–45. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Basak, S.; Basu, P.; Avittathur, B.; Sikdar, S. Manufacturer driven strategic coordination as a response to “showrooming”. Decis. Supp. Syst. 2020, 133, 113305. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Fassnacht, M.; Beatty, S.E.; Szajna, M. Combating the negative effects of showrooming: Successful salesperson tactics for converting showroomers into buyers. J. Bus. Res. 2019, 102, 131–139. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Mehra, A.; Kumar, S.; Raju, J.S. Competitive strategies for brick-and-mortar stores to counter “showrooming”. Manag. Sci. 2018, 64, 3076–3090. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  12. Jing, B. Showrooming and webrooming: Information externalities between online and offline sellers. Market. Sci. 2018, 37, 469–483. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Kuksov, D.; Liao, C. When showrooming increases retailer profit. J. Market. Res. 2018, 55, 459–473. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Li, G.; Li, L.; Sun, J. Pricing and service effort strategy in a dual-channel supply chain with showrooming effect. Trans. Res. Part E Logist. Trans. Rev. 2019, 126, 32–48. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Li, Y.; Li, B.; Zheng, W.; Chen, X. Reveal or hide? Impact of demonstration on pricing decisions considering showrooming behavior. Omega 2021, 102, 102329. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Bell, D.R.; Gallino, S.; Moreno, A. How to win in an omnichannel world. MIT Sloan Manag. Rev. 2014, 56, 45–53. [Google Scholar]
  17. Gao, F.; Su, X. Online and offline information for omnichannel retailing. Manufact. Serv. Operat. Manag. 2017, 19, 84–98. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  18. Gu, Z.J.; Tayi, G.K. Consumer pseudo-showrooming and omni-channel placement strategies. MIS Quart. 2017, 41, 583–606. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Dzyabura, D.; Jagabathula, S. Offline assortment optimization in the presence of an online channel. Manag. Sci. 2018, 64, 2767–2786. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  20. Li, G.; Zhang, T.; Tayi, G.K. Inroad into omni-channel retailing: Physical showroom deployment of an online retailer. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2020, 283, 676–691. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Park, J.; Dayarian, I.; Montreuil, B. Showcasing optimization in omnichannel retailing. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2020. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Du, S.; Wang, L.; Hu, L. Omnichannel management with consumer disappointment aversion. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2019, 215, 84–101. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Liu, Z.; Lu, L.; Qi, X. The showrooming effect on integrated dual channels. J. Oper. Res. Soc. 2020, 71, 1347–1356. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Liu, L.; Feng, L.; Xu, B.; Deng, W. Operation strategies for an omni-channel supply chain: Who is better off taking on the online channel and offline service? Electron. Comm. Res. Appl. 2020, 39, 100918. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Li, M.; Zhang, X.; Dan, B. Cooperative advertising contract design in a supply chain with an offline showroom under asymmetric information. J. Oper. Res. Soc. 2021. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Zhang, T.; Li, G.; Cheng, T.E.; Shum, S. Consumer inter-product showrooming and information service provision in an omni-channel supply chain. Decis. Sci. 2020, 51, 1232–1264. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Li, M.; Zhang, X.; Dan, B. Competition and cooperation in a supply chain with an offline showroom under asymmetric information. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2020, 58, 5964–5979. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Zhang, H.; Dan, B.; Zhang, X. Discourage or encourage? An online manufacture’s response to competing product introduction under physical showroom cooperation. Electron. Comm. Res. Appl. 2021, 47, 101038. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Guo, L. The benefits of downstream information acquisition. Market. Sci. 2009, 28, 457–471. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  30. Guan, X.; Mantrala, M.; Bian, Y. Strategic information management in a distribution channel. J. Retail. 2019, 95, 42–56. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Xiao, L.; Xu, M.; Zheng, J.J.; Huang, S. Inducing manufacturer’s quality enhancement via retailer’s acquisition strategy. Omega 2020, 93, 102032. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Amornpetchkul, T.; Duenyas, I.; Şahin, Ö. Mechanisms to induce buyer forecasting: Do suppliers always benefit from better forecasting? Prod. Operat. Manag. 2015, 24, 1724–1749. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Chen, F.; Lai, G.; Xiao, W. Provision of incentives for information acquisition: Forecast-based contracts vs. menus of linear contracts. Manag. Sci. 2016, 62, 1899–1914. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  34. Shin, H.; Tunca, T.I. Do firms invest in forecasting efficiently? The effect of competition on demand forecast investments and supply chain coordination. Operat. Res. 2010, 58, 1592–1610. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  35. Li, G.; Zheng, H.; Sethi, S.P.; Guan, X. Inducing downstream information sharing via manufacturer information acquisition and retailer subsidy. Decis. Sci. 2020, 51, 691–719. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Huang, S.; Guan, X.; Xiao, B. Incentive provision for demand information acquisition in a dual-channel supply chain. Trans. Res. Part E Logist. Trans. Rev. 2018, 116, 42–58. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Gao, F.; Su, X. Omnichannel retail operations with buy-online-and-pick-up-in-store. Manag. Sci. 2017, 63, 2478–2492. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  38. Cho, I.K.; Kreps, D.M. Signaling games and stable equilibria. Quart. J. Econ. 1987, 102, 179–221. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Li, Q.; Zhou, J. A horizontal capacity reservation game under asymmetric information. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2019, 57, 1103–1118. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Yan, Y.; Zhao, R.; Xing, T. Strategic introduction of the marketplace channel under dual upstream disadvantages in sales efficiency and demand information. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2019, 273, 968–982. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Supply chain structure.
Figure 1. Supply chain structure.
Jtaer 16 00100 g001
Figure 2. The impact of information acquisition: (a) Forecast revenue; (b) Signal cost.
Figure 2. The impact of information acquisition: (a) Forecast revenue; (b) Signal cost.
Jtaer 16 00100 g002
Figure 3. SN contract (R6a).
Figure 3. SN contract (R6a).
Jtaer 16 00100 g003
Figure 4. SF contract (R9a).
Figure 4. SF contract (R9a).
Jtaer 16 00100 g004
Table 1. Comparison among our paper and the most relevant researches.
Table 1. Comparison among our paper and the most relevant researches.
PaperShowroom from the Aspect of Supply ChainInformation Acquisition and Its Incentives
Without
Competition
With
Competition
Without
Competition
With
Competition
Liu et al. [24]; Li et al. [25]
Zhang et al. [26]; Li et al. [27]; Zhang et al. [28]
Guo [29]; Guan et al. [30]; Xiao et al. [31]; Amornpetchkul et al. [32]; Chen et al. [33]
Shin and Tunca [34]; Li et al. [35]; Huang et al. [36]
Our paper
Table 2. The impact of the optimal strategy on the e-tailers.
Table 2. The impact of the optimal strategy on the e-tailers.
ConditionsOptimal StrategyIts Impact
R1 γ < γ 3 η δ < η 5 C > 0 N Δ E π i < 0
R2 η 5 η δ < η 4 C > 0 N Δ E π i 0
R3 η δ η 4 C F s + S s F Δ E π i 0
R4 C > F s + S s N Δ E π i 0
R5 γ γ 3 η δ < η 4 C > 0 N Δ E π i < 0
R6 η 4 η δ < η 5 C F s + S s F Δ E π i < 0
R7 C > F s + S s N Δ E π i < 0
R8 η δ η 5 C F s + S s F Δ E π i 0
R9 C > F s + S s N Δ E π i 0
Where γ 3 = 2 + θ 2 5 + 2 + θ 2 3 1 + 2 2 + θ 2 4 4 + θ 2 ; η 5 is the solution of F i + S i = 0 on η δ , and η 5 < η 1 .
Table 3. The impact of the optimal strategy on the whole supply chain.
Table 3. The impact of the optimal strategy on the whole supply chain.
ConditionsOptimal StrategyIts Impact
R2a γ < γ 3 η 5 η δ < η 6 C > 0 N Δ E π s c < 0
R2b η 6 η δ < η 4 C F s c + S s c N Δ E π s c 0
R4a η δ η 4 F s + S s < C F s c + S s c N Δ E π s c 0
R6a γ γ 3 η 4 η δ < η 6 C F s + S s F Δ E π s c < 0
R6b η 6 η δ < η 5 C F s + S s F Δ E π s c 0
R9a η δ η 5 F s + S s < C F s c + S s c N Δ E π s c 0
Where η 6 is the solution of F s c + S s c = 0 on η δ , and η 6 < η 1 .
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Li, M.; Zhang, X. Information Acquisition and Its Incentives in an E-Commerce Supply Chain under the Offline Showroom Model. J. Theor. Appl. Electron. Commer. Res. 2021, 16, 1791-1804. https://doi.org/10.3390/jtaer16050100

AMA Style

Li M, Zhang X. Information Acquisition and Its Incentives in an E-Commerce Supply Chain under the Offline Showroom Model. Journal of Theoretical and Applied Electronic Commerce Research. 2021; 16(5):1791-1804. https://doi.org/10.3390/jtaer16050100

Chicago/Turabian Style

Li, Mengli, and Xumei Zhang. 2021. "Information Acquisition and Its Incentives in an E-Commerce Supply Chain under the Offline Showroom Model" Journal of Theoretical and Applied Electronic Commerce Research 16, no. 5: 1791-1804. https://doi.org/10.3390/jtaer16050100

APA Style

Li, M., & Zhang, X. (2021). Information Acquisition and Its Incentives in an E-Commerce Supply Chain under the Offline Showroom Model. Journal of Theoretical and Applied Electronic Commerce Research, 16(5), 1791-1804. https://doi.org/10.3390/jtaer16050100

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop