Fresh Agricultural Products Supply Chain Coordination and Volume Loss Reduction Based on Strategic Consumer
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Literature Review
3. Problem Description and Models
3.1. Problem Description
3.2. Models
3.2.1. Centralized Model
3.2.2. Contractual Cooperation Model
3.3. Model Comparison and Analysis
4. Numerical Experimentation
4.1. The Impact of δ on the Profit of FASC and Three Types of Volume Losses
4.2. The Impact of ε on the Profit of FASC and Three Types of Vol. The Impact of γ on the Profit of FASC and Three Types of Volume Losses ume Losses
4.3. The Impact of γ on the Profit of FASC and Three Types of Volume Losses
4.4. The Impact of ρ on the Profit of FASC and Three Types of Volume Losses
5. Discussion
- (1)
- The fresh agricultural products supply chain where the TPLSP and retailer act as a Stackelberg leader and a follower can achieve coordination by the revenue and service-cost sharing contract. This is compatible with the study of Ma et al. [10] however the unit price for the freshness-keeping service must be negative in order to achieve coordination. Differing from it, the unit price of logistics service can be positive in this paper and when the revenue sharing coefficient and service-cost sharing coefficient are under certain conditions, the Pareto improvement can be achieved. The cost sharing coefficient decreases with the consumer utility discount coefficient. Therefore the consumers’ strategic behavior influences the profit distribution which is compatible with the study of Su et al. [26]. The cooperation of the TPLSP and retailer will bring logistics service level, which leads to higher freshness. Then fresh agricultural products are healthier to consumers. Therefore, retailers and TPLSP should try their best to cooperate and negotiate the profit sharing coefficient to obtain increased profit and higher freshness of fresh agricultural products;
- (2)
- The supply chain coordination leads to a reduction in the per unit demand volume loss which is compatible with the study of Mohammadi et al. [6]. The per unit demand volume loss decreases with the optimal logistics service level [57] and the optimal logistics service level is higher in contractual cooperation model than in a decentralized model because of the retailer’s revenue and service-cost sharing with the TPLSP. Then the per unit demand volume loss is always less compared to the decentralized model. Obliviously, the corporation of the retailer and TPLSP will get more profit and a reduction in the per unit demand volume loss [53];
- (3)
- The supply chain coordination leads to a reduction in the per unit profit volume loss and total demand volume loss simultaneously only if the lowest marginal costs of FASC occur under certain conditions. As the study of Bai et al. [24] shows the total carbon emission are analyzed, the two types of volume losses are not studied in the model studies to the best of the author’s knowledge. However the two types of volume losses are important for decision makers. In the contractual cooperation model, the freshness of products are higher and the total demands are higher than in the decentralized model. Therefore the two types of volume losses are not always lower than in the decentralized model. The two types of volume losses can be simultaneously lower than in the decentralized model only if the lowest marginal costs is low. Then the retailer and TPLSP should reduce the smallest marginal cost of the supply chain, so that the two types of volume losses are reduced. In addition, the increase of the lower bound of the smallest marginal cost of FASC will increase the possibility that the coordination leads to a reduction in the two types of volume losses. According to the relationships between the lower bound of the smallest marginal cost of FASC and parameters in the model, the increase in the service sensitivity coefficient, the decrease (increase) in consumer utility discount coefficient if it is small (large), and the increase in the freshness discount coefficient if it is large will lead to the increase in the possibility of a reduction in the two types of volume losses when the supply chain achieves coordination. Therefore, while it seemed that volume loss was not related to the retailer, it in fact has a lot to do with the retailer because of their decisions about the freshness discount coefficient and influences on consumers to change their strategy, thus these two participants of the supply chain cannot work separately but rather make a collaborative effort to reduce volume losses [53].
- (4)
- When the FASC achieves coordination the profit of FASC is inversely proportional to the consumer utility discount coefficient which is compatible with the study of Chen et al. [17], making the decision of responding pricing. The total demand is inversely proportional to the consumer utility discount coefficient. Therefore, consumer strategic behavior is detrimental to the total demand which is also compatible with the study of Chen et al. [17]. The optimal logistics service level decreases first and then increases with the consumer utility discount coefficient. If the level of strategic behavior is small (large), the decrease (increase) in it will lead to higher freshness of products and less per unit demand volume loss. Therefore, the increase in the level of strategic behavior is detrimental to the profits of the whole supply chain, but beneficial to consumers and the environment under certain conditions. As mentioned above, the level of strategic behavior also influences the profit distribution between the retailer and TPLSP, then the increase in it will change the cost sharing which may be beneficial to the retailer;
- (5)
- When FASC achieves coordination, the profit of FASC is inversely proportional to the price sensitivity coefficient, and it is directly proportional to the service sensitivity coefficient and freshness level discount coefficient due to the utility of consumers being inversely proportional (directly proportional) to the price sensitivity coefficient (service sensitivity coefficient). The lower (higher) of the price sensitivity coefficient (service sensitivity coefficient), the more total demand. The relationships between the profit and price sensitivity (freshness sensitivity) is compatible with the study of Yan et al. [7]. In the numerical analysis of Yan et al. [7], it seems that the profit decreases first and then increases with price sensitivity (freshness sensitivity) due to the neglect of the condition that the order quantity must be positive. When this condition is taken into account, the relationship between the profit of the supply chain and the price sensitivity (freshness sensitivity) is the same as this paper;
- (6)
- When FASC achieves coordination, the relationships between the three types of volume losses including the per unit demand volume loss, per unit profit volume loss, and total demand volume loss in the centralized model (contractual cooperation model) and parameters are as follows: (1) The three types of volume losses are inversely proportional to the service sensitivity coefficient which is compatible with the study of Mohammadi et al. [6] where the percentage of product waste is inversely proportional to surviving rate coefficient therefore, the TPLSP should arrange the storage of products in transport vehicles reasonably and load fresh agricultural products into transport vehicles as soon as possible so as to reduce loss and increase the freshness of the products and profit of FASC; (2) the three types of volume losses increase first and then decrease with the consumer utility discount coefficient due to the relationship between the logistics service and consumer utility discount coefficient. Therefore, the retailer should emphasize the nutritional value of fresh agricultural products to consumers in order to affect them to reduce their consumer utility discount coefficient when it’s small so as to reduce loss and increase the profit of FASC. It should be noted that the impact of the consumer utility discount coefficient on profit distribution is not considered here; (3) when , the per unit demand volume loss and per unit profit volume loss first increase and then decrease with the freshness discount coefficient; when , the two types of volume losses decrease with it. Therefore, the retailer should increase the freshness level discount coefficient if it is large enough to reduce the two types of losses and increase the profit of FASC; (4) the per unit demand volume loss and per unit profit volume loss increase with the price sensitivity coefficient. Therefore, the retailer should emphasize the nutritional value of fresh agricultural products to consumers in order to affect them to reduce their price sensitivity coefficient so as to reduce loss and increase the profit of FASC.
6. Conclusions
Author Contributions
Funding
Conflicts of Interest
Appendix A
Decentralized Model
Appendix B
References
- Yan, B.; Wu, J.; Jin, Z.; He, S. Decision-making of fresh agricultural product supply chain considering the manufacturer’s fairness concerns. 4OR-Q. J. Oper. Res. 2020, 18, 91–122. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yu, Y.; Xiao, T. Pricing and cold-chain service level decisions in a fresh agri-products supply chain with logistics outsourcing. Comput. Ind. Eng. 2017, 111, 56–66. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Fang, Y.; Jiang, Y.; Han, X. Bundle Pricing Decisions for Fresh Products with Quality Deterioration. J. Food Qual. 2018, 2018, 1595807. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Yu, Y.; Xiao, T.; Feng, Z. Price and cold-chain service decisions versus integration in a fresh agri-product supply chain with competing retailers. Ann. Oper. Res. 2020, 287, 465–493. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Fan, T.; Xu, C.; Tao, F. Dynamic pricing and replenishment policy for fresh produce. Comput. Ind. Eng. 2020, 139, 106127. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mohammadi, H.; Ghazanfari, M.; Pishvaee, M.S.; Twimoury, E. Fresh-product supply chain coordination and waste reduction using a revenue-and-preservation-technology-investment-sharing contract: A real-life case study. J. Clean. Prod. 2019, 213, 262–282. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yan, B.; Fan, J.; Cai, C.; Fang, J. Supply chain coordination of fresh Agri-products based on value loss. Oper. Manag. Res. 2020, 1–12. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cai, X.; Chen, J.; Xiao, Y.; Xu, X.; Yu, G. Fresh-product supply chain management with logistics outsourcing. Omega 2013, 41, 752–765. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wu, Q.; Mu, Y.; Feng, Y. Coordinating contracts for fresh product outsourcing logistics channels with power structures. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2015, 160, 94–105. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ma, X.; Wang, S.; Islam, S.M.N.; Liu, X. Coordinating a three-echelon fresh agricultural products supply chain considering freshness-keeping effort with asymmetric information. Appl. Math. Model. 2019, 67, 337–356. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Qin, Y.; Wang, J.; Wei, C. Joint pricing and inventory control for fresh produce and foods with quality and physical quantity deteriorating simultaneously. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2014, 152, 42–48. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Tang, C.S. Robust strategies for mitigating supply chain disruptions. Int. J. Logist. Res. Appl. 2006, 9, 33–45. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dong, J.; Wu, D. Two-period pricing and quick response with strategic customers. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2019, 215, 165–173. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yi, G.; Chen, X. Optimal pricing of perishable products with replenishment policy in the presence of strategic consumers. J. Ind. Manag. Optim. 2019, 5, 1579–1597. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Aviv, Y.; Pazgal, A. Optimal pricing of seasonal products in the presence of forward-looking consumers. M&SOM-Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag. 2008, 10, 339–359. [Google Scholar]
- Su, X.; Zhang, F. Strategic customer behavior, commitment, and supply chain performance. Manag. Sci. 2008, 54, 1759–1773. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Chen, K.; Zha, Y.; Alwan, L.C.; Zhang, L. Dynamic pricing in the presence of reference price effect and consumer strategic behaviour. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2020, 58, 546–561. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Food and Agriculture Organisation of the United Nations (FAO); International Fund for Agricultural Development (IFAD); United Nations World Food Programme (WFP). The State of Food Insecurity in the World 2013. The Multiple Dimensions of Food Security; FAO: Rome, Italy, 2013. [Google Scholar]
- Eriksson, M.; Strid, I.; Hansson, P.A. Food losses in six Swedish retail stores: Wastage of fruit and vegetables in relation to quantities delivered. Resour. Conserv. Recycl. 2012, 68, 14–20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Martin-Rios, C.; Demen-Meier, C.; Gössling, S.; Cornuz, C. Food waste management innovations in the Food service industry. Waste Manag. 2018, 79, 196–206. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Zimon, D.; Madzik, P.; Domingues, P. Development of Key Processes along the Supply Chain by Implementing the ISO 22000 Standard. Sustainability 2020, 12, 6176. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cicatiello, C.; Franco, S.; Pancino, B.; Blasi, E. The value of food waste: An exploratory study on retailing. J. Retail. Consum. Serv. 2016, 30, 96–104. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Principato, L.; Ruini, L.; Guidi, M.; Secondi, L. Adopting the circular economy approach on food loss and waste: The case of Italian pasta production. Res. Conserv. Recycl. 2019, 144, 82–89. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bai, Q.; Gong, Y.; Jin, M.; Xu, X. Effects of carbon emission reduction on supply chain coordination with vendor-managed deteriorating product inventory. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2019, 208, 83–99. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Feng, Y.; Wu, Q.; Yu, Y. A divergent fresh agri-products supply chain’s game models under dual-factor horizontal competition. Oper. Res. Manag. Sci. 2016, 25, 102–109. [Google Scholar]
- Jia, J.; Hu, Q. Dynamic ordering and pricing for a perishable goods supply chain. Comput. Ind. Eng. 2011, 60, 302–309. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yan, B.; Wu, X.; Ye, B.; Zhang, Y. Three-level supply chain coordination of fresh agricultural products in the Internet of Things. Ind. Manag. Data Syst. 2017, 117, 1842–1865. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Zheng, Q.; Ieromonachou, P.; Fan, T.; Zhou, L. Supply chain contracting coordination for fresh products with fresh-keeping effort. Ind. Manag. Data Syst. 2017, 117, 538–559. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yang, L.; Tang, R. Comparisons of sales modes for a fresh product supply chain with freshness-keeping effort. Transp. Res. Part E-Logist. Transp. Rev. 2019, 125, 425–448. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhang, H.; Xu, H.; Pu, X. Comparisons of pre-sale strategies for a fresh agri-product supply chain with service effort. Agriculture 2020, 10, 324. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Xiao, Y.; Chen, J. Supply chain management of fresh products with producer transportation. Decis. Sci. 2012, 43, 785–815. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhang, J.; Liu, G.; Bai, Z. Coordinating a supply chain for deteriorating items with a revenue sharing and cooperative investment contract. Omega 2015, 56, 37–49. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dye, C.Y.; Yang, C.T. A note on “coordinating a supply chain for deteriorating items with a revenue sharing and cooperative investment contract”. Omega 2016, 62, 115–122. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dye, C.Y.; Yang, C.T. Optimal dynamic pricing and preservation technology investment for deteriorating products with reference price effects. Omega 2016, 62, 52–67. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dye, C.Y.; Yang, C.T.; Wu, C.C. Joint dynamic pricing and preservation technology investment for an integrated supply chain with reference price effects. J. Oper. Res. Soc. 2018, 69, 811–824. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cai, X.; Chen, J.; Xiao, Y.; Xu, X. Optimization and coordination of fresh product supply chains with freshness-keeping effort. Prod. Oper. Manag. 2010, 19, 261–278. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gu, B.; Fu, Y.; Li, Y. Fresh-keeping effort and channel performance in a fresh product supply chain with loss-averse consumers’ returns. Math. Probl. Eng. 2018, 2018, 4717094. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Du, J.; Zhang, J.; Hua, G. Pricing and inventory management in the presence of strategic customers with risk preference and decreasing value. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2015, 164, 160–166. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Levin, Y.; McGill, J.; Nediak, M. Optimal dynamic pricing of perishable items by a monopolist facing strategic consumers. Prod. Oper. Manag. 2009, 19, 40–60. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yan, B.; Ke, C.X. Two strategies for dynamic perishable product pricing to consider in strategic consumer behaviour. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2018, 56, 1757–1772. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Papanastasiou, Y.; Savva, N. Dynamic pricing in the presence of social learning and strategic consumers. Manag. Sci. 2017, 63, 919–939. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Cachon, G.P.; Swinney, R. The value of fast fashion: Quick response, enhanced design, and strategic consumer behavior. Manag. Sci. 2011, 57, 778–795. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Levin, Y.; McGill, J.; Nediak, M. Dynamic pricing in the presence of strategic consumers and oligopolistic competition. Manag. Sci. 2009, 55, 32–46. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Liu, Q.; Zhang, D. Dynamic pricing competition with strategic customers under vertical product differentiation. Manag. Sci. 2013, 59, 84–101. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Du, P.; Xu, L.; Chen, Q.; Tsai, S.B. Pricing competition on innovative product between innovator and entrant imitator facing strategic customers. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2018, 56, 1806–1824. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- De Moraes, C.C.; de Oliveira Costa, F.H.; Pereira, C.R.; da Silva, A.L.; Delai, I. Retail food waste: Mapping causes and reduction practices. J. Clean. Prod. 2020, 256, 120124. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gustavsson, J.; Cederberg, C.; Sonesson, U. Global Food Losses and Food Waste; Swedish Institute for Food and Biotechnology (SIK): Gothenburg, Sweden, 2011. [Google Scholar]
- Kummu, M.; De Moel, H.; Porkka, M.; Siebert, S.; Varis, O.; Ward, P.J. Lost food, wasted resources: Global food supply chain losses and their impacts on freshwater, cropland and fertiliser use. Sci. Total Environ. 2012, 438, 477–489. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Tsolakis, N.K.; Keramydas, C.A.; Toka, A.K.; Aidonis, D.A.; Iakovou, E.T. Agrifood supply chain management: A comprehensive hierarchical decision-making framework and a critical taxonomy. Biosyst. Eng. 2014, 120, 47–64. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ju, M.; Osako, M.; Harashina, S. Food loss rate in food supply chain using material flow analysis. Waste Manag. 2016, 61, 443–454. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gokarn, S.; Kuthambalayan, T.S. Analysis of challenges inhibiting the reduction of waste in food supply chain. J. Clean. Prod. 2017, 168, 595–604. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Göbel, C.; Langen, N.; Blumenthal, A.; Teitscheid, P.; Ritter, G. Cutting food waste through cooperation along the food supply chain. Sustainability 2015, 7, 1429–1445. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Devin, B.; Richards, C. Food waste, power, and corporate social responsibility in the Australian food supply chain. J. Bus. Ethics 2018, 150, 199–210. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kaipia, R.; Dukovska-Popovska, I.; Loikkanen, L. Creating sustainable fresh food supply chains through waste reduction. Int. J. Phys. Distrib. Logist. Manag. 2013, 43, 262–276. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Hu, M.; Milner, J.; Wu, J. Liking and following and the newsvendor: Operations and marketing policies under social influence. Manag. Sci. 2016, 62, 867–879. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Hu, Q.; Xu, Q.; Xu, B. Introducing of online channel and management strategy for green agri-food supply chain based on pick-your-own operations. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2019, 16, 1990. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Rolle, R.S. Improving postharvest management and marketing in the Asia–Pacifific region: Issues and challenges. In Postharvest Management of Fruit and Vegetables in the Asia–Pacifific Region; Rolle, R.S., Ed.; Asian Productivity Organization (APO) and Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations (FAO): Rome, Italy, 2006; pp. 23–31. [Google Scholar]
Notation | Description |
---|---|
ui | The utility functions of consumers in period i (i = 1, 2) |
v | The consumers’ basic cognitive value of fresh agricultural products following a uniform distribution of [0,1] |
pi | The selling price in period i (i = 1, 2) |
Logistics service level | |
ε | The measure of the sensitivity of the utility of consumers to the logistics service level, referred to as service sensitivity coefficient |
ρ | The measures of the sensitivity of the utility of consumers to the selling price, referred to as price sensitivity coefficient |
k | The measures of the sensitivity of the utility of consumers to the freshness level |
h | The measures of the sensitivity of freshness level in period one to the logistics service level |
(di, d) | The demand of the retailer in period i, the total demand of the retailer |
cl | Unit cost of the third-party logistics service providers (TPLSP) |
ω | Unit purchase price of retailer |
pl | The TPLSP’s logistics service price |
δ | The consumer utility discount coefficient in period 2 within (0,1) |
γ | Freshness level discount coefficient in period 2 within (0,1) |
πi | The profit of TPSP (i = l), retailer (i = r), whole supply chain (i = sc) |
csm | The spot price in the spot market |
τ | The service cost factor |
m | The loss rate of quantity without logistics service, i.e., natural volume loss rate, within (0,1) |
(pdl, ppl, tdl) | The per unit demand volume loss, per unit profit volume loss and total demand volume loss |
Models | Centralized Model | Decentralized Model |
---|---|---|
The optimal selling price in the first period | 0.969 | 1.041 |
The optimal selling price in the second period | 0.720 | 0.954 |
The optimal logistics service level | 0.519 | 0.164 |
The optimal logistics service price | - | 0.487 |
The total demand | 0.533 | 0.199 |
The profit of retailer | - | 0.040 |
The profit of third-party logistics service provider | - | 0.065 |
The profit of supply chain | 0.174 | 0.105 |
The per unit demand volume loss | 0.096 | 0.167 |
The per unit profit volume loss | 0.296 | 0.317 |
The total demand volume loss | 0.051 | 0.033 |
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations. |
© 2020 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Qiu, F.; Hu, Q.; Xu, B. Fresh Agricultural Products Supply Chain Coordination and Volume Loss Reduction Based on Strategic Consumer. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2020, 17, 7915. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph17217915
Qiu F, Hu Q, Xu B. Fresh Agricultural Products Supply Chain Coordination and Volume Loss Reduction Based on Strategic Consumer. International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health. 2020; 17(21):7915. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph17217915
Chicago/Turabian StyleQiu, Fang, Qifan Hu, and Bing Xu. 2020. "Fresh Agricultural Products Supply Chain Coordination and Volume Loss Reduction Based on Strategic Consumer" International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health 17, no. 21: 7915. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph17217915
APA StyleQiu, F., Hu, Q., & Xu, B. (2020). Fresh Agricultural Products Supply Chain Coordination and Volume Loss Reduction Based on Strategic Consumer. International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health, 17(21), 7915. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph17217915