Next Article in Journal
Complementary Feeding Practices and Parental Pressure to Eat among Spanish Infants and Toddlers: A Cross-Sectional Study
Next Article in Special Issue
Analysis of the New Kuznets Relationship: Considering Emissions of Carbon, Methanol, and Nitrous Oxide Greenhouse Gases—Evidence from EU Countries
Previous Article in Journal
Prevalence of Sexual Abuse in Adults with Intellectual Disability: Systematic Review and Meta-Analysis
Previous Article in Special Issue
Can Industrial Collaborative Agglomeration Reduce Haze Pollution? City-Level Empirical Evidence from China
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Is the Relocation of Polluting Industries Prompted by FDI Flow and Stock, Globalisation, Corruption and Regulation?

by
Patrícia Hipólito Leal
1,2,
Rafaela Vital Caetano
1 and
António Cardoso Marques
1,2,*
1
Management and Economics Department, University of Beira Interior, 6201-001 Covilhã, Portugal
2
Management and Economics Department NECE-UBI—Research Unit in Business Sciences, University of Beira Interior, Rua Marquês d’Ávila e Bolama, 6201-001 Covilhã, Portugal
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2021, 18(4), 1981; https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph18041981
Submission received: 13 January 2021 / Revised: 12 February 2021 / Accepted: 12 February 2021 / Published: 18 February 2021
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Air Pollution and Carbon Dioxide Emissions)

Abstract

:
Can globalisation and foreign direct investment shape sustainable development? Foreign direct investment is one of the main drivers for the transfer of polluting industries. With this in mind, the main objective of this research is to identify the role played by foreign direct investment (flow and stock), globalisation (de jure and de facto), corruption and regulatory quality in environmental degradation and sustainable development. To accomplish this objective, and to link the relationships under analysis to the level of development, a comparison between a group of developing countries and a group of developed ones was performed. The results confirm the suitability of the division of the countries by revealing various effects. This analysis was conducted from 1996 to 2017 and by recurring to the Autoregressive Distributed Lag model. This study proves that foreign investors play a vital role in reaching sustainable development. Measures must be implemented to eliminate the distortions that cause a company based in a country with strict environmental regulations to relocate its production to one with lax environmental regulations. However, these measures need to be combined with complementary measures that encourage developing economies to agree to a possible slowdown in their economic growth if sufficiently compensated for this reduced growth.

1. Introduction

Around the globe, corruption phenomena, discrepancies in environmental regulatory frameworks, and distinct economic and environmental goals among countries could undermine efforts to reduce global emissions. The Paris Agreement (2015) and The Climate and Energy Framework Agreement (2018) (https://ec.europa.eu/clima/policies/strategies/2030_en (accessed on 10 November 2020)) strengthen the necessity to combat climate change through mitigating carbon dioxide (CO2) emissions (used in this study as a proxy of environmental degradation, see, e.g., in [1]), with shared responsibility among countries. Environmental degradation has become one of the biggest challenges regarding economic issues, for the main reason that resources are scarce. The environment is considered within this scarcity. Although some countries are taking big steps towards sustainability, others choose to ignore the urgency of combatting climate change in favour of becoming richer.
Globalisation is considered a key feature when defining economic development and the future of the planet [2]. Globalisation is inclined to have adverse environmental effects on developing economies, although developed ones tend to experience environmental benefits from it [3]. Globalisation encompasses economic, political and social aspects [4], and Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) is a phenomenon within globalisation. The analyses of the effect of globalisation on the environment are extremely important [5], however this relationship is controversial [6] (see more in Section 2.1). On the one hand, globalisation is seen to enable countries to achieve environmental improvements [7], while on the other hand, as much of the literature recognises, globalisation is viewed as a driving force of economic growth [8] which could, consequently, be a driver of environmental degradation [7,9]. The same is noted for FDI, as it increases economic growth [10,11], but its negative effects on the environment are observed [12,13] as well. These negative effects of globalisation and FDI are external factors which have an adverse effect, negative externalities, on the environment. As stated by Rahman [14], economic growth directly affects CO2 emissions, as an increase in output requires more energy consumption which could lead to more environmental degradation (mainly if countries have a lower share of renewables).
Globalisation (also FDI) provides an effective framework for the transfer of polluting industries from developed to developing countries. The relocation of dirty industries phenomenon clashes with the sustainable development goals of the United Nations (such as Goal 10: Reduced Inequalities, Goal 13: Climate Action and Goal 17: Partnerships). The greatest concern is that emissions from polluting industries are transferred to the host country (commonly developing countries), maintaining, or even increasing, the global level of environmental degradation. Considering that the literature points to the relocation of pollutant industries to developing countries with permissive environmental regulation and weak exigence of governance [15], an empirical analysis of regulatory quality and corruption as governance indicators associated with this phenomenon is relevant.
Even though some researchers are investigating the role of FDI and globalisation on environmental degradation, few are using empirical evidence directed to sustainable development. Sustainable development (measured in this study by the Index of Sustainable Economic Welfare) has been a topic of discussion in diverse fields for several years. However, measuring sustainable development is quite difficult, as it must be measured by incorporating three main dimensions: social, economic and environmental (see more in Section 3.1.1). Bearing this in mind, an indicator such as the Index of Sustainable Economic Welfare (ISEW), which considers social, economic and environmental aspects, has an advantage when compared with other indicators (see more in Section 2.3). Globalisation may be considered unsustainable [16], and investigating the role of FDI on recipient countries’ sustainable development depends on the type of FDI, the kind of recipient country and their ecological footprint [17].
The analysis of FDI flow and stock in the same study is scarce in the literature [18]. To address this gap, FDI is analysed through the inward and outward FDI flow and stock to assess the effects of the relocation of pollutant industries. It is not expected that inward FDI flow and stock will have the same role as outward FDI. Therefore, it is expected that inward FDI flow and stock will have more incidence in developing countries than outward FDI. Besides being scarce in the literature, the analysis of this measurement of FDI might avoid biased results and misinterpretation. Therefore, this study innovates by analysing inward and outward FDI flow and stock to give robust empirical evidence of both the effects on environmental degradation and sustainable development due to the relocation of polluting industries.
This study aims to provide measures to combat environmental degradation without compromising sustainable development. Overall, this research innovates by providing an all-embracing analysis of the role of globalisation [19] (economic, social and political de jure and de facto) and FDI (inward and outward FDI flow and stock) on environmental degradation and sustainable development for two groups of countries: developed and developing. In light of this, the central question is “Are globalisation and FDI contributing to environmental degradation, thus compromising sustainable development?” In order to answer the central research question, this paper analyses the role of each dimension and measure of globalisation and inward and outward FDI, flow and stock, on a group of 17 developed countries and a group of 14 developing ones, by performing a comparison between them. Moreover, this paper analyses the role of corruption and regulatory quality on the relocation of polluting industries. These governance indicators were chosen as they are considered in the literature as motivation for the transfer of polluting industries. In a context of energy sources substitution and taking into account the resources widely used by FDI, the sources composition is analysed by considering both fossil fuels and renewable energy sources. This analysis is performed from the longest time period available from 1996 to 2017. Although FDI is considered a long-run phenomenon [20], the transfer of technology to developing countries could instantaneously impact the environment. With this in mind, using a methodology that permits the distinction of effects between the short- and long-run is necessary. The Autoregressive Distributed Lag (ARDL) model is most suitable in this case (see more in Section 3.2). The main findings reveal the requirement to disaggregate overall components, such as globalisation and FDI, by exposing their different effects on CO2 emissions and sustainable development in both groups of countries. Furthermore, governance indicators expose a relevant and distinct role in the countries under analysis, by analysing the regulatory quality and the control of corruption.
Hereinafter, this paper is structured as follows. In Section 2, a debate of the literature about the central topics of globalisation, FDI and sustainable development is given. The third section presents the data, details about ISEW calculation and the methods used in this paper. Section 4 reveals the results. Last, Section 5 and Section 6 contain a discussion and the conclusions of the main results, respectively.

2. Literature Background

The debate section is divided into three subsections aiming to provide an organised literature review. The first subsection contains a review of globalisation literature. The second provides a summary of the FDI–environment nexus literature. Last, the third subsection presents a literature review about sustainable development and the most usual indicators to measure it.

2.1. Globalisation

Globalisation is considered a useful tool helping individuals and economies trade goods and services and allowing countries to share their public policies and culture. However, it has an influential role on production, consumption, the environment and human behaviour. Consequently, it represents varied challenges in the economic, energy and environmental performance areas. The outcomes of globalisation on environmental degradation have been a focus of attention for researchers in recent times [1,4,21,22,23,24,25,26,27] and have revealed that their relationship is far from consensus [6]. On the one hand, globalisation can promote environmental degradation mitigation through the transfer of clean and green technology or by improving and sharing global ecological awareness. Beyond that, it is expected that globalisation contributes to improving countries’ welfare [7]. On the other hand, the deterioration of the environment by globalisation occurs through the stimulation of trade openness and by inducing the relocation of pollutant industries from developed to developing countries, provoking increased resources use. Through the relocation of pollutant industries, globalisation prompts a split of production from consumption, and the appropriate use of natural resources becomes a challenge with increasing globalisation [28].
Throughout the years, diverse globalisation indexes have been proposed. One that stands out is the KOF globalisation index, first presented by Dreher [29], and later improved by Dreher et al. [30]. Constituted by three dimensions, namely, economic, social and political, this index has become the most used globalisation measurement in the literature [31]. This index allows the analysis of globalisation using the KOF overall globalisation index [32] or through the economic, political and social globalisation indexes [33,34,35]. However, the use of these different measurements of globalisation could lead to different results. The studies developed by Suki et al. [36] support both the harmful and beneficial effects of globalisation on the environment. The analyses of the economic, social and political globalisation indexes reveal that economic globalisation increases environmental degradation, and political and social globalisation mitigate it. However, when analysing the overall globalisation index, a damaging effect on the environment was revealed. In light of this, a consensus about the effect of globalisation on the environment may not occur due to the measurement of globalisation used, see, e.g., in [36].
Considering that globalisation is an all-embracing and complex concept, using a proxy or an aggregate index, instead of a comprehensive analysis, could provide results that do not entirely correspond to reality. Recently, and considering the increasing complexity of reality, the KOF globalisation index was revisited by Gygli et al. [31], introducing two new measures of globalisation: de jure and de facto. Gygli et al. [31] provide a complete definition of each globalisation dimension, each measure and the respective subdimensions. This new measurement of globalisation allows a complex and extensive analysis of globalisation and avoids biased findings resulting from the use of aggregate indexes [37]. Even though the analysis of the new measures of globalisation is scarce in the literature [19,26,38], its advantages have already been revealed [37]. Briefly, distinguishing globalisation into de jure and de facto aspects is considered crucial to discern the environmental impacts of globalisation [39]. It is expected that each dimension and measure of globalisation has distinct effects on environmental degradation and sustainable development, in both nature and magnitude. Furthermore, it is also predicted that globalisation has different impacts in developed comparatively to in developing countries.

2.2. Foreign Direct Investment

The nexus between FDI and the environment has positive and negative externalities. Demena and Afesorgbor [18] provide a meta-analysis of the effects of FDI on the environment. There are two main hypotheses empirically tested in this subject: the Pollution Halo and the Pollution Haven Hypotheses. The Pollution Halo hypothesis posits that FDI inflows preserve the environment by reducing emissions [18,40,41,42,43]. The transference of advanced and eco-friendly technologies is the key driver for this [44]. Whereas, when FDI increases pollution, the Pollution Haven Hypothesis is supported [45,46,47,48]. Xie et al. [49] analysed the direct and indirect/spillover effects of FDI on the environment, obtaining validity for both the Pollution Haven Hypothesis, through direct effect, and the Pollution Halo Hypothesis, through spillover effect.
According to Balsalobre et al. [50], the income level of countries influences the environment mainly through three effects: scale, structural or composition, and technique. As FDI could increase income [51], these effects are also considered in the literature about the FDI–Environment nexus [52]. The scale effect is confirmed when FDI inflows increase production, thus raising energy consumption and, consequently, pollution. The structural/composition effect depends on the comparative advantages of an economy [53]. For instance, the impact of FDI differs from an economy specialised in the agriculture sector or the services sector because this transition tends to become less pollutant [50]. Last, the technique effect captures the effect of the diffusion and adoption of improved techniques. Considering all these points, it is possible to claim that the characteristics of recipient countries have great relevance to defining the impact of FDI on environmental degradation.
Nevertheless, as stated by Adeel-Farooq et al. [54], the source country of FDI also determines whether the effects are positive or negative on the recipient country’s environment. Therefore, the impact of FDI on the environment is also defined by what the source country of FDI is seeking. According to Hao et al. [55], this is disaggregated into three categories: resource-seeking, market-seeking and technology/efficiency-seeking. Resource-seeking consists of companies investing in countries with an abundance of resources (human or natural), while market-seeking denotes the search for countries with market potential. Technology-seeking comprises countries entering into high-technology foreign markets to obtain more knowledge and have easier access to technology. Among these three could emerge one more category: the search for a country with lower environmental standards to avoid environmental taxes. This category could encourage developing countries wishing to attract FDI to relax their environmental standards to gain a comparative advantage in pollution-intensive industries [11,56]. Indeed, environmental regulation plays a relevant role in defining the effect of FDI on the environment of recipient countries [41,57]. Under these circumstances, the favourable conditions for the transfer of polluting industries become united: lower environmental standards allow the relocation of polluting industries from developed to developing countries, benefiting both groups of countries, but undermining the environment worldwide.
Regarding the framework under the impact of FDI on the environment, and as both developed and developing countries are under analysis, one expects that outward FDI will impact mainly on developed countries. Moreover, inward FDI (both stock and flow) is predicted to increase emissions in developing countries while decreasing it in developed ones, thus sustaining the Pollution Haven Hypothesis.

2.3. Sustainable Development and Economic Growth

Increasing Gross Domestic Product (GDP) is one of the main goals of countries worldwide, but this objective may hamper sustainable development targets. Besides being powerless to measure welfare and sustainability [58,59,60,61], the goal of growing GDP can have a backlash on human wellbeing [59]. To measure sustainable development, it is crucial to incorporate the three main dimensions of sustainability: economic efficiency, social cohesion and environmental responsibility [62,63]. This is one of the main limitations found across the literature where, generally, sustainable development is measured through the use of indicators such as The Human Development Indicator [64,65] and The Ecological Footprint [17,66], that is, measured as separate indicators [58]. Frugoli et al. [67] compared 10 indices taken from the literature, and recently Kwatra et al. [68] developed a critical perspective of the evolution of sustainable development indices. The Index of Sustainable Economic Welfare (ISEW), brought into use around 1989 by Daly and Cobb [69] (lately improved in 1994 by Cobb and Cobb [70]), is a measure with a more holistic social reporting system of sustainable development than GDP.
The ISEW was introduced in the literature not as a substitute for GDP, but as an additional indicator to complement any analysis of the state of an economy [58]. Lawn [71] provides a comprehensive comparison between the ISEW and other indicators, analysing each component of them. Marques et al. [60] state that countries need to increase their productivity, but this implies future costs, the so-called defensive costs. The ISEW has the advantage of considering the three crucial defensive costs by using variables such as consumption, income inequality and natural resource depletion [60]. These are the typical defensive costs considered in the ISEW computation. They intend to reduce discrepancies in the results of the literature and make it easier to compare countries [61]. Bleys and Whitby [72] present some barriers and opportunities for ISEW calculation.
Briefly, the ISEW allows current and future wellbeing analysis, which is the keystone to sustainable development, ensuring the satisfaction of future generations’ necessities. To the best of our knowledge, the ISEW is considered a useful measure of sustainable development [73]. This indicator is currently under use in the literature, mainly in energy economics literature, such as energy–growth nexus for several areas, for instance, American countries [74], Asian countries [59], Ecuador [75], Europe [61,76], Spain [73] and Sub-Saharan countries [77]. Furthermore, it is also used in food consumption literature [78]. A study developed by Sánchez et al. [75] provides the theories of sustainable development, also explaining each component included in the ISEW calculation. As a result of the predicted impact of FDI on environmental degradation, it is expected that FDI reduces sustainable development in developing countries, and increases it in developed ones, both as inward flow and stock.

3. Data and Methodology

3.1. Data

The relocation of polluting industries is associated with contrasting features among the home and the host country. In light of this, this research aims to analyse two groups of countries with distinct features, such as level of development, income, globalisation and regulatory quality. The countries under analysis are categorised as developed and developing countries by the United Nations [79]. Categorised as developed economies, namely, Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Finland, France, Germany, Ireland, Japan, Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Slovakia, Slovenia, Sweden, Switzerland and the United States, these countries have high levels of income, globalisation and strict environmental regulation. Categorised as developing economies, namely, Algeria, Botswana, Cameroon, Côte d’Ivoire, Egypt, Gabon, Kenya, Madagascar, Malawi, Mauritania, Morocco, Nigeria, South Africa and Tunisia, these countries have low levels of income: globalisation and lax environmental regulation. These two groups of countries were achieved through the available data of inward and outward FDI flow and stock. Regarding the time span, data availability of the governance indicators (corruption index and regulatory quality index) and ISEW computation were the main criterion for the selection. Therefore, two time periods are analysed in order to use the most available data. The models with CO2 emissions as the dependent variable are estimated from 1996 to 2017, while the models with ISEW as the dependent variable are estimated from 2000 to 2017. Table 1 presents the variables under analysis.
The FDI is measured as inward and outward, both stock and flows. Based on the FDI stock definition, it measures the total level of FDI at a given point in time, while FDI flows mean the value of FDI transactions during a given period. As such, it may provide an in-depth analysis of the impacts of FDI on the environment. Both the corruption index and regulatory quality index are used following the definition provided by the World Bank proposed by Kaufmann et al. [81]. The control of corruption index denotes the public perceptions of corruption, while the regulatory quality index denotes the proficiency of the government to developed and execute policies and regulations that encourage the development of the private sector. These indexes, as defined by the World Bank, are measured on a scale ranging from −2.5 to 2.5. The negative value denotes permissive governance, which means maximum corruption and low regulatory quality, while the positive value denotes rigorous governance, which means minimum corruption and high regulatory quality. The measurement of regulatory quality within developed and developing countries is often quite different due to the lower transparency of bureaucratic indicators mainly in developing countries. Thus, it is worthwhile to note that these variables are used mainly due to the data availability to allow a comparison between countries.

3.1.1. Index for Sustainable Economic Welfare (ISEW)

In contrast to GDP, the ISEW is an indicator that aims to measure sustainable economic welfare. This indicator is used as a proxy of sustainable development, see, e.g., in [61,78]. Based on economic, environmental and social dimensions, the ISEW is an aggregate indicator for present and future wellbeing. As announced by Menegaki et al. [76], welfare is an uncertain and multifaceted concept; therefore, a composite indicator is crucial to measure it. An ISEW computation starts with the personal consumption expenditure weighted for income inequality, considering the advantages that rich countries benefit from economic growth contrasted to poorer countries. To this, positive welfare magnitudes, such as public health and education expenditures, are added and negative welfare magnitudes, such as environmental costs (defensive costs), are subtracted.
The ISEW calculation process employed in this research is adopted from studies such as Menegaki et al., Marques et al., and Menegaki and Tsagarakis [76,78,82]. Equation (1) describes the ISEW analysed in the study:
I S E W = C w   +   G e h   +   K n   +   S     N     C s ,
where C w symbolises the weighted private consumption, G e h means the non-defensive public expenditure, K n denotes the net capital growth, S measures the unpaid work benefit, N consists of the depletion of the natural environment and C s defines the cost of social issues.
Some limitations were faced during the ISEW calculation process, such as the lack of social costs data, as handled by Menegaki et al. and Marques et al. [76,78]. Therefore, social costs were not included in the ISEW calculation. The parameters used in the calculation process of ISEW are presented in Table 2.
Owing to a lack of observations in the GINI coefficient data for a small number of countries, the missing values were calculated through the trend of the available years, see, e.g., in [80]. For example, for Botswana, Kenya, Mozambique, South Africa and Tunisia, data on the last two years were lacking and they were calculated accordingly.

3.1.2. Preliminary Analysis

A preliminary analysis to evaluate the data features was conducted. Correlation is a common concern in panel data analysis. In light of this, the coefficients of the correlation matrix were assessed. Therefore, in order to avoid correlation between the variables, specific transformations were performed, namely, GDP, CO2 and ISEW were transformed into per capita (pc), and FF and RES were transformed into a percentage of primary energy consumption. Descriptive statistics of the variables under analysis for both groups of countries and both time periods are displayed in Table 3 and Table 4.
Panel data specification tests were performed, such as the cross section dependence test (CD-test). Cross-sectional dependence is a common phenomenon in panel data settings, and it can lead to inconsistent outcomes once the presence of cross section dependence can bias the results of the first-generation unit root tests. Introduced by Pesaran [83], the CD-test is displayed in Table 5 and Table 6.
As displayed in Table 5 and Table 6, the null hypothesis of cross-sectional independence is rejected, confirming the presence of cross-sectional dependence for most of the variables. Therefore, the second-generation unit root test (CIPS) proposed by Pesaran [84], which is robust in the presence of cross-sectional dependence, was performed (Table 7 and Table 8).
Considering the time periods under analysis, over which diverse events could have occurred, the suspicion of the existence of structural breaks arises in the series. In light of this, the assessment of the variables unit root was taken further and as commonly used in energy economics research, see, e.g., in [19,85,86,87] the unit root test with structural breaks Zivot and Andrews [88] was conducted. Accordingly, the results of this test corroborate the results of the second-generation unit root test (the results are not presented to preserve space but available upon request). Besides that, the break points identified might be included and tested as impulse dummy variables in the estimations to control events that might have occurred in the series.

3.2. Methodology

Introduced in the literature by Pesaran and Smith [89] and Pesaran et al. [90], the ARDL model has diverse characteristics that can be considered as a benefit. This model is used to accomplish the main objective of this study as it allows the analysis of the dynamics of variables, disaggregating the impacts in both the short- and long-run. Furthermore, this approach is considered flexible as it permits the use of variables with distinct integration order, stationary in level or integrated of order one, I(0) and I(1), or borderline. Besides, this model allows the control of potential events through the inclusion of dummies, additionally dealing with cointegration and endogeneity issues.
The general ARDL model is provided in Equation (2):
Δ φ t = β i + ϑ i 1 Δ θ t + p = 1 k β 1 i φ t p + p = 1 k β 2 i θ t p + μ i , t
where φ t denotes the vector of dependent variables, β i represents the intercept, ϑ i 1 denotes the semi-elasticities, θ t denotes the vector of independent variables, β 1 i consists of the error correction mechanism (ECM), β 2 i denotes the elasticities and μ i , t denotes the error term.
Following the general ARDL model structure, Equation (3) represents the models estimated with the ISEW:
D L I S E W _ P C i t = α 0 + j = 0 n η i 1 D L C O 2 _ P C i t + j = 0 n η i 2 D L N R E S _ P i t + j = 0 n η i 3 D L R E S _ P i t + j = 0 n η i 4 D F D I _ F i t + j = 0 n η i 5 D F D I _ S i t + j = 0 n η i 6 D L K O F E C D F i t + j = 0 n η i 7 D L K O F E C D J i t + j = 0 n η i 8 D L K O F S O D F i t + j = 0 n η i 9 D L K O F S O D J i t + j = 0 n η i 10 D L K O F P O D F i t + j = 0 n η i 11 D L K O F P O D J i t + j = 0 n η i 12 D C O R R i t + j = 0 n η i 13 D R Q i t + ω i 1 L I S E W _ P C i t 1 + ω i 2 L C O 2 _ P C i t 1 + ω i 3 L N R E S _ P i t 1 + ω i 4 L R E S _ P i t 1 + ω i 5 F D I _ F i t 1 + ω i 6 F D I _ S i t 1 + ω i 7 L K O F E C D F i t 1 + ω i 8 L K O F E C D J i t 1 + ω i 9 L K O F S O D F i t 1 + ω i 10 L K O F S O D J i t 1 + ω i 11 L K O F P O D F i t 1 + ω i 12 L K O F P O D J i t 1 + ω i 13 C O R R i t 1 + ω i 14 R Q i t 1 + ε i t
Equation (4) represents the models estimated with CO2 emissions as a dependent variable:
D L C O 2 _ P C i t = α 0 + j = 0 n η i 1 D L G D P _ P C i t + j = 0 n η i 2 D L N R E S _ P i t + j = 0 n η i 3 D L R E S _ P i t + j = 0 n η i 4 D F D I _ F i t + j = 0 n η i 5 D F D I _ S i t + j = 0 n η i 6 D L K O F E C D F i t + j = 0 n η i 7 D L K O F E C D J i t + j = 0 n η i 8 D L K O F S O D F i t + j = 0 n η i 9 D L K O F S O D J i t + j = 0 n η i 10 D L K O F P O D F i t + j = 0 n η i 11 D L K O F P O D J i t + j = 0 n η i 12 D C O R R i t + j = 0 n η i 13 D R Q i t + ω i 1 L C O 2 _ P C i t 1 + ω i 2 L G D P _ P C i t 1 + ω i 3 L N R E S _ P i t 1 + ω i 4 L R E S _ P i t 1 + ω i 5 F D I _ F i t 1 + ω i 6 F D I _ S i t 1 + ω i 7 L K O F E C D F i t 1 + ω i 8 L K O F E C D J i t 1 + ω i 9 L K O F S O D F i t 1 + ω i 10 L K O F S O D J i t 1 + ω i 11 L K O F P O D F i t 1 + ω i 12 L K O F P O D J i t 1 + ω i 13 C O R R i t 1 + ω i 14 R Q i t 1 + ε i t
In these equations, prefix D indicates first differences, α 0 exemplifies the intercept, n is the lag order, η i represents the estimated parameters in the short-run, ω i denotes the estimated parameters in the long-run and ε i t symbolises the error term.
The estimation of models with diverse explanatory variables could raise the suspicion of multicollinearity among them and consequently raise concerns regarding the confidence in the results and variables’ significance. In light of this, the variance inflation factor (VIF) statistics were assessed, revealing potential multicollinearity among FDI_si and FDI_so in the models of the developed countries. Therefore, these two variables were not estimated simultaneously, and two separate models were estimated for FDI_si (models I and III) and for FDI_so (models II and IV). Furthermore, a high correlation between KOFSODF and KOFSODJ in the model of the developing countries was noticed. Consequently, two separate models were estimated for KOFSODF (models V and VII) and for KOFSODJ (models VI and VIII). Furthermore, in the developing countries’ models, a high correlation between CO2_pc and GDP_pc was reversed through estimation the model with CO2 instead of CO2_pc.
The Hausman test was employed to choose the most appropriated estimator to use. The null hypothesis under this test is that the random effects are appropriate, and the results are presented in Table 9.
The rejection of the null hypothesis displayed above supports that the fixed effects estimator is the most appropriate estimator to use. Considering that, some specification tests were conducted to assess the presence of contemporaneous correlation, namely, Pesaran [83], Frees [91] and Friedman [92] tests. The presence of heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation were assessed through Modified Wald and Wooldridge tests, respectively (Table 10).
The results from the previous tests emphasise that the Driscoll–Kraay [93] estimator is the most appropriated estimator to use, as it can deal with the presence of cross section dependence, contemporaneous correlation, first-order serial correlation and heteroskedasticity. This estimator considers cross-sectional dependence and assumes that the error structure is heteroskedastic, autocorrelated and correlated among the groups in the panel.

4. Results

The estimations of the ARDL model and Driscoll–Kraay estimator for both the ISEW and CO2 as dependent variables and for both groups of countries are displayed in Table 11. Bearing in mind the results of the unit roots test with structural breaks, the break points were tested in the models. Therefore, the dummy variables in 2009 and 2010 were supported by this test and demonstrated a notable adherence to an actual event, the global recession. The dummy variable included in the CO2 models of developed and developing countries reflects a decline in CO2 emissions provoked by a decrease in economic activity during the financial crisis (2008−2009) [94]. In turn, the effect on sustainable development was, on the one hand, through the reduction in capital growth (Kn component of the ISEW computation) and, on the other hand, through defensive costs (N component of the ISEW computation). In developed countries, this effect was immediate, and the dummy variable was included in 2009 in the ISEW model of developed countries. While in developing countries, the effect was more evident in 2010.
Besides the conducted analyses of FDI in the disaggregated form (inward and outward FDI flow and stock) provided in Table 11, FDI was also analysed as a flow and stock, by subtracting outward from inward. By comparing the outcomes of both analyses, a higher complexity in developed countries was revealed than in developing ones. On the one hand, the similarity between models for developing countries provides further support for the main findings displayed in Table 11. On the other hand, a few changes that occurred in the developed countries’ models revealed a complexity in developed countries that must be deeply analysed. This complexity could come from the diverse purposes that FDI is looking for in the developed economies, such as comparative advantages, namely, expertise and highly qualified workforce, research and development capabilities, and harnessing economies of agglomeration and clustering. In the developing economies, the aim of FDI is more predictable, in the sense that it is associated with more evident factors, such as comparative advantage on labour factor where labour-intensive industries do not necessarily require highly qualified workers. Overall, FDI in developing economies is related to more standardised and stabilised processes, while in developed ones, FDI could be a more innovative and even disruptive investment.
The analysis of FDI in the developed economies reveals that FDI stock affects the environment contrary to the effect produced on sustainable development. Both inward and outward FDI stock produced mitigation of environmental degradation and an improvement of sustainable development, suggesting that the improvement in the ISEW occurs through the reduction of the CO2 emissions damage costs (a component of the depletion of the natural environment (N) on the ISEW computation). In the developing economies, the stock of FDI also increases sustainable development through inward FDI; however, it increases environmental degradation as well. In these economies, inward FDI flow is the one that produced an effect on the environment contrary to the effect produced on sustainable development, reducing environmental degradation and improving sustainable development.
The analysis of globalisation through each dimension and measure proved to be useful as well. It showed an effect on the environment contrary to the effect on sustainable development in both groups of countries. Economic globalisation de jure raises environmental degradation and reduces sustainable development in both groups of countries. Contrasting, social globalisation improves sustainable development in both groups of countries, together with political globalisation de jure, while political globalisation de facto is harmful to it. Concerning governance, regulation quality mitigates environmental degradation, meanwhile, corruption, which can be a business enabler and consequently increases GDP, benefits sustainable development by increasing capital growth (Kn of ISEW computation) in both groups of countries. It is worth highlighting that the Error Correction Model (ECM) of all models is highly significant and discloses a moderate speed of adjustment to the long-run equilibrium.
The estimations shown in Table 11 resulted from using the longest time period available. In light of this, the models were estimated for different time periods. However, in order to provide results that might be more comparable, the same preliminary procedures are executed (see Table A1 and Table A2 in Appendix A), and Table A3 in Appendix A reveals the models with CO2 emissions as the dependent variable, estimated from 2000 to 2017. Overall, these results are similar to the results presented in Table 11, with the exceptions of loss of statistically significance of the regulatory quality in both groups of countries as well as energy consumption from renewable energy sources only in the developed countries. These two small changes could be a consequence of the exclusion of important environmental marks, such as the Kyoto protocol, which demonstrates the relevance of its inclusion and the use of the longest time period available. All the main findings are further discussed in the following section.

5. Discussion

The achievement of sustainable development goals is a global objective, but some countries could be facing more barriers than others to reach this. In developing countries, renewable energy consumption is not adequate enough to shrink environmental degradation as its use remains statistically insignificant, which is also found with sustainable development. Both of these outcomes are entirely predictable. As announced by Zaidi and Saidi [95], developing countries have lower available resources to implement measures to mitigate climate changes. In developed countries, renewable energy consumption has the capability to reduce environmental degradation, which reflects the high levels of investment in renewables. However, this only occurs in the short-run, suggesting that the level of investment does not meet the rising energy demand. Regarding sustainable development, renewable energy consumption seems to be decreasing it in the long-run in developed countries. As these countries have more investment in renewables, this could inhibit economic growth when the investments are supported by the government. As sustainable development is embodied by social, economic and environmental dimensions, these costs could be affecting the economic one. Fossil fuel consumption increases environmental degradation in the short- and long-run in developed and developing countries, reflecting the urgency to reduce fossil fuel dependence and increase renewable energy consumption.
The impact of corruption could depend on the objectives of the investor. Indeed, Barassi and Zhou [96] consider that corruption could attract investment when the investor chooses the host country aiming to benefit from corruption; otherwise, corruption could inhibit investment. Thus, there are two main hypotheses in the literature that analyse the impact of corruption on investments. On the one hand, the positive effect of corruption on investments is sustained in the literature as the “Helping Hand Hypothesis”, as corruption may speed the bureaucratic processes [97]. However, this only happens when investment revenues overcome the costs of corruption [98]. On the other hand, the “Grabbing Hand hypothesis” sustains the negative effect of corruption, as the indirect taxes/bribes could discourage investment [97], hampering economic growth [99]. In this study, the control of corruption (thus diminishing corruption) expands sustainable development. As such, this group of developing countries could increase their level of sustainable development by increasing their control of corruption, which could attract more investment. Considering both hypotheses, note that corruption must not be assumed as a driver for sustainable development, as it can represent long-term adverse effects that would inhibit future investments, thus undermining the growth of economies [100].
Regulatory quality, on the one hand, stimulates sustainable development in developed countries. On the other hand, regulatory quality diminishes sustainable development in developing countries. As a result, regulatory quality in developed countries incites sustainable development, perhaps due to the reduction in defensive costs (N component of ISEW computation), as the regulatory quality reduces environmental degradation. However, while regulatory quality reduces environmental degradation in developing countries, the negative impact on investment level seems larger than the relevance of reducing defensive costs. As stated by Dartey-Baah [62], the accomplishment of sustainable development goals in developing countries depends on effective leadership. Briefly, regulatory quality has a relevant role in mitigating CO2 emissions: it contributes to a sharp reduction in investments in developing countries, as they are frequently chosen as recipient countries for polluting industries.
Focusing on globalisation, the results obtained provide evidence that globalisation measures can have distinct effects on environmental degradation and sustainable development, in both nature and/or magnitude. Globalisation revealed some opposite effects on environmental degradation compared with the effects on sustainable development in both groups of countries. Economic globalisation de jure is related to trade taxes and investment restrictions, and as stated by Rudolph and Figge [101], high economically globalised countries have a high ecological footprint. Thus, economic globalisation de jure increases environmental degradation and simultaneously reduces sustainable development in both groups of countries. By increasing environmental degradation, the defensive costs (N component of ISEW computation) will consequently increase, suggesting that any decrease in sustainable development could be due to an increase in defensive costs. Regarding developing economies, this effect could be explained by investment restrictions which cause the continued use of older and more polluting technologies, consequently increasing environmental degradation.
Regarding social globalisation, both de jure and de facto measures contribute to increasing sustainable development and environmental degradation in the developing economies. A possible cause for that could be explained by the fact that these countries are an international tourism destination and trade in cultural goods recipients [26]. Despite increasing environmental degradation, social globalisation contributes to sustainable development, which suggests that, although social globalisation provokes environmental degradation, the increase of capital growth offsets the increase of defensive costs. In turn, in the developed economies, social globalisation de facto mitigates environmental degradation. This could be explained by the easier access to information components such as the use of internet and access to reliable media that could enhance environmental awareness, as stated by Ahmed et al. [102]. The improvement that social globalisation de facto provokes in sustainable development might come from the reduction in the defensive costs (damage from CO2 emissions (N)) reflected in lower emissions.
Last, while political globalisation de facto contributes to environmental quality improvement, political globalisation de jure increases environmental degradation in the developing economies under analysis. As referred by Leal et al. [26], the mitigation effect of de facto measures could be explained by the dissemination of environmental policies among countries, while the positive effect of de jure measures could provide evidence of a lack of success on global environmental management. In developed countries, political globalisation de facto reduces sustainable development, while political globalisation de jure improves it, which could be explained by the international treaties that prompt economic development. In short, sustainable development in developed countries is prompted by social globalisation de facto, as it shrinks CO2 emissions, and by political globalisation de jure. In developing countries, social globalisation, both de jure and de facto, is also contributing to sustainable development, but contrary to the effect on developed countries, in developing ones, social globalisation increases environmental degradation as political globalisation de jure. However, political globalisation de facto mitigates environmental degradation in developing countries.

5.1. The Foreign Direct Investment Impacts

Looking carefully at the FDI stock definition, it measures the total level of FDI at a given point in time, while FDI flows mean the value of FDI transactions during a given period. As expected, FDI behaves differently in the groups of countries under analysis. The stock of FDI both inward and outward revealed opposite effects on environmental degradation compared with the effects on sustainable development in the developed economies. Regarding the mitigation of environmental degradation, inward and outward FDI stock reduce emissions and increase sustainable development in developed countries. The effect of inward FDI stock reflects more environmental awareness and that these countries are receiving environmentally friendly FDI with the transfer of efficient technologies. This is also supported by the mitigating effect of inward FDI flow on environmental degradation in the developed countries. Consequently, one observes a decrease in defensive costs (N component of ISEW computation); inward FDI stock contributes to an increase in sustainable development. In turn, the outcome of outward FDI stock is anticipated and could suggest that polluting industries have been relocated from developed countries to developing countries, transferring emissions. Nonetheless, it is also important to consider that outward FDI could represent a production transfer, thus reducing energy consumption and environmental degradation.
Inward FDI stock is damaging the developing countries’ environment, which could mean that these countries are receiving polluting industries, thus supporting the Pollution Haven Hypothesis. Therefore, inward FDI stock induces environmental degradation as it considers the industries already relocated and installed. This means that the effect of inward FDI measured as stock represents the accumulation effect of FDI on the environment [103]. Thus, this result is not unexpected in developing countries. Inward FDI flow appears to reduce CO2 emissions and be environmentally conscious in the long-run in developing countries, thus contributing to environmental preservation. The greater the gap between the technological level in the source country of FDI and the recipient ones, the greater the effect of the introduction of technological processes [104]. This outcome may not be a consequence of an increase in environmental stringency in developing countries, but it might suggest that source countries are no longer transferring obsolete technologies.
Regarding sustainable development in developing countries, it has been positively affected by inward FDI both as a flow and stock. Following the assumption that FDI induces economic growth, this outcome is expected. As FDI increases income and the rate of employment, then the social consequences are reduced while FDI is increasing [105]. This means that, besides contributing to economic development, FDI could improve social welfare [104]. Briefly, the attraction of foreign investors could support developing countries to reach the sustainable development goals proposed by the United Nations [63]. However, how could it be possible to suggest attracting foreign investors while inward FDI stock is contributing to environmental degradation? The answer is that the harmful effect that inward FDI stock provokes on the environment is offset by the improvement in sustainable development through the increase in economic capital. In short, the main findings provide evidence for the transfer of polluting industries from developed to developing countries, supporting the Pollution Haven Hypothesis. However, inward FDI flows bring developing countries environmentally friendly technology, revealing that they are no longer receiving obsolete and pollutant technology. It announces that FDI could be mandatory to reach sustainable development goals, mainly in developing countries, but they must receive these technologies and knowledge, and adopt them in their own production process.
The main findings expose a potential new paradigm under the analysis of the relocation of polluting industries. While inward FDI stock supports the transfer of polluting industries, inward FDI flow uncovers the indirect role of the investment in innovation in developed countries. Besides, this result also reveals the crucial role of energy consumption. Although the adoption of energy-efficient techniques through FDI could be considered as crucial to reduce emissions [106], the energy source might also be taken into account. Most of the energy consumed in developing countries comes from fossil fuels, as these countries also lower the availability of resources to invest in renewable energy projects. This means that an increase in energy consumption in developing countries will rise pollution (which is supported by the results). Thus, besides diminishing environmental regulation discrepancies among developed and developing countries, the governments of developing countries must attract investment towards renewable energy generation projects. Moreover, these countries ought to improve their governance standards by increasing the control of corruption, as they could attract more investment, also contributing to sustainable development. The investment in innovation towards Research and Development grants, for example, must be steadily encouraged in developed countries.

5.2. Research Gaps and Future Lines of Research

This investigation is developed under the objective of filling some gaps found in the literature. Indeed, each dimension and measure of globalisation is considered. The results reveal the suitability of conducting this disaggregation as it could have different impacts in nature and/or magnitude. Furthermore, to better discern the transfer of polluting industries from developed to developing countries, inward and outward FDI are analysed, both as flow and stock. Besides, the measurement of sustainable development by the ISEW is innovative in this subject. By analysing and comparing developed and developing countries, it was fulfilled a gap in the literature by analysing whether globalisation and FDI are harming environmental degradation and compromising sustainable development.
Environmental degradation has become one of the biggest challenges facing the planet. Resources are scarce, and the environment is considered within this scarcity. The fight against climate change is urgent, and although some countries are taking significant steps towards environmental degradation mitigation, others are ignoring this urgency. The Glasgow summit (26th United Nations Climate Change Conference of the Parties (COP26) in Glasgow), originally scheduled to take place in November 2020, has been rescheduled to November 2021 as a consequence of the current COVID-19 pandemic situation. The Paris Agreement (COP21) outlined the necessity to meet every five years to re-evaluate the current state of climate change. COP26 is the first time that parties are expected to commit to enhancing the ambition to tackle climate change. A key topic of discussion at the Glasgow summit should be the transfer of pollutant industries to developing countries. It is in these countries that the transfer has the greatest repercussions, and as a driver of environmental degradation, mechanisms to discourage it and/or compensate those host countries receiving it should be a focus.
This study suggests that future lines of research could involve conducting a similar analysis to the present one by considering other indicators of sustainable development, including social, economic and environmental aspects of sustainability. Furthermore, the use of ecological footprint as a proxy for environmental degradation could bring an interesting discussion to compare results with a sustainable development indicator, as it is used in the literature as a proxy for both environmental degradation, see, e.g., in [102], and sustainable development, see, e.g., in [17,66]. Further research could also include more governance indicators such as the rule of law and political stability, as they could influence the investment decisions of foreign investors.

6. Conclusions

This research was undertaken with the objective of evaluating the nature of polluting industries transfer from developed to developing countries. To do that, this study analyses the influence of FDI (measured as inward and outward FDI flow and stock) on environmental degradation. This study also aims to analyse the consequences of the phenomenon of industry relocation on sustainable development (measured through the ISEW) for both home and host countries. This research goes beyond innovating through analysing the specific effect of inward and outward FDI flow and stock on developed and developing economies; the influence of each dimension and measure of globalisation is considered as well. Additionally, governance indicators were included in the analysis. The analysis of both inward and outward FDI flow and stock, and the analysis of globalisation through the three dimensions and two measures, make it possible to go deeper into the study of the complexity of globalisation and FDI on the environment, and to the best of our knowledge, this approach is innovative.
When looking for governance indicators, the effect of corruption seems to be helpful to reach sustainability. Corruption may speed bureaucratic processes and assumes the role of business facilitator. However, corruption can represent long-term adverse effects that could be undermining the growth of economies. Regarding regulatory quality, it reduces environmental degradation in both groups of countries, which helps countries to reach sustainable development goals. In developed countries, this beneficial environmental effect is reflected in an increase in sustainable growth through the reduction of environmental costs. In the developing ones, the loss of capital growth is not offset by the reduction in environmental costs, thus reducing sustainable development. These effects evidenced the lax and undemanding environmental regulation in the developing countries analysed in the study.
The analysis of inward and outward FDI flow and stock in developed countries reveals that both improve environmental quality and sustainable development. In these countries, the reduction in emissions that consequently leads to a reduction in defensive costs (damage from CO2 emissions (N)) results in improved sustainable development. On the one hand, inward FDI flow and stock suggest that the investments received by developed economies have an environmental awareness background. On the other hand, the environmental mitigation effect of outward FDI stock in developed countries might suggest that emissions have been transferred through the relocation of pollutant industries to developing countries. As a result, inward FDI stock in both the short- and long-run increases environmental degradation in developing countries.
The undemanding environmental regulation in developing countries adds to the defensive costs that are subsequently offset by capital growth. Inward FDI stock provokes an improvement in sustainable development. As is evidenced by the effects of regulatory quality in developing countries, this research maintains that it is necessary to implement measures that encourage these countries to improve their environmental regulation. Notwithstanding, it is essential to compensate recipient countries for the loss of investment that may result from tightening environmental legislation.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, P.H.L., R.V.C., and A.C.M.; methodology, P.H.L.; software, P.H.L.; validation, P.H.L., R.V.C., and A.C.M.; formal analysis, P.H.L., R.V.C., and A.C.M.; investigation, P.H.L., and R.V.C.; resources, P.H.L., and R.V.C.; data curation, P.H.L., and R.V.C.; writing—original draft preparation, P.H.L., and R.V.C.; writing—review and editing, A.C.M.; visualization, A.C.M.; supervision, A.C.M.; project administration, A.C.M.; funding acquisition, A.C.M. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research was funded by NECE-UBI—Research Unit in Business Science and Economics, Portugal, Project no. UIDB/04630/2020, and PhD fellowship (2020.06026.BD), both sponsored by the FCT—Portuguese Foundation for the Development of Science and Technology, Ministry of Science, Technology and Higher Education, Portugal. And this research was also funded by Santander Universities through “Scholarships BID/UBI-Santander Universities/2020”.

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

Publicly available datasets were analysed in this study. This data can be found here: https://www.eia.gov/environment/data.php (accessed on 12 November 2020); https://unctadstat.unctad.org/wds/ReportFolders/reportFolders.aspx (accessed on 12 November 2020); https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/NY.GDP.MKTP.KD (accessed on 13 November 2020); https://databank.worldbank.org/source/worldwide-governance-indicators (accessed on 13 November 2020); https://www.eia.gov/totalenergy/data/annu (accessed on 12 November 2020); https://kof.ethz.ch/en/forecasts-and-indicators/indicators/kof-globalisation-index.html (accessed on 13 November 2020).

Acknowledgments

The authors would like to gratefully acknowledge the generous financial support of the NECE-UBI—Research Unit in Business Science and Economics, Portugal, Project no. UIDB/04630/2020, and a PhD fellowship (2020.06026.BD), both sponsored by the FCT—Portuguese Foundation for the Development of Science and Technology, Ministry of Science, Technology and Higher Education, Portugal. The financial support of Santander Universities through “Scholarships BID/UBI-Santander Universities/2020” is also gratefully acknowledged. We would also like to express our acknowledgements for the anonymous reviewers’ comments that greatly contributed to improving the quality of the paper.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A

Table A1. Hausman test and F-test for CO2 model (2000–2017).
Table A1. Hausman test and F-test for CO2 model (2000–2017).
Developed CountriesDeveloping Countries
I-CO2 Model with FDI_siII-CO2 Model with FDI_soV-CO2 Model with KOFSODFVI-CO2 Model with KOFSODJ
F-test4.85 ***4.94 ***3.14 ***3.19 ***
Hausman test62.73 ***63.60 ***36.03 ***36.45 ***
Notes: *** denotes significance level at 1%.
Table A2. Specification tests for CO2 model (2000–2017).
Table A2. Specification tests for CO2 model (2000–2017).
Developed CountriesDeveloping Countries
I-CO2 Model with FDI_siII-CO2 Model with FDI_soV-CO2 Model with KOFSODFVI-CO2 Model with KOFSODJ
Pesaran test7.509 ***7.788 ***2.544 **2.209 **
Frees test0.332 ***0.461 ***0.1200.035
Fiedman test51.188 ***51.497 ***28.980 ***27.966 ***
Modified Wald test297.30 ***281.42 ***184.68 ***215.26 ***
Wooldrige test125.361 ***98.212 ***45.098 ***52.334 ***
Notes: ***, ** denotes significance level at 1%, and 5%, respectively.
Table A3. Estimations of ARDL model—both models CO2 and ISEW from 2000 to 2017.
Table A3. Estimations of ARDL model—both models CO2 and ISEW from 2000 to 2017.
Developed CountriesDeveloping Countries
CO2 ModelISEW ModelISEW Model CO2 Model
I-FDI_siII-FDI_soIII-FDI_siIV-FDI_soVII-KOFSODFVIII-KOFSODJ V-KOFSODFVI-KOFSODJ
DLGDP_pc0.5847***0.6435 *** DLGDP_pc
DLCO2_pc DLCO2
DFDI_fi−0.0009 ***−0.0009 *** 0.015 ***0.0128 ***DFDI_fi
DFDI_fo DFDI_fo−0.0112 **−0.0115 **
DFDI_si DFDI_si0.0024 **0.0018 *
DFDI_so DFDI_so
DLFF_p0.905 ***0.9220 *** DLFF_p1.8024 ***1.7209 ***
DLRES_p DLRES_p −0.0245 **
DCORR 0.0976 **0.0892 **0.2731 ** DCORR
DRQ 0.0693 ** −0.2738 * DRQ
DLKOFECDF −0.8967 ***−0.9049 *** DLKOFECDF
DLKOFECDJ −0.5456 ***DLKOFECDJ0.1956 ***0.1809 ***
DLKOFSODF 0.9839 ***0.837 **0.4057 ** DLKOFSODF
DLKOFSODJ 0.9309 ***DLKOFSODJ
DLKOFPODF DLKOFPODF
DLKOFPODJ DLKOFPODJ
LISEW_pc (­−1) −0.1407 ***−0.1401 ***−0.7447 ***−0.7586 ***LISEW_pc (−1)
LCO2_pc (−1)−0.3448 ***−0.3264 ***0.2863 ***0.2597 ***0.3267 **0.2485 **LCO2 (−1)−0.2775 ***−0.2946 ***
LGDP_pc (−1) LGDP_pc (−1)
FDI_fi (−1) FDI_fi (−1)−0.0046 **−0.0034 **
FDI_fo (−1) FDI_fo (−1)
FDI_si (−1)−0.0002 * 0.0012 *** 0.008 ***0.0051 ***FDI_si (−1)0.0012 **
FDI_so (­­−1) −0.0002 ** 0.00068 *** FDI_so (−1)
LFF_p (−1)0.5075 ***0.4883 *** LFF_p (−1)0.6997 ***0.7817 ***
LRES_p (−1) −0.0496 ***−0.0658 *** LRES_p (−1)
CORR (−1) 0.1028 ***0.0895 ***0.3039 **0.2419 **CORR (−1)
RQ (−1) RQ (−1)
LKOFECDF (−1) LKOFECDF (−1)
LKOFECDJ (−1) −0.5117 ***−0.5396 ***−0.4261 *−0.5397 **LKOFECDJ (−1)
LKOFSODF (−1)−0.2894 ***−0.2357 *** 0.7076 *** LKOFSODF (−1)0.0755 **
LKOFSODJ (−1) 1.5626 ***LKOFSODJ (−1) 0.1910 **
LKOFPODF (−1)−0.3895 *** −0.8895 ***−0.8307 *** LKOFPODF (−1)−0.1576 ***−0.1181 **
LKOFPODJ (−1)0.2196 ** 1.1089 ***1.1739 *** LKOFPODJ (−1)0.4386 **0.4674 **
C−4.0770 ***−4.7775 ***5.8755 ***5.2215 ***8.5173 ***4.4613 *C−3.8549 **−4.8995 ***
Dum_2009 −0.1923 ***−0.2006 *** Dum_2009−0.1007 ***−0.0979 ***
Dum_2010 0.0806 **0.14405 ***Dum_2010
Dum_2014−0.0212 ***−0.0210 ***
Elasticities
LCO2_pc (−1) 2.0346 *1.8545 *0.4387 ***0.3276 **LCO2 (−1)
LGDP_pc (−1) LGDP_pc (−1)
FDI_fi (−1) FDI_fi (−1)−0.0166 ***−0.0117 ***
FDI_fo (−1) FDI_fo (−1)
FDI_si (−1)−0.0004 ** 0.0088 ** 0.0107 ***0.0067 ***FDI_si (−1)0.0045 ***
FDI_so (−1) −0.0006 *** 0.0049 ** FDI_so (−1)
LFF_p (−1)1.4719 ***1.4957 *** LFF_p (−1)2.5214 ***2.654 ***
LRES_p (−1) −0.3522 ***−0.4698 *** LRES_p (−1)
CORR (−1) 0.7308 ***0.6391 **0.4081 **0.3189 **CORR (−1)
RQ (−1) RQ (−1)
LKOFECDF (−1) LKOFECDF (−1)
LKOFECDJ (−1) −3.6371 *−3.8532 *−0.5721 **−0.7115 ***LKOFECDJ (−1)
LKOFSODF (−1)−0.8394 ***−0.7221 *** 0.9501 *** LKOFSODF (−1)0.272 **
LKOFSODJ (−1) 2.06 ***LKOFSODJ (−1) 0.6484 **
LKOFPODF (−1)-1.1295 *** −6.3223 **−5.9316 ** LKOFPODF (−1)−0.5677 ***−0.4009 ***
LKOFPODJ (−1)0.6370*** 7.8818 **8.3822 ** LKOFPODJ (−1)1.5803 ***1.5869 ***
Notes: ***, **, * denotes significance level at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively; prefix D denotes Differences; prefix L denotes Logarithm; Dum denotes dummy; C denotes constant; Values in bold and italic are the ECM.

References

  1. Rahman, M.M. Environmental degradation: The role of electricity consumption, economic growth and globalisation. J. Environ. Manag. 2020, 253, 109742. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Intriligator, M.D. Globalization of the world economy: Potential benefits and costs and a net assessment. J. Policy Model. 2004, 26, 485–498. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Ulucak, R.; Koçak, E.; Erdoğan, S.; Kassouri, Y. Investigating the non-linear effects of globalization on material consumption in the EU countries: Evidence from PSTR estimation. Resour. Policy 2020, 67, 101667. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Bilgili, F.; Ulucak, R.; Koçak, E.; İlkay, S.Ç. Does globalization matter for environmental sustainability? Empirical investigation for Turkey by Markov regime switching models. Environ. Sci. Pollut. Res. 2020, 27, 1087–1100. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Zhu, K.; Jiang, X. Slowing down of globalization and global CO2 emissions—A causal or casual association? Energy Econ. 2019, 84, 104483. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Rafindadi, A.A.; Usman, O. Globalization, energy use, and environmental degradation in South Africa: Startling empirical evidence from the Maki-cointegration test. J. Environ. Manag. 2019, 244, 265–275. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  7. Shahbaz, M.; Shahzad, S.J.H.; Mahalik, M.K. Is Globalization Detrimental to CO2 Emissions in Japan? New Threshold Analysis. Environ. Model. Assess. 2018, 23, 557–568. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  8. Mishkin, F.S. Globalization and financial development. J. Dev. Econ. 2009, 89, 164–169. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. You, W.; Lv, Z. Spillover effects of economic globalization on CO2 emissions: A spatial panel approach. Energy Econ. 2018, 73, 248–257. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Muhammad, B.; Khan, S. Effect of bilateral FDI, energy consumption, CO2 emission and capital on economic growth of Asia countries. Energy Rep. 2019, 5, 1305–1315. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Singhania, M.; Saini, N. Demystifying pollution haven hypothesis: Role of FDI. J. Bus. Res. 2021, 123, 516–528. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. De Pascale, G.; Sardaro, R.; Faccilongo, N.; Contò, F. What is the influence of FDI and international people flows on environment and growth in OECD countries? A panel study. Environ. Impact Assess. Rev. 2020, 84, 106434. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Bildirici, M.; Gokmenoglu, S.M. The impact of terrorism and FDI on environmental pollution: Evidence from Afghanistan, Iraq, Nigeria, Pakistan, Philippines, Syria, Somalia, Thailand and Yemen. Environ. Impact Assess. Rev. 2020, 81, 106340. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Rahman, M.M. Do population density, economic growth, energy use and exports adversely affect environmental quality in Asian populous countries? Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2017, 77, 506–514. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Candau, F.; Dienesch, E. Pollution Haven and Corruption Paradise. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 2017, 85, 171–192. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  16. Beumer, C.; Figge, L.; Elliott, J. The sustainability of globalisation: Including the ‘social robustness criterion’. J. Clean. Prod. 2018, 179, 704–715. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Doytch, N. The impact of Foreign Direct Investment on the Ecological Footprints of Nations. Environ. Sustain. Indic. 2020, 8, 100085. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Demena, B.A.; Afesorgbor, S.K. The effect of FDI on environmental emissions: Evidence from a meta-analysis. Energy Policy 2019, 138, 111192. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Leal, P.H.; Marques, A.C. The environmental impacts of globalisation and corruption: Evidence from a set of African countries. Environ. Sci. Policy 2021, 115, 116–124. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Baek, J. A panel cointegration analysis of CO2 emissions, nuclear energy and income in major nuclear generating countries. Appl. Energy 2015, 145, 133–138. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Leal, P.H.; Marques, A.C. Are de jure and de facto globalization undermining the environment? Evidence from high and low globalized EU countries. J. Environ. Manag. 2019, 250, 109460. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Liu, M.; Ren, X.; Cheng, C.; Wang, Z. The role of globalization in CO2 emissions: A semi-parametric panel data analysis for G7. Sci. Total Environ. 2020, 718, 137379. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Sun, C.; Chen, L.; Zhang, F. Exploring the trading embodied CO2 effect and low-carbon globalization from the international division perspective. Environ. Impact Assess. Rev. 2020, 83, 106414. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Wang, L.; Vo, X.V.; Shahbaz, M.; Ak, A. Globalization and carbon emissions: Is there any role of agriculture value-added, financial development, and natural resource rent in the aftermath of COP21? J. Environ. Manag. 2020, 268, 110712. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Leal, P.H.; Marques, A.C. Rediscovering the EKC hypothesis for the 20 highest CO2 emitters among OECD countries by level of globalization. Int. Econ. 2020, 164, 36–47. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Leal, P.H.; Marques, A.C.; Shahbaz, M. The role of globalisation, de jure and de facto, on environmental performance: Evidence from developing and developed countries. Environ. Dev. Sustain. 2020, 1–20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Leal, P.H.; Marques, A.C. Rediscovering the EKC Hypothesis on the High and Low Globalized OECD Countries. In Green Energy and Technology; Shahbaz, M., Balsalobre, D., Eds.; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 2019; pp. 85–114. ISBN 978-3-030-06000-8. [Google Scholar]
  28. Bolwig, S.; Ponte, S.; Du Toit, A.; Riisgaard, L.; Halberg, N. Integrating poverty and environmental concerns into value-chain analysis: A conceptual framework. Dev. Policy Rev. 2010, 28, 173–194. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Dreher, A. Does globalization affect growth? Evidence from a new index of globalization. Appl. Econ. 2006, 38, 1091–1110. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  30. Dreher, A.; Gaston, N.; Martens, P. Measuring globalisation. In Gauging Its Consequences; Springer: New York, NY, USA, 2008. [Google Scholar]
  31. Gygli, S.; Haelg, F.; Potrafke, N.; Sturm, J.E. The KOF Globalisation Index—Revisited. Rev. Int. Organ. 2019, 14, 543–574. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  32. Sethi, P.; Chakrabarti, D.; Bhattacharjee, S. Globalization, financial development and economic growth: Perils on the environmental sustainability of an emerging economy. J. Policy Model. 2020, 42, 520–535. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Woo, B.; Jun, H.J. Globalization and slums: How do economic, political, and social globalization affect slum prevalence? Habitat Int. 2020, 98, 102152. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Khan, M.K.; Teng, J.Z.; Khan, M.I.; Khan, M.O. Impact of globalization, economic factors and energy consumption on CO2 emissions in Pakistan. Sci. Total Environ. 2019, 688, 424–436. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Hammudeh, S.; Sohag, K.; Husain, S.; Husain, H. Nonlinear relationship between economic growth and nuances of globalisation with income stratification: Roles of financial development and governance. Econ. Syst. 2020, 44, 100761. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Suki, N.M.; Sharif, A.; Afshan, S.; Suki, N.M. Revisiting the Environmental Kuznets Curve in Malaysia: The role of globalization in sustainable environment. J. Clean. Prod. 2020, 264, 121669. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Martens, P.; Caselli, M.; De Lombaerde, P.; Figge, L.; Scholte, J.A. New Directions in Globalization Indices. Globalizations 2015, 12, 217–228. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Pleninger, R.; Sturm, J. The effects of economic globalisation and ethnic fractionalisation on redistribution. World Dev. 2020, 130, 104945. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  39. Aluko, O.A.; Osei Opoku, E.E.; Ibrahim, M. Investigating the environmental effect of globalization: Insights from selected industrialized countries. J. Environ. Manag. 2021, 281, 111892. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Doytch, N.; Narayan, S. Does FDI influence renewable energy consumption? An analysis of sectoral FDI impact on renewable and non-renewable industrial energy consumption. Energy Econ. 2016, 54, 291–301. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Marques, A.C.; Caetano, R. The impact of foreign direct investment on emission reduction targets: Evidence from high−and middle-income countries. Struct. Chang. Econ. Dyn. 2020, 55, 107–118. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Yilanci, V.; Bozoklu, S.; Gorus, M.S. Are BRICS countries pollution havens? Evidence from a bootstrap ARDL bounds testing approach with a Fourier function. Sustain. Cities Soc. 2020, 55, 102035. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Zhu, H.; Duan, L.; Guo, Y.; Yu, K. The effects of FDI, economic growth and energy consumption on carbon emissions in ASEAN-5: Evidence from panel quantile regression. Econ. Model. 2016, 58, 237–248. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  44. Latorre, M.C.; Yonezawa, H.; Zhou, J. A general equilibrium analysis of FDI growth in Chinese services sectors. China Econ. Rev. 2018, 47, 172–188. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Dong, Y.; Tian, J.; Ye, J. Environmental regulation and foreign direct investment: Evidence from China’s outward FDI. Financ. Res. Lett. 2020, 101611. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Essandoh, O.K.; Islam, M.; Kakinaka, M. Linking international trade and foreign direct investment to CO2 emissions: Any differences between developed and developing countries? Sci. Total Environ. 2020, 712, 136437. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Shahbaz, M.; Balsalobre-Lorente, D.; Sinha, A. Foreign direct Investment–CO2 emissions nexus in Middle East and North African countries: Importance of biomass energy consumption. J. Clean. Prod. 2019, 217, 603–614. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  48. Hanif, I.; Faraz Raza, S.M.; Gago-de-Santos, P.; Abbas, Q. Fossil fuels, foreign direct investment, and economic growth have triggered CO2 emissions in emerging Asian economies: Some empirical evidence. Energy 2019, 171, 493–501. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Xie, Q.; Wang, X.; Cong, X. How does foreign direct investment affect CO2 emissions in emerging countries? New findings from a nonlinear panel analysis. J. Clean. Prod. 2020, 249, 119422. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Balsalobre, D.; Álvarez, A.; Cantos, J.M. Public budgets for energy RD&D and the effects on energy intensity and pollution levels. Environ. Sci. Pollut. Res. 2015, 22, 4881–4892. [Google Scholar]
  51. Omri, A.; Nguyen, D.K.; Rault, C. Causal interactions between CO2 emissions, FDI, and economic growth: Evidence from dynamic simultaneous-equation models. Econ. Model. 2014, 42, 382–389. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  52. Pazienza, P. The impact of FDI in the OECD manufacturing sector on CO2 emission: Evidence and policy issues. Environ. Impact Assess. Rev. 2019, 77, 60–68. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Shahbaz, M.; Nasir, M.A.; Roubaud, D. Environmental degradation in France: The effects of FDI, financial development, and energy innovations. Energy Econ. 2018, 74, 843–857. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  54. Adeel-Farooq, R.M.; Riaz, M.F.; Ali, T. Improving the environment begins at home: Revisiting the links between FDI and environment. Energy 2021, 215, 119150. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Hao, Y.; Guo, Y.; Guo, Y.; Wu, H.; Ren, S. Does outward foreign direct investment (OFDI) affect the home country’s environmental quality? The case of China. Struct. Chang. Econ. Dyn. 2020, 52, 109–119. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Shahbaz, M.; Nasreen, S.; Abbas, F.; Anis, O. Does foreign direct investment impede environmental quality in high-, middle-, and low-income countries? Energy Econ. 2015, 51, 275–287. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Rafindadi, A.A.; Muye, I.M.; Kaita, R.A. The effects of FDI and energy consumption on environmental pollution in predominantly resource-based economies of the GCC. Sustain. Energy Technol. Assess. 2018, 25, 126–137. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Pais, D.F.; Afonso, T.L.; Marques, A.C.; Fuinhas, J.A. Are economic growth and sustainable development converging? Evidence from the comparable genuine progress indicator for organisation for economic co-operation and development countries. Int. J. Energy Econ. Policy 2019, 9, 202–213. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Menegaki, A.N.; Tugcu, C.T. Two versions of the Index of Sustainable Economic Welfare (ISEW) in the energy-growth nexus for selected Asian countries. Sustain. Prod. Consum. 2018, 14, 21–35. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Marques, A.C.; Fuinhas, J.A.; Gaspar, J.D.S. On the Nexus of Energy Use–Economic Development: A Panel Approach. Energy Procedia 2016, 106, 225–234. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Dos Santos, G.J.; Marques, A.C.; Fuinhas, J.A. The traditional energy-growth nexus: A comparison between sustainable development and economic growth approaches. Ecol. Indic. 2017, 75, 286–296. [Google Scholar]
  62. Dartey-Baah, K. Effective leadership and sustainable development in Africa: Is there “really” a link? J. Glob. Responsib. 2014, 5, 203–218. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  63. Aust, V.; Morais, A.I.; Pinto, I. How does foreign direct investment contribute to Sustainable Development Goals? Evidence from African countries. J. Clean. Prod. 2020, 245, 118823. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  64. Sharma, B.; Gani, A. The Effects of Foreign Direct Investment on Human Development. Glob. Econ. J. 2004, 4, 1850025. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  65. Apinran, M.O.; Taşpınar, N.; Gökmenoğlu, K.K. Impact of Foreign Direct Investment on Human Development Index in Nigeria. Bus. Econ. Res. J. 2018, 9, 1–13. [Google Scholar]
  66. Balsalobre-Lorente, D.; Gokmenoglu, K.K.; Taspinar, N.; Cantos-Cantos, J.M. An approach to the pollution haven and pollution halo hypotheses in MINT countries. Environ. Sci. Pollut. Res. 2019, 26, 23010–23026. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  67. Frugoli, P.A.; Almeida, C.M.V.B.; Agostinho, F.; Giannetti, B.F.; Huisingh, D. Can measures of well-being and progress help societies to achieve sustainable development? J. Clean. Prod. 2015, 90, 370–380. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  68. Kwatra, S.; Kumar, A.; Sharma, P. A critical review of studies related to construction and computation of Sustainable Development Indices. Ecol. Indic. 2020, 112, 106061. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  69. Daly, H.E.; Cobb, J.B. For the Common Good: Redirecting the Economy toward Community, the Environment, and a Sustainable Future; Beach Press: Boston, MA, USA, 1989. [Google Scholar]
  70. Cobb, C.W.; Cobb, J.B. The Green National Product: A Proposed Index of Sustainable Economic Welfare; University Press of America: Lanham, MD, USA, 1994. [Google Scholar]
  71. Lawn, P.A. A theoretical foundation to support the Index of Sustainable Economic Welfare (ISEW), Genuine Progress Indicator (GPI), and other related indexes. Ecol. Econ. 2003, 44, 105–118. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  72. Bleys, B.; Whitby, A. Barriers and opportunities for alternative measures of economic welfare. Ecol. Econ. 2015, 117, 162–172. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  73. O’Mahony, T.; Escardó-Serra, P.; Dufour, J. Revisiting ISEW Valuation Approaches: The Case of Spain Including the Costs of Energy Depletion and of Climate Change. Ecol. Econ. 2018, 144, 292–303. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  74. Menegaki, A.N.; Tiwari, A.K. The index of sustainable economic welfare in the energy-growth nexus for American countries. Ecol. Indic. 2017, 72, 494–509. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  75. Sánchez, M.; Ochoa, M.; Toledo, E.; Ordóñez, J. The relevance of Index of Sustainable Economic Wellbeing. Case study of Ecuador. Environ. Sustain. Indic. 2020, 6, 100037. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  76. Menegaki, A.N.; Marques, A.C.; Fuinhas, J.A. Redefining the energy-growth nexus with an index for sustainable economic welfare in Europe. Energy 2017, 141, 1254–1268. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  77. Menegaki, A.N.; Tugcu, C.T. Rethinking the energy-growth nexus: Proposing an index of sustainable economic welfare for Sub-Saharan Africa. Energy Res. Soc. Sci. 2016, 17, 147–159. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  78. Marques, A.C.; Fuinhas, J.A.; Pais, D.F. Economic growth, sustainable development and food consumption: Evidence across different income groups of countries. J. Clean. Prod. 2018, 196, 245–258. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  79. United Nations. World Economic Situation and Prospects. J. Chem. Inf. Model. 2019, 167–170. [Google Scholar]
  80. Posner, S.M.; Costanza, R. A summary of ISEW and GPI studies at multiple scales and new estimates for Baltimore City, Baltimore County, and the State of Maryland. Ecol. Econ. 2011, 70, 1972–1980. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  81. Kaufmann, D.; Kraay, A.; Mastruzzi, M. The worldwide governance indicators: Methodology and analytical issues. Hague J. Rule Law 2011, 3, 220–246. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  82. Menegaki, A.N.; Tsagarakis, K.P. More indebted than we know? Informing fiscal policy with an index of sustainable welfare for Greece. Ecol. Indic. 2015, 57, 159–163. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  83. Pesaran, M.H. General diagnostic tests for cross section dependence in panels. Empir. Econ. 2004, 60, 13–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  84. Pesaran, M.H. A simple panel unit root test in the presence of cross-section dependence. J. Appl. Econom. 2007, 22, 265–312. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  85. Ike, G.N.; Usman, O.; Sarkodie, S.A. Fiscal policy and CO2 emissions from heterogeneous fuel sources in Thailand: Evidence from multiple structural breaks cointegration test. Sci. Total Environ. 2020, 702, 134711. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  86. Khan, I.; Hou, F.; Le, H.P. The impact of natural resources, energy consumption, and population growth on environmental quality: Fresh evidence from the United States of America. Sci. Total Environ. 2021, 754, 142222. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  87. Pata, U.K.; Caglar, A.E. Investigating the EKC hypothesis with Renewable Energy Consumption, Human Capital, Globalization and Trade Openness for China: Evidence from Augmented ARDL Approach with a Structural Break. Energy 2020, 216, 119220. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  88. Zivot, E.; Andrews, D.W.K. Further Evidence on the Great Crash, the Oil Price Shock, and the Unit Root Hypothesis. J. Bus. Econ. Stat. 1992, 10, 251–270. [Google Scholar]
  89. Pesaran, M.H.; Smith, R. Estimating Long-Run Relationships from Dynamic Heterogeneous Panels. J. Econom. 1995, 68, 79–113. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  90. Pesaran, M.H.; Pesaran, M.H.; Shin, Y.; Smith, R.P. Pooled Mean Group Estimation of Dynamic Heterogeneous Panels. J. Am. Stat. Assoc. 1999, 94, 621–634. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  91. Frees, E.W. Assessing cross-sectional correlation in panel data. J. Econom. 1995, 69, 393–414. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  92. Friedman, M. The use of ranks to avoid the assumption of normality implicit in the analysis of variance. J. Am. Stat. Assoc. 1937, 32, 675–701. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  93. Driscoll, J.C.; Kraay, A.C. Consistent Covariance Matrix Estimation with Spatially Dependent Panel Data. Rev. Econ. Stat. 1998, 80, 549–560. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  94. Sadorsky, P. Energy related CO2 emissions before and after the financial crisis. Sustainability 2020, 12, 3867. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  95. Zaidi, S.; Saidi, K. Environmental pollution, health expenditure and economic growth in the Sub-Saharan Africa countries: Panel ARDL approach. Sustain. Cities Soc. 2018, 41, 833–840. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  96. Barassi, M.R.; Zhou, Y. The effect of corruption on FDI: A parametric and non-parametric analysis. Eur. J. Polit. Econ. 2012, 28, 302–312. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  97. Gossel, S.J. FDI, democracy and corruption in Sub-Saharan Africa. J. Policy Model. 2018, 40, 647–662. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  98. Woo, J.-Y. The Impact of Corruption on a Country’s FDI Attractiveness: A Panel Data Analysis, 1984–2004. J. Int. Area Stud. 2010, 17, 71–91. [Google Scholar]
  99. Shleifer, A.; Vishny, R.W. Corruption. Q. J. Econ. 1993, 108, 599–617. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  100. Qureshi, F.; Qureshi, S.; Vinh Vo, X.; Junejo, I. Revisiting the nexus among foreign direct investment, corruption and growth in developing and developed markets. Borsa Istanbul Rev. 2020. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  101. Rudolph, A.; Figge, L. Determinants of Ecological Footprints: What is the role of globalization? Ecol. Indic. 2017, 81, 348–361. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  102. Ahmed, Z.; Cary, M.; Le, H.P. Accounting asymmetries in the long-run nexus between globalization and environmental sustainability in the United States: An aggregated and disaggregated investigation. Environ. Impact Assess. Rev. 2021, 86, 106511. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  103. Opoku, E.E.O.; Adams, S.; Adewale, O.A. The foreign direct investment-environment nexus: Does emission disaggregation matter? Energy Rep. 2021, 7, 778–787. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  104. Fagbemi, F.; Osinubi, T. Leveraging foreign direct investment for sustainability: An approach to sustainable human development in Nigeria. Resour. Environ. Sustain. 2020, 2, 100005. [Google Scholar]
  105. Kardos, M. The Relevance of Foreign Direct Investment for Sustainable Development. Empirical Evidence from European Union. Procedia Econ. Financ. 2014, 15, 1349–1354. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  106. Nepal, R.; Paija, N.; Tyagi, B.; Harvie, C. Energy security, economic growth and environmental sustainability in India: Does FDI and trade openness play a role? J. Environ. Manag. 2021, 281, 111886. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Table 1. Variables.
Table 1. Variables.
VariableDescriptionSource
ISEWIndex for Sustainable Economic WelfareOwn calculation
CO2Carbon Dioxide Emissions (MMtons)U.S. Energy Information Administration
FDI_fiInward Foreign Direct Investment Flow (% of GDP)UNCTADStat
FDI_foOutward Foreign Direct Investment Flow (% of GDP)
FDI_siInward Foreign Direct Investment Stock (% of GDP)
FDI_soOutward Foreign Direct Investment Stock (% of GDP)
GDPGross Domestic Product (constant 2010 US$)World Bank Development Indicators
CORRControl of Corruption IndexWorld Bank, Worldwide Governance Indicators
RQRegulatory Quality Index
FFFossil fuels consumption (quad Btu)U.S. Energy Information Administration
RESRenewable energy consumption (quad Btu)
KOFECDFKOF Globalisation Index Economic Dimension de FactoKOF Swiss Economic Institute
KOFECDJKOF Globalisation Index Economic Dimension de Jure
KOFSODFKOF Globalisation Index Social Dimension de Facto
KOFSODJKOF Globalisation Index Social Dimension de Jure
KOFPODFKOF Globalisation Index Political Dimension de Facto
KOFPODJKOF Globalisation Index Political Dimension de Jure
Notes: MMtons denotes Million Metric tonnes; quad Btu denotes quadrillion British thermal unit. Interpolation technique with the average of the values from the adjacent years was employed to calculate the years of 1997, 1999 and 2001 of the governance indicators (corruption index and regulatory quality index), see e.g., in [80].
Table 2. Index of Sustainable Economic Welfare (ISEW) components.
Table 2. Index of Sustainable Economic Welfare (ISEW) components.
VariablesSignCalculation MethodSource
Adjusted personal consumption with durables (Cw)+PC * (1-GINI)PC: https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/NE.CON.PRVT.CD
GINI: https://dataverse.harvard.edu/dataset.xhtml?persistentId=doi:10.7910/DVN/LM4OWF
Education expenditure (Geh)+Education expenditure * 0,5http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/NY.ADJ.AEDU.CD
Health expenditure (Geh)+Health expenditure * 0,5https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/SH.XPD.CHEX.PC.CD
Net capital growth (Kn)±GCF-CFCFCA: http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/NE.GDI.TOTL.CD
CFC: http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/NY.ADJ.DKAP.CD
Mineral depletion (N)- http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/NY.ADJ.DMIN.CD
Energy depletion (N)- http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/NY.ADJ.DNGY.CD
Forest depletion (N)- http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/NY.ADJ.DFOR.CD
Damage from CO2 emissions (N)- http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/NY.ADJ.DCO2.CD
Notes: * denotes multiplication; PC denotes Final household consumption expenditure; FCA denotes Gross capital formation; CFC denotes consumption of fixed capital. The sources were last accessed on 12 October 2020.
Table 3. Descriptive statistics from 1996 to 2017 (CO2 model).
Table 3. Descriptive statistics from 1996 to 2017 (CO2 model).
Developed Countries
MeanStd. Dev.Min.Max.Obs.
CO2_pc1.08 × 10−54.23 × 10−64.75 × 10−62.08 × 10−5374
GDP_pc45,323.4216,260.439290.18991565.73374
FDI_fi3.93026.8449−14.972974.7406374
FDI_fo4.09496.1196−6.856257.7976374
FDI_si47.119942.39080.6134315.1932374
FDI_so49.599151.63830.8444312.0545374
FF_p70.317518.505930.178498.3638374
RES_p18.177116.82121.081669.8216374
CORR1.70840.5393−0.00662.4650374
RQ1.46680.35070.51332.0980374
KOFECDF68.295114.730629.268392.0529374
KOFECDJ83.06617.325050.106794.7231374
KOFSODF81.57347.334155.330195.1544374
KOFSODJ84.49614.658764.995292.6337374
KOFPODF88.72257.041644.896398.0264374
KOFPODJ90.03209.972057.0964100374
Developing Countries
MeanStd. Dev.Min.Max.Obs.
CO2_pc61.737116.74210.8331481.3982308
GDP_pc3101.3812714.604361.043511,949.28308
FDI_fi2.55743.1981−7.867828.909308
FDI_fo0.17270.6498−2.61526.6982308
FDI_si26.648119.47820.6565103.8824308
FDI_so4.12278.17290.006579.3375308
FF_p86.120314.856941.728699.8846308
RES_p13.7023150.053358.2714308
CORR−0.49580.583−1.43121.2167308
RQ−0.35790.4799−1.3520.8042308
KOFECDF49.39819.831529.85868.8775308
KOFECDJ44.813910.680623.296169.5586308
KOFSODF38.316214.72177.969266.9936308
KOFSODJ48.180312.807317.424874.0204308
KOFPODF65.388819.663124.13793.309308
KOFPODJ71.545414.067227.160594.1716308
Notes: Max. denotes Maximum; Min. denotes Minimum; Std. Dev. denotes Standard deviation; Obs denotes Observations; pc denotes per capita.
Table 4. Descriptive statistics from 2000 to 2017 (ISEW model).
Table 4. Descriptive statistics from 2000 to 2017 (ISEW model).
Developed Countries
MeanStd. Dev.Min.Max.Obs.
ISEW_pc20,787.88107.952571.25445,772.46306
CO2_pc1.07 × 10−54.25 × 10−64.75 × 10−64.75 × 10−5306
FDI_fi3.93966.9368−14.972974.7406306
FDI_fo4.15296.0808−6.856257.7976306
FDI_si52.008744.62331.0296315.1932306
FDI_so55.313454.93081.5233312.0545306
FF_p69.970418.527630.178498.3638306
RES_p18.496416.74791.619969.8216306
CORR1.70740.5397−0.00662.465306
RQ1.48450.33850.53052.0980306
KOFECDF70.209813.929529.840992.0529306
KOFECDJ83.22176.035762.593894.7231306
KOFSODF83.02836.607159.539595.1544306
KOFSODJ85.77223.344073.92792.6337306
KOFPODF89.15476.399670.302598.0264306
KOFPODJ90.84939.327264.4206100306
Developing Countries
MeanStd. Dev.Min.Max.Obs.
ISEW_pc1016.448740.74787.15433345.461252
CO2_pc1.69 × 10−62.23 × 10−65.81 × 10−89.45 × 10−6252
FDI_fi2.91233.3016−1.719428.909252
FDI_fo0.17910.6995−2.61526.6982252
FDI_si28.946719.79361.5335103.8824252
FDI_so4.22068.7030.031479.3375252
FF_p86.131815.032841.728699.8846252
RES_p13.696015.16980.093558.2714252
CORR−0.50440.5736−1.43121.2167252
RQ−0.3790.4804−1.3520.8042252
KOFECDF49.88689.928329.85868.8775252
KOFECDJ45.676810.677123.296169.5586252
KOFSODF40.624514.0889.955866.9936252
KOFSODJ50.848411.541325.874574.0204252
KOFPODF67.417818.885425.403893.309252
KOFPODJ73.586612.538643.403494.1716252
Notes: Max. denotes Maximum; Min. denotes Minimum; Std. Dev. denotes Standard deviation; Obs denotes Observations; pc denotes per capita.
Table 5. Cross section dependence test from 1996 to 2017 (CO2 model).
Table 5. Cross section dependence test from 1996 to 2017 (CO2 model).
Developed CountriesDeveloping Countries
CD-TestCorrAbs (corr) CD-TestCorrAbs (corr)
LCO2_pc35.87 ***0.6560.663LCO2_pc25.96 ***0.580.721
LGDP_pc51.56 ***0.9430.943LGDP_pc20.26 ***0.4530.644
FDI_fi9.34 ***0.1710.242FDI_fi2.73 ***0.0610.199
FDI_fo7.06 ***0.1290.235FDI_fo1.81 *0.040.227
FDI_si28.13 ***0.5140.643FDI_si18.52 ***0.4140.584
FDI_so31.97 ***0.5850.674FDI_so9.08 ***0.2030.661
LNRES_p19.22 ***0.3510.599LNRES_p−2.07 **−0.0460.399
LRES_p24.59 ***0.4490.563LRES_p−1.47−0.0330.404
CORR0.890.0160.319CORR−1.67 *−0.0370.35
RQ3 ***0.0550.394RQ8.76 ***0.1960.362
LKOFECDF30.11 ***0.5510.706LKOFECDF0.390.0090.399
LKOFECDJ17.42 ***0.3190.534LKOFECDJ8.19 ***0.1830.363
LKOFSODF52.57 ***0.9610.961LKOFSODF42 ***0.9390.939
LKOFSODJ46.29 ***0.8460.846LKOFSODJ41.89 ***0.9360.936
LKOFPODF10.88 ***0.1990.381LKOFPODF23.54 ***0.5260.534
LKOFPODJ38.81 ***0.710.813LKOFPODJ39.79 ***0.8890.889
Notes: *, **, *** denotes statistical significance level at 10%, 5% and 1%, respectively; prefix L denotes Logarithm.
Table 6. Cross section dependence test from 2000 to 2017 (ISEW model).
Table 6. Cross section dependence test from 2000 to 2017 (ISEW model).
Developed CountriesDeveloping Countries
CD-TestCorrAbs (corr) CD-TestCorrAbs (corr)
ISEW_pc41.9 ***0.8470.847ISEW_pc30.47 ***0.7530.753
CO2_pc35.88 ***0.7250.727CO2_pc5.06 ***0.1250.486
FDI_fi9.63 ***0.1950.264FDI_fi1.380.0340.207
FDI_fo5.52 ***0.1120.243FDI_fo1.75 *0.0430.239
FDI_si23.17 ***0.4680.536FDI_si13.96 ***0.3450.517
FDI_so23.26 ***0.4700.622FDI_so8.95 ***0.2210.642
FF_p19.53 ***0.3950.598FF_p−1.93 *−0.0480.436
RES_p25.32 ***0.5120.6RES_p−1.35−0.0330.448
CORR1.070.0220.345CORR−0.85−0.0210.353
RQ1.20.0240.412RQ9.58 ***0.2370.430
KOFECDF20.16 ***0.4070.705KOFECDF0.460.0110.392
KOFECDJ16.21 ***0.3280.5KOFECDJ0.790.020.308
KOFSODF46.75 ***0.9450.945KOFSODF36.91 ***0.9120.912
KOFSODJ31.73 ***0.6410.641KOFSODJ34.73 ***0.8580.858
KOFPODF5.37 ***0.1090.401KOFPODF15.72 ***0.3880.418
KOFPODJ34.22 ***0.6920.74KOFPODJ36.33 ***0.8980.898
Notes: *, *** denotes statistical significance level at 10% and 1%, respectively; prefix L denotes Logarithm.
Table 7. Second-generation unit root test (CIPS) from 1996 to 2017 (CO2 model).
Table 7. Second-generation unit root test (CIPS) from 1996 to 2017 (CO2 model).
Developed CountriesDeveloping Countries
Without TrendWith TrendWithout TrendWith Trend
LCO2_pc−2.944 ***−2.14 **0.613−0.841
DLCO2_pc−11.039 ***−9.149 ***−11.984 ***−10.258 ***
LGDP_pc0.3291.9572.6853.988
DLGDP_pc−6.549 ***−4.751 ***−6.26 ***−6.195 ***
FDI_fi−8.15 ***−7.735 ***−5.857 ***−5.783 ***
DFDI_fi−17.031 ***−15.634 ***−13.276 ***−11.878 ***
FDI_fo−7.120 ***−7.154 ***−3.837 ***−4.761 ***
DFDI_fo−15.448 ***−13.731 ***−14.191 ***−12.454 ***
FDI_si−0.0813.8480.8352.581
DFDI_si−9.893 ***−9.111 ***−7.556 ***−6.287 ***
FDI_so0.3043.1856.5323.713
DFDI_so−8.160 ***−7.123 ***−5.196 ***−3.958 ***
LFF_p−3.677 ***−2.48 ***0.785−1.257
DLFF_p−13.481 ***−12.046 ***−11.733 ***−10.755 ***
LRES_p−3.862 ***−3.214 ***1.10.906
DLRES_p−14.63 ***−13.908 ***−11.728 ***−10.515 ***
CORR0.5250.6360.2342.23
DCORR−9.524 ***−6.854 ***−6.340 ***−4.785 ***
RQ−0.6451.475−1.2390.051
DRQ−8.281 ***−6.315 ***−8.073 ***−5.958 ***
LKOFECDF−2.438 ***−1.671 **−0.293−1.792 **
DLKOFECDF−8.107 ***−6.122 ***−10.32 ***−8.413 ***
LKOFECDJ−0.8310.435−1.049−1.07
DLKOFECDJ−12.93 ***−11.854 ***−10.933 ***−9.074 ***
LKOFSODF−2.941 ***−1.137−1.805 **−2.16 **
DLKOFSODF−12.925 ***−11.6 ***−12.089 ***−10.317 ***
LKOFSODJ−3.582 ***−2.429 ***−1.945 **−0.553
DLKOFSODJ−11.196 ***−10.076 ***−9.548 ***−7.961 ***
LKOFPODF−3.942 ***−1.55 *−4.018 ***−1.741 **
DLKOFPODF−10.943 ***−9.326 ***−10.313 ***−9.237 ***
LKOFPODJ−3.052 ***−2.888 ***−5.477 ***−5.869 ***
DLKOFPODJ−11.055 ***−10.553 ***−13.519 ***−11.983 ***
Notes: *, **, *** denotes statistical significance level at 10%, 5% and 1%, respectively; prefix D denotes Differences; prefix L denotes Logarithm.
Table 8. Second-generation unit root test (CIPS) from 2000 to 2017 (ISEW model).
Table 8. Second-generation unit root test (CIPS) from 2000 to 2017 (ISEW model).
Developed CountriesDeveloping Countries
Without TrendWith TrendWithout TrendWith Trend
LISEW_pc−0.4170.385−1.174−0.436
DLISEW_pc−7.361 ***−4.160 ***−6.369 ***−5.002 ***
LCO2_pc−3.065 ***−0.9950.838−2.682 ***
DLCO2_pc−8.052 ***−5.553 ***−9.340 ***−8.045 ***
FDI_fi−7.593 ***−6.8 ***−4.105 ***−3.799 ***
DFDI_fi−15.068 ***−12.919 ***−11.165 ***−9.489 ***
FDI_fo−7.482 ***−6.073 ***−2.136 **−3.305 ***
DFDI_fo−13.476 ***−10.870 ***−10.858 ***−9.056 ***
FDI_si−1.515 *1.7020.6562.539
DFDI_si−7.736 ***−7.394 ***−4 ***−3.301 ***
FDI_so0.2742.5314.6611.908
DFDI_so−5.599 ***−3.818 ***−4.755 ***−2.968 ***
LFF_p−2.627 ***−2.219 **−0.805−0.358
DLFF_p−11.802 ***−9.625 ***−9.081 ***−8.636 ***
LRES_p−3.806 ***−3.954 ***1.047−0.612
DLRES_p−13.078 ***−11.109 ***−10.663 ***−10.055 ***
CORR0.1230.562−0.3181.441
DCORR−8.061 ***−5.491 ***−5.126 ***−3.399 ***
RQ−1.338 *−0.067−1.678 **−0.152
DRQ−7.611 ***−6.928 ***−6.751 ***−4.862 ***
LKOFECDF−1.140−0.9120.186−0.205
DLKOFECDF−8.653 ***−7.041 ***−8.094 ***−6.586 ***
LKOFECDJ−1.962 **−0.212−0.4630.339
DLKOFECDJ−9.598 ***−8.882 ***−7.761 ***−5.984 ***
LKOFSODF−3.234 ***−2.397 ***−2.477 ***−3.652 ***
DLKOFSODF−10.151 ***−7.615 ***−10.81 ***−10.244 ***
LKOFSODJ−4.456 ***−2.180 **−0.69−0.096
DLKOFSODJ−9.994 ***−9.122 ***−6.566 ***−5.79 ***
LKOFPODF−0.6811.597−1.262−1.363 *
DLKOFPODF−6.973 ***−6.662 ***−7.802 ***−6.171 ***
LKOFPODJ−2.469 ***−1.685 **−2.941 ***−4.743 ***
DLKOFPODJ−8.551 ***−7.307 ***−10.451 ***−8.923 ***
Notes: *, **, *** denotes significance level at 10%, 5% and 1%, respectively; prefix D denotes Differences; prefix L denotes Logarithm.
Table 9. Hausman test and F-test.
Table 9. Hausman test and F-test.
Developed Countries
I-CO2 Model with FDI_siII-CO2 Model with FDI_soIII-ISEW Model with FDI_siIV-ISEW Model with FDI_so
F-test3.59 ***3.56 ***3 ***2.38 ***
Hausman test50.93 ***50.62 ***42.75 ***35.04 ***
Developing Countries
V-CO2 Model with KOFSODFVI-CO2 Model with KOFSODJVII-ISEW Model with KOFSODFVIII-ISEW Model with KOFSODJ
F-test2.9 ***2.89 ***7.05 ***9.36 ***
Hausman test34.45 ***34.35 ***66.49 ***79.91 ***
Notes: *** denotes significance level at 1%.
Table 10. Specification tests.
Table 10. Specification tests.
Developed Countries
I-CO2 Model with FDI_siII-CO2 Model with FDI_soIII-ISEW Model with FDI_siIV-ISEW Model with FDI_so
Pesaran test8.636 ***8.775 ***16.806 ***15.198 ***
Frees test0.549 ***0.579 ***2.217 ***1.997 ***
Fiedman test66.108 ***66.411 ***105.232 ***100.286 ***
Modified Wald test320.32 ***361.58 ***44.40 ***66.98 ***
Wooldrige test100.426 ***87.545 ***118.034 ***95.314 ***
Developing Countries
V-CO2 Model with KOFSODFVI-CO2 Model with KOFSODJVII-ISEW Model with KOFSODFVIII-ISEW Model with KOFSODJ
Pesaran test1.999 **1.899 *4.513 ***4.792 ***
Frees test0.041−0.0051.027 ***0.837 ***
Fiedman test34.03 ***34.141 ***39.653 ***43.227 ***
Modified Wald test176.37 ***187.71 ***706.11 ***650.51 ***
Wooldrige test55.846 ***52.965 ***16.456 ***14.367 ***
Notes: ***, **, * denotes significance level at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively.
Table 11. Estimations of Autoregressive Distributed Lag (ARDL) model.
Table 11. Estimations of Autoregressive Distributed Lag (ARDL) model.
Developed CountriesDeveloping Countries
CO2 ModelISEW ModelISEW Model CO2 Model
I-FDI_siII-FDI_soIII-FDI_siIV-FDI_soVII-KOFSODFVIII-KOFSODJ V-KOFSODFVI-KOFSODJ
DLGDP_pc0.4421 ***0.4515 *** DLGDP_pc
DLCO2_pc DLCO2
DFDI_fi−0.0006 **−0.0006 ** 0.015 ***0.0128 ***DFDI_fi
DFDI_fo DFDI_fo
DFDI_si DFDI_si0.0019 **0.0013 *
DFDI_so DFDI_so−0.0051 ***−0.0048 ***
DLFF_p0.8718 ***0.8698 *** DLFF_p1.5867 ***1.6863 ***
DLRES_p−0.0267 **−0.0282 ** DLRES_p
DCORR 0.0976 **0.0892 **0.2731 ** DCORR
DRQ 0.0693 ** −0.2738 * DRQ−0.0750 **−0.0677 *
DLKOFECDF −0.8967 ***−0.9049 *** DLKOFECDF
DLKOFECDJ −0.5456 ***DLKOFECDJ0.2732 ***0.1932 ***
DLKOFSODF 0.9839 ***0.837 **0.4057 ** DLKOFSODF
DLKOFSODJ 0.9309 ***DLKOFSODJ
DLKOFPODF DLKOFPODF
DLKOFPODJ DLKOFPODJ
LISEW_pc (−1) −0.1407 ***−0.1401 ***−0.7447 ***−0.7586 ***LISEW_pc (−1)
LCO2_pc (−1)−0.1927 ***−0.1986 ***0.2863 ***0.2597 ***0.3267 **0.2485 **LCO2 (−1)−0.2275 ***−0.2214 ***
LGDP_pc (−1) LGDP_pc (−1)
FDI_fi (−1) FDI_fi (−1)−0.0036 **−0.0032 **
FDI_fo (−1) FDI_fo (−1)
FDI_si (−1)−0.00011 ** 0.0012 *** 0.008 ***0.0051 ***FDI_si (−1)0.00092 *
FDI_so (−1) −0.00013 ** 0.00068 *** FDI_so (−1)
LFF_p (−1)0.2861 ***0.2908 *** LFF_p (−1)0.4846 ***0.6031 ***
LRES_p (−1) −0.0496 ***−0.0658 *** LRES_p (−1)
CORR (−1) 0.1028 ***0.0895 ***0.3039 **0.2419 **CORR (−1)
RQ (−1)−0.0156 **−0.0177 ** RQ (−1)−0.0411 *
LKOFECDF (−1) LKOFECDF (−1)
LKOFECDJ (−1)0.0971 ***0.0893 ***−0.5117 ***−0.5396 ***−0.4261 *−0.5397 **LKOFECDJ (−1)0.12 *
LKOFSODF (−1)−0.1115 ***−0.1014 ** 0.7076 *** LKOFSODF (-1)0.1063 ***
LKOFSODJ (−1) 1.5626 ***LKOFSODJ (−1) 0.1636 ***
LKOFPODF (−1) −0.8895 ***−0.8307 *** LKOFPODF (−1)−0.1081 **−0.0871 **
LKOFPODJ (−1) 1.1089 ***1.1739 *** LKOFPODJ (−1)0.2089 ***0.284 ***
C−3.3438 ***−3.438 ***5.8755 ***5.2215 ***8.5173 ***4.4613 *C−2.8327 ***−3.5374 ***
Dum_2009−0.0281 ***−0.0279 ***−0.1923 ***−0.2006 *** Dum_2009−0.0948 ***−0.0962 ***
Dum_2010 0.0806 **0.14405 ***Dum_2010
Elasticities
LCO2_pc (−1) 2.0346 *1.8545 *0.4387 ***0.3276 **LCO2 (−1)
LGDP_pc (−1) LGDP_pc (−1)
FDI_fi (−1) FDI_fi (−1)−0.0159 ***−0.0144 ***
FDI_fo (−1) FDI_fo (−1)
FDI_si (−1)−0.00058 ** 0.0088 ** 0.0107 ***0.0067 ***FDI_si (−1)0.004 **
FDI_so (−1) −0.00064 *** 0.0049 ** FDI_so (−1)
LFF_p (−1)1.4851 ***1.4641 *** LFF_p (−1)2.1307 ***2.7238 ***
LRES_p (−1) −0.3522 ***−0.4698 *** LRES_p (−1)
CORR (−1) 0.7308 ***0.6391 **0.4081 **0.3189 **CORR (−1)
RQ (−1)−0.0811 **−0.08887** RQ (−1)−0.1806 **
LKOFECDF (−1) LKOFECDF (−1)
LKOFECDJ (−1)0.5039 ***0.4494 ***−3.6371 *−3.8532 *−0.5721 **−0.7115 ***LKOFECDJ (−1)0.5275 **
LKOFSODF (−1)−0.5787 ***−0.5106 *** 0.9501 *** LKOFSODF (−1)0.4671 ***
LKOFSODJ (−1) 2.06 ***LKOFSODJ (−1) 0.7387 ***
LKOFPODF (−1) −6.3223 **−5.9316 ** LKOFPODF (−1)−0.4752 ***−0.3935 ***
LKOFPODJ (−1) 7.8818 **8.3822 ** LKOFPODJ (−1)0.9185 ***1.2828 ***
Notes: ***, **, * denotes significance level at 1%, 5% and 10% respectively; prefix D denotes Differences; prefix L denotes Logarithm; Dum denotes dummy; C denotes constant; Values in bold and italic are the ECM.
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Leal, P.H.; Caetano, R.V.; Marques, A.C. Is the Relocation of Polluting Industries Prompted by FDI Flow and Stock, Globalisation, Corruption and Regulation? Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2021, 18, 1981. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph18041981

AMA Style

Leal PH, Caetano RV, Marques AC. Is the Relocation of Polluting Industries Prompted by FDI Flow and Stock, Globalisation, Corruption and Regulation? International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health. 2021; 18(4):1981. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph18041981

Chicago/Turabian Style

Leal, Patrícia Hipólito, Rafaela Vital Caetano, and António Cardoso Marques. 2021. "Is the Relocation of Polluting Industries Prompted by FDI Flow and Stock, Globalisation, Corruption and Regulation?" International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health 18, no. 4: 1981. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph18041981

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop