Next Article in Journal
Taking Care of Forced Migrants Together: Strengths and Weaknesses of Interorganizational Work from the Perspective of Social Workers
Next Article in Special Issue
The Outlook of Green Building Development in China during the “Fourteenth Five-Year Plan” Period
Previous Article in Journal
Protective and Overprotective Behaviors against COVID-19 Outbreak: Media Impact and Mediating Roles of Institutional Trust and Anxiety
Previous Article in Special Issue
Research on the Spatial Correlation of China’s Haze Pollution and the Government’s Cooperative Governance Competitive Strategy
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Horizontal CO2 Compensation in the Yangtze River Delta Based on CO2 Footprints and CO2 Emissions Efficiency

1
School of Geographical Sciences, Nanjing Normal University, Nanjing 210023, China
2
School of Tourism and Urban Management, Jiangxi University of Finance and Economics, Nanchang 330013, China
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2023, 20(2), 1369; https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph20021369
Submission received: 19 November 2022 / Revised: 2 January 2023 / Accepted: 4 January 2023 / Published: 12 January 2023
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Research in Ecological Economy and Regional Sustainable Development)

Abstract

:
Purpose: In this study, we attempted to reduce the negative economic externalities related to Carbon Dioxide (CO2) emissions in the Yangtze River Delta region (YRD) and designed a cross-municipality responsibility-sharing mechanism. Methods: We estimated the municipal CO2 footprints in the YRD from 2000 to 2019 based on nighttime light data and measured CO2 emissions efficiency using a super slack-based measurement (super-SBM) model. Based on this, we designed a scenario of horizontal CO2 compensation among the YRD’s municipalities from the perspectives of both CO2 footprints and CO2 trading (CO2 unit prices in trading were determined based on CO2 emissions efficiency). Results: The results showed the following: (1) The CO2 footprints evolution of the YRD municipalities could be divided into four categories, among which, eleven municipalities showed a decreasing trend. Thirteen municipalities stabilized their CO2 footprints. Thirteen municipalities exhibited strong growth in their CO2 footprints, whereas four municipalities maintained a low level of slow growth. (2) Spatially, CO2 emissions efficiency evolved from a broad distribution of low values to a mosaic distribution of multi-type zones. (3) After 2011, the ratio of CO2 footprint compensation amounts to local Gross Domestic Product (GDP) in most municipalities was less than 0.01%, with its center of gravity shifting cyclically. It was appropriate to start charging the CO2 footprint compensation amounts after 2011, with a dynamic adjustment of 3 years. (4) After 2007, the supply–demand relationship of CO2 trading continued to deteriorate, and it eased in 2016. However, its operational mechanism was still very fragile and highly dependent on a few pioneering municipalities. Innovations: In this study, we designed a horizontal CO2 compensation mechanism from the binary perspective of CO2 footprints and CO2 trading. In this mechanism, the former determines the CO2 footprint compensation amounts paid by each municipality based on whether the CO2 footprint exceeds its CO2 allowance. The latter determines the CO2 trading compensation amounts paid by the purchasing municipalities based on their CO2 emissions efficiency. This system balances equity and efficiency and provides new ideas for horizontal CO2 compensation.

1. Introduction

The warming caused by excessive fossil energy consumption has led the international community to rethink the current economic growth model [1,2]. A ‘carbon neutrality’ approach to deep decarbonization is becoming a significant trend in the evolution of the global energy economy [3,4]. From the Kyoto Protocol to The Paris Agreement, the division of responsibility for the reduction of CO2 emissions has always been at the heart of the international approach to CO2 emissions [5]. Based on the constraints of the global CO2 emissions and the realistic requirements of domestic economic transformation, China is actively fulfilling its commitments under the National Autonomous Contribution framework. China has incorporated binding emissions-reduction targets into its long-term economic development plan and proposed the goal of ‘achieving carbon neutrality by 2060’ at the United Nations General Assembly in September 2020.
Inter-regional horizontal CO2 compensation has become a new governance model to promote synergistic regional economic development [6,7]. Although it is impossible to achieve a mandatory national CO2 emissions reduction, it is feasible for China to adopt the idea of regional pilot projects first, followed by national implementation. The YRD has the market base to establish a unified environmental rights and interests trading system. The cumulative spot trading volume of the Shanghai CO2 trading market reached 159 million tons in 2020, with the trading volume exceeding RMB 1.7 billion. The results achieved with CO2 trading have made it increasingly clear that CO2 emissions are property-rights-based and tradable. This has raised awareness and increased the capacity of neighboring municipalities to manage their CO2 assets. Secondly, Zhejiang and Jiangsu provinces have been working on emissions trading for over ten years and have a wealth of experience. In addition, Zhejiang and Anhui provinces have developed models of watershed protection to follow in terms of ecological compensation. Thus, it seems that the YRD is an essential test region for the horizontal CO2 compensation system in China.
The horizontal CO2 compensation system aims to compensate for the negative externality of CO2 emissions and to ensure that municipalities develop a low-carbon economy with fairness and efficiency. Some municipalities are developing economies at the cost of a welfare loss for the environments of neighboring municipalities. However, these municipalities do not have to bear this external cost, which results in the marginal cost to society being greater than the marginal cost to individuals, and which can be called a negative externality. The negative externality caused by CO2 emissions is deeply affecting climate change and is an urgent issue to be addressed regionally, nationally, and globally. For the YRD, the traditional competitive model of ‘competitive growth’ which emerged in the early days under the performance appraisal mechanism of the GDP promotion race became one of the institutional root causes of sloppy and distorted economic growth, which directly led to severe environmental pollution and energy consumption. With the transformation of the economic model and the improvement of the government’s governance capacity, the performance appraisal mechanism for Chinese municipal officials has gradually strengthened its assessments of energy consumption and CO2 emissions indicators. Horizontal CO2 compensation will become a long-term mechanism to promote the development of China’s low-carbon economy from top to bottom. It requires not only balancing the development of each municipality in the process of CO2 emissions reduction to avoid the further development of disparities among municipalities but also taking into account the differences in the CO2 emissions efficiency among municipalities to prevent the bullwhip effect. Therefore, in this study, we explored the issues of how to set municipal CO2 allowances based on CO2 footprints, how to set the CO2 unit prices in trading among municipalities according to their CO2 emissions efficiency, and how to design a horizontal CO2 compensation system among municipalities while considering the principles of equity and efficiency.
This paper enriches or expands on the existing studies in the following aspects. Firstly, due to the lack of energy consumption data at the municipal scale in China, most studies have explored CO2 footprints and CO2 emissions efficiency at the provincial scale, which could hinder the establishment of a joint responsibility mechanism for CO2 emission reduction among the municipalities of the YRD. Since the 1980s, Welch has been the first to verify the feasibility of using nighttime lighting data to estimate energy consumption, using eastern U.S. cities as the study target [8]. Subsequently, a series of studies confirmed the consistency between nighttime lighting values and energy consumption footprints, which provided the theoretical basis and methods for calculating the municipal CO2 footprints in the present study. However, relevant studies with municipalities in the YRD as a sample are still lacking, and this study has enriched this region of research. Secondly, we determined municipalities’ horizontal CO2 compensation system by considering their emission reduction potential and economic conditions. On the one hand, unlike the studies conducted by Hu et al. [9] and Yang et al. [10], we used the historical CO2 intensity method to determine municipal CO2 allowances. In this method, we calculated CO2 intensity based on municipal historical production data and CO2 emissions and reduced it year by year to determine the CO2 allowance for the following year. On the other hand, we considered the ratio of the CO2 footprint compensation amount to local GDP, as well as the stability of municipalities’ CO2 surplus and deficit statuses when determining the implementation time of the compensation system. Thirdly, most existing studies have determined the horizontal CO2 compensation amounts based on the municipal CO2 surplus and deficit status (CO2 footprints) [9,10]. However, the difference in municipal CO2 emissions efficiency makes the two sides of CO2 trading obtain significantly different economic values. Therefore, this study further expands the existing research by including the added value generated in CO2 trading into the horizontal CO2 compensation system.

2. Literature Review and Study Framework

The concept of a CO2 footprint originated from the ecological footprint concept proposed by William in 1992, which refers to the number of greenhouse gases (GHG) emitted through production and consumption activities. CO2 footprint calculation is one of the effective ways to evaluate GHG emissions, and there are currently three main calculation methods. The first is the life cycle assessment method (LCA), which mainly assesses the CO2 emissions of a product during its life cycle and is a bottom-up evaluation method based on process analysis [11,12]. The second is the input–output analysis method (I-O), which mainly uses the preparation of input–output tables (IOTs) for accounting, including the single-region (SRIO) and multi-region input–output method (MRIO) [13]. It is a top-down model based on input–output analysis [14]. The third is the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) coefficient method, which uses the national GHG inventories compiled by the IPCC and the corresponding emission coefficients to calculate CO2 emissions [15,16]. All three methods mentioned above have their applicability and limitations. Specifically, LCA considers both direct and indirect CO2 emissions during the system’s life cycle with high accuracy and is suitable for CO2 footprint calculation at the micro level for products. However, it involves significant obstacles in acquiring data at the macro level. In addition, it involves problems such as truncation errors in the delineation of system boundaries and subjectivity in the standardization and weighting processes [11,12]. I-O can comprehensively reflect the direct and indirect CO2 emission relationships of various sectors and can overcome the problem of the duplication or omission of calculations due to the complex production relationships among sectors. However, the currently compiled IOT exhibits a significant lag time, and the aggregation mode of sectors in the IOT may be different from those of the energy consumption data, leading to some errors in the calculation of CO2 footprints [14]. The IPCC coefficient method comprehensively examines the GHG emissions caused by the combustion of different energies. It is easy to obtain data using this method and it involves a relatively simple calculation process, which is suitable for CO2 footprint calculations in regard to energy consumption at all scales. However, it cannot cover implied indirect CO2 emissions [15]. Since it is hard to obtain IOTs for municipalities and to monitor all the substances and activities covered by each product life cycle within a municipality [17], scholars usually use the IPCC method to calculate municipal-scale CO2 footprints. It is worth noting that municipal-scale energy consumption data are also difficult to obtain. Fortunately, with the development of earth observation techniques, nighttime light data from DMSP/OLS and VIIRS/DNB provide essential aids for the process of downscaling, which his used to calculate municipal CO2 footprints. The relevant studies date back to the 1980s, when Welch was the first to validate the feasibility of using nighttime light data to estimate energy consumption, using eastern cities in the United States as the study target [8]. Subsequently, Elvidge et al. [18] and Doll et al. [19] further confirmed the correlation between nighttime light brightness values and CO2 footprints, providing the theoretical foundation and empirical examples for modeling CO2 footprints on the basis of nighttime light data. Recently, some scholars have also started to apply nighttime light data to analyze CO2 footprints, proposing a quantitative method to monitor municipal CO2 footprints from top to bottom [20,21,22].
Based on measurements of CO2 footprints, evaluating CO2 emissions efficiency has become a popular area of academic study. Scholars have successively proposed various measurement criteria, such as the CO2 index (CO2 emissions per unit of energy consumption), energy intensity (energy consumption per unit of GDP), CO2 intensity (CO2 emissions per unit of GDP), etc. It is worth noting that the above criteria are ‘single indicators’ in nature, ignoring the impact of indicator substitution effects on CO2 reduction activities. As data envelopment analysis (DEA) methods become more established in the environmental field, more studies have shown that energy has to be integrated with production indicators such as capital and labor in order to obtain accurate outputs [23,24,25]. It is more reasonable to explore the issue of CO2 emissions efficiency in a full-indicator framework [26]. Traditional DEA models focus only on the desired outputs of economic activity and ignore the undesired ones, which biases the results. As a result, scholars have improved these models [27,28]. For example, Teng et al. introduced CO2 sinks as an exogenous variable into a modified dynamic SBM model based on China’s afforestation area data to assess provincial CO2 emissions efficiency [29]. Zhao et al. used the epsilon-based measure (EBM)-DEA model to estimate the CO2 emissions efficiency of the transport sector in Chinese provinces. They further explored the impact of transport structure, technological progress, and urbanization level on CO2 emissions efficiency [30]. Wu et al. used an extended SBM model to analyze the spatio-temporal evolution of provincial CO2 emissions efficiency. They used σ and spatial β-convergence tests to explore whether there was a catch-up trend in CO2 emissions efficiency among provinces [31]. Xie et al. used a super-SBM model to assess the CO2 emissions efficiency of 59 countries. They also used national panel quantile regressions to explore the multiple effects of technological progress on CO2 emissions efficiency [32].
Horizontal CO2 compensation can help to coordinate regional environmental protection measures and achieve ‘carbon neutrality’ [33]. CO2 compensation studies can be traced back to the 1950s, when the U.S., France, Mexico, and Costa Rica explored ‘ecological compensation’ as a method of environmental management. ‘Ecological compensation’ originally referred to the payments for ecosystem/environmental services (PES) made by environmental services consumers to suppliers for access to natural resource services [6,34,35]. Recently, PES has been applied extensively to transboundary pollution management, and CO2 compensation has become an emerging area of inquiry [9]. Scholars have focused on CO2 compensation studies from three main perspectives: theory, methods of measuring compensation amounts, and applications. (i) The public goods theory, ecological capital theory, and ecological justice theory together form the philosophical foundation and theoretical cornerstone of CO2 compensation. Public goods theory mainly emphasizes the negative externalities of CO2 emissions, meaning that one economic agent does not fully bear the costs of its emissions, causing welfare losses for other economic agents [36,37]. Scholars have attempted to construct a system that internalizes all externalities, leading to a debate on the Pigouvian CO2 tax and the Coasean approach. Ecological capital theory emphasizes the capital properties of CO2 emissions rights. More and more countries, organizations, and enterprises are realizing the value embedded in CO2 emissions rights. A CO2 trading market based on allowances has gradually developed, giving rise to CO2 emissions rights futures, options trading, and other financial products [38]. The ecological justice theory emphasizes the need for CO2 emissions behavior to be organically integrated with social justice, working to unlock the international climate dilemma of collective action [39,40]. (ii) The main methods for measuring CO2 compensation amounts include the ecosystem service value method [34], the cost analysis method [41], the willingness assessment method [42], and the footprints method [9]. For example, Cui et al. used the ecosystem service value method to investigate the impact of human activities on CO2 emissions from wetlands. They calculated the value of CO2 management in the Zoige wetland using a local trading price for CO2 reductions. Their method was consistent with the economic theory that value determines the price, and their accounting results were relatively objective [43]. Engel et al. used a cost analysis to model decisions on representative land. They designed payment schemes linked to the price of an agricultural crop (soybean) and the price of CO2 emissions by comparing the costs and future returns of interchanging the two land types of forest and agriculture. Their method considered the direct input costs for ecological conservation and the development opportunity costs [41]. Albertini et al. applied the willingness assessment method to assess the payment criteria for Italian and Czech households by conducting web-based interviews to determine participants’ willingness to pay for CO2 emissions from energy consumption. This method considered CO2 emitters’ willingness and facilitated the implementation and diffusion of CO2 compensation systems [44]. Hu et al. used the CO2 footprint and carrying capacity calculation methods to estimate the CO2 source and sink functions and spatial distribution of eleven municipalities in Jiangxi Province. They determined the horizontal ecological compensation amounts based on municipalities’ CO2 surplus and deficit statuses [9]. The footprints method is more applicable to calculating the horizontal CO2 compensation amounts than the other three methods. The main reason for this is that the statistical standards for energy consumption data in different regions are relatively consistent. The cost of ecological compensation can be conveniently and uniformly accounted for across municipalities based on CO2 footprints. (iii) Application studies of CO2 compensation are usually carried out for specific projects, such as CO2 compensation for engineering construction [45], reservoir development [46], forestry and grass types [47], etc. In contrast, horizontal CO2 compensation is still in the exploration stage, and studies on inter-provincial and inter-municipal CO2 compensation standards and models require further enrichment [48].
The remainder of this paper is structured as follows. Section 3 presents the data sources and methods. The methods include a method estimating CO2 footprints based on nighttime light data, a super-SBM model for calculating the CO2 emissions efficiency, and a method of calculating horizontal CO2 compensation amounts. Section 4 first presents trends in municipal CO2 footprints and their spatial correlation. Secondly, it describes the spatio-temporal differences in CO2 emissions efficiency. Finally, scenarios of horizontal CO2 compensation among municipalities are discussed from the two perspectives of CO2 footprints and CO2 trading (Figure 1). Section 5 summarizes and discusses the conclusions and recommendations.

3. Data and Methods

3.1. Data Collection

(1) DMSP/OLS stable annual light data for 2000–2013 were obtained from the National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration-National Geophysical Data Center (NOAA/NGDC, http://www.ngdc.noaa.gov/eog/dmsp.html, accessed on 13 May 2022). Monthly VIIRS/DNB light data for 2012–2019 were obtained from the Earth Observation Group (EOG, https://eogdata.mines.edu/products/vnl, accessed on 13 May 2022). MOD13A2-EVI vegetation indices were obtained from the National Aeronautics and Space Administration. Impervious surface data were derived from the Global Urban Boundary Dataset. (i) In this study, we applied continuum correction to DMSP/OLS data [49] and desaturated them using enhanced vegetation indices [50]. (ii) We converted the VIIRS/DNB data into annual sequence data, extracted the image elements with DN ≠ 0 in DMSP-OLS to generate a mask, and performed noise removal on the VIIRS/DNB data. (iii) After the processing, individual image element outliers were substituted with neighboring image element maxima. (iv) The high-precision extraction of information on built-up areas is a prerequisite for conducting CO2 footprint simulations. The optimal segmentation threshold was set to DN = 2.9 (via the mutation detection method) to extract the built-up area information [51]. The extraction accuracy (95.50%) was calculated based on the built-up area extracted from the impervious surface, and the results met the requirements. (v) The relationship between the 2013 DMSP/OLS and VIIRS/DNB data was quantified using an S-shaped function so that both had an identical spatial resolution and similar radiometric characteristics [52]. The derived relationship enabled us to generate globally coherent nighttime light raster data for 2000–2019, which masked the extraction of nighttime light data from Chinese municipalities.
(2) Energy data were obtained from the China Energy Statistical Yearbook and from provincial and municipal statistical yearbooks, covering eight types of energy: coal, coke, crude oil, gasoline, paraffin, diesel, energy oil, and natural gas. To measure the average energy, we calculate low-level calorific values according to the General Rules for Calculating Comprehensive Energy Consumption (GB/T2589-2008). The carbon content per unit calorific value and the carbon oxidation rate are referred to in the Guidelines for the Preparation of Provincial Greenhouse Gas Inventories (National Development and Reform Commission Climate (2011), No. 1041).
(3) CO2 emissions efficiency input indicators and desired output indicators are from the China Urban Statistical Yearbook, Shanghai Statistical Yearbook, Jiangsu Statistical Yearbook, Zhejiang Statistical Yearbook, and Anhui Statistical Yearbook.

3.2. Methods

3.2.1. Estimation of the CO2 Footprints

(1) Estimation of provincial CO2 footprints: we calculated CO2 footprint coefficients (Am) for coal (1.900 kg-CO2/kg), coke (2.860 kg-CO2/kg), crude oil (3.020 kg-CO2/kg), gasoline (2.925 kg-CO2/kg), paraffin (3.072 kg-CO2/kg), diesel (3.096 kg-CO2/kg), energy oil (3.171 kg-CO2/kg), and natural gas (2.162 kg-CO2/kg) based on the average energy low-level calorific value, the carbon content per unit calorific value, and the carbon oxidation rate. The provincial CO2 footprints (Cp) were calculated according to (Equation (1)).
C p = m = 1 M = 8 E p m × A m
where Epm is the consumption of the mth energy in the pth provincial district, m = 1, 2, 3 … M.
(2) Fitting of municipal CO2 footprints: The fitted curve (Equation (2)) was determined based on the total brightness values of provincial nighttime light (TNLIp) and the provincial CO2 footprints (Cp). Then, the municipal CO2 footprints (Ci) (Equation (3)) were estimated based on the regression parameter (ω), the power law parameter (τ) in Equation (2), and the total brightness value of municipal nighttime light (TNLIi).
C p = ω × T N L I p τ
C i = ω × T N L I i τ
(3) Accuracy checking of municipal CO2 footprints. We checked the model accuracy in two ways. The first method was to check the fitting of Equation (2). R2 was a critical indicator for comparing the fitting of the model. The higher the R2, the more reliable the regression results. The second method was to use municipalities with energy statistics as a test sample. We computed the actual CO2 footprints based on the energy statistics provided for the test sample. At the same time, the total brightness value of the nighttime light for the test sample was input into Equation (3) with the fitted CO2 footprints as the output for the same period. The deviation between the actual and fitted CO2 footprints was compared to check the accuracy of the results.

3.2.2. Estimation of CO2 Emissions Efficiency

(1) The super-SBM model is a popular method to determine CO2 emissions efficiency. Its mathematical logic is to compare the input–output systems of all municipalities and screen out the Pareto optimal solution with the lowest input and undesired output and the highest desired output to constitute the frontier surface. Slack variables are also incorporated into the objective function to calculate the deviation distance from each municipality to the production frontier surface and use it to evaluate the municipal CO2 emissions efficiency. The most significant advantage of the super-SBM model is that it solves the input–output slackness problem and the efficiency decomposition problem in the presence of undesired outputs without the need to estimate the parameters in advance or to make weighting assumptions. It avoids the influence of human subjective factors and broadens the applicable constraints of the model. In addition, it can overcome the previous drawback of not being able to compare the efficiency values of multiple municipalities when they are 1 [53,54]. Based on these characteristics, we applied the super-SBM model to measure the municipal CO2 emissions efficiency (ρit) (Equation (4)) [55].
(2) We constructed the input–output indicator system based on the principle that the number of input and output indicators should not exceed 1/3 of the number of decision-making units. (i) Rapid economic development is highly dependent on the scale of investment growth, especially in regard to enormous government-led investments in infrastructure. Strong geographical inertia is essential in the choice of location for large, energy-intensive, installation-based industries. Therefore, we calculated the social fixed-asset investment volume as capital inputs using the perpetual inventory method, with 2000 as the base year [56]. (ii) The material production process is the process of labor acting on productive resources. A large employment population attracts a concentration of labor-intensive industries, which can bring about problems such as a decrease in environmental air quality, while promoting economic development. Therefore, we chose year-end employment as a labor input [56,57]. (iii) The crucial aspect in developing a low-carbon economy is saving energy without curtailing economic output. Energy utilization efficiency has a material impact on the decarbonization of municipal economies. Therefore, based on the availability of data and the avoidance of covariance with undesired outputs, we used the total social electricity consumption as an energy input [56,58]. (iv) Science and technology expenditure drives CO2 capture and storage technologies from the experimental stage to the diffusion stage. It is a fundamental force in the transformation of economic models. Therefore, we used science and technology expenditure as a measure of municipalities’ technology inputs. (v) GDP (converted to constant 2000 prices) reflects the overall level of municipal economic development [56,57,58]. Retail sales of social consumer goods reflect the material living standards of citizens and the purchasing power of social goods. Both are positive indicators of the feasibility of the design path of decarbonization. Therefore, in this study we regarded them as desired outputs of CO2 reduction activities. (vi) Fossil energy combustion is the primary source of carbon increase in the atmosphere, and CO2 footprints are also the core of this paper. Therefore, CO2 footprints were considered undesired outputs of CO2 reduction activities [56,57,58].
ρ i t = min 1 1 A a = 1 A s i a t - i n x i a t 1 + 1 B + C ( b = 1 B s i b t - o u t y i b t + c C s i c t - o u t z i c t )
The constraints were as follows.
x i a t i = 1 , i j I ( x i a t λ i s i a t - i n ) , 1 1 B + C ( b = 1 B s i b t - o u t y i b t + c = 1 C s i c t - o u t z i c t ) > 0
where xiat, yibt, and zict are the ath input indicators, the bth desired output indicator, and the cth undesired output indicator for the ith municipality in year t, respectively. siat-in, sibt-out, and sict-out are the slack values of the above three indicators, respectively.

3.2.3. Horizontal CO2 Compensation Model

Horizontal CO2 compensation is an institutional arrangement that relies on economic instruments to regulate the interests of relevant municipalities to solve the negative externalities of CO2 emissions. We conducted a study in terms of CO2 footprints and CO2 trading (with CO2 unit prices in the trading process determined by CO2 emissions efficiency). The former concept was focused on energy consumption behavior, and this determined the CO2 compensation amounts paid by each municipality based on whether their CO2 footprints exceed their CO2 allowances. The compensation amounts were closely related to the municipal CO2 footprints. The latter concept focused on CO2 trading activities, and this involved charging purchasing municipalities a fee based on the economic benefits generated in transferring CO2 emissions rights among municipalities. In this way, we designed a horizontal CO2 compensation model from a binary perspective. In terms of equity (whether CO2 footprints exceeded CO2 allowances) and efficiency (whether the CO2 emissions efficiency reached the average level), we classified municipalities into four types: ‘high-efficiency and low-emissions’, ‘high-efficiency and high-emissions’, ‘low-efficiency and high-emissions’, and ‘low-efficiency and low-emissions’ municipalities (Figure 1).
From the perspective of CO2 footprints: The YRD exhibits uneven economic development. ‘One-size-fits-all’ instruments will lead to inefficient and unfair horizontal CO2 compensation. Therefore, in this study, we followed the principle of a universal levy and additional adjustments.
Firstly, we used the historical CO2 intensity method [59] to allocate CO2 allowances to municipalities (Equation (5)).
q i t = ϑ G D P i t
where GDPit is the GDP of the ith municipality in year t. ϑ is a base value for the historical CO2 intensity. When the CO2 intensity continues to rise or fall in years t − 3 to t − 1 and the cumulative change exceeds 30%, ϑ is taken as the CO2 intensity in year t − 1. Otherwise, ϑ takes the average value of the CO2 intensity in years t − 3 to t − 1.
Then, a differentiated CO2 footprint income and expenditure coefficient (CFIE) was developed, including a baseline CFIE (δq) and an additional CFIE (δ∆q). For CO2-deficit municipalities, CO2 footprints were paid at δq for the portion not exceeding the CO2 allowances, and the excess was paid at δq. For CO2-surplus municipalities, CO2 footprints were paid at δq, whereas these municipalities are compensated at δq according to their remaining CO2 space. The baseline CO2 footprint compensation amounts paid at δq are an essential component of the financial transfer among municipalities (top tier) under the YRD emissions reduction responsibility-sharing mechanism. These ultimately come from the CO2 tax levied by the municipal government on local enterprises or residents (the bottom tier). Therefore, δq should be relatively consistent with the observed value of the CO2 tax rate (RMB 40/ton). In addition, we set the value of δ∆q based on the growth curve function (Equation (6)) [60].
δ Δ q = ( 1 + G D P i t × ρ i t φ ( 1 + e f ) i = 1 I ( G D P i t × ρ i t φ ) ) δ q
where f is the average value of the Engel coefficient of the 41 municipalities in year t. φ is taken to be a constant in order to avoid the excessive influence of CO2 emissions efficiency on σt.
Finally, we calculated the CO2 footprint compensation amounts Ai′t for the i′th CO2-deficit municipalities (Equation (7)) and Ait for the i″th CO2-surplus municipalities (Equation (8)), respectively.
A i t = δ q × C i t + δ Δ q ( C i t q i t )
A i t = δ q × C i t δ Δ q ( q i t C i t )
(2) From the perspective of CO2 trading with a price mechanism determined by CO2 emissions efficiency: As a valuable asset and strategic resource with geographical attributes, CO2 emissions rights are a unique intangible commodity. The inequality in CO2 emissions efficiency leads to differences in the economic benefits obtained per unit of CO2 emissions among municipalities. On the one hand, CO2 trading follows a self-regulatory mechanism for pricing. The higher a municipality’s CO2 emissions efficiency, the higher the unit prices of the CO2 emissions rights (CO2 unit prices) it sells, and vice versa. On the other hand, CO2 emissions rights may generate added value during transfers among municipalities, from which the purchasing municipality benefits. In this study, we calculated the input amounts (Ab) based on the CO2 unit prices in the selling municipality and the output amounts (As) based on the CO2 unit prices in the purchasing one. Equation (9) was used to calculate the CO2 trading compensation amounts (Ait) to be paid by the purchasing municipality.
A i t = A s A b = ( ρ i t p r i ) Δ c δ ( ρ i t p r i ) Δ c δ
where pri is the CO2 unit price, which was set to RMB 36.36/ton [9]. (ρit·pri) and (ρit·pri) are the CO2 unit prices in the selling and purchasing municipalities, respectively. ∆c is the CO2 trading volume. δ′ is the value-added coefficient for CO2 turnover based on the VAT rate for intangible asset transfers (6%).
To maximize the economic benefits for the entire YRD, the government plays the following regulatory role (Figure 1). (i) The government strictly controls the sales of ‘high-efficiency and low-emissions’ municipalities at a suppressed price in CO2 trading. (ii) The government uses part of the CO2 compensation amounts in the form of energy savings and environmental protection investments to the ‘low-efficiency and high-emissions’ and ‘low-efficiency and low-emissions’ municipalities to help these poorly performing municipalities in an intelligent way. Part of these amounts are in the form of financial subsidies to guide ‘high-efficiency and low-emissions’ and ‘low-efficiency and low-emissions’ municipalities to prioritize the CO2 emissions needs of ‘high-efficiency and high-emissions’ municipalities. ‘High-efficiency and high-emissions’ municipalities compete for priority purchase rights through competition for CO2 emissions efficiency among themselves. (iii) The government uses penalties to discourage municipalities with high CO2 emissions efficiency from selling CO2 emissions rights to municipalities with low CO2 emissions efficiency (∆c < ∆cG) (Figure 2). Accordingly, in this study we have designed a CO2 trading market.
When i I ( P i t c i t ) < i I ( c i t P i t ) , competition mainly occurs among selling municipalities in a CO2 trading market with a surplus of total CO2 allowances, and the overall economic benefits brought about by CO2 trading are E cot = Δ c = 0 Δ c = i I ( P i t c i t ) f ( ρ i t ) f ( ρ i t ) d Δ c . When i I ( P i t c i t ) > i I ( c i t P i t ) , competition mainly occurs among purchasing municipalities in a CO2 trading market with a shortage of total CO2 allowances, and the overall economic benefits brought about by CO2 trading are E cot = Δ c = 0 Δ c = i I ( c i t P i t ) f ( ρ i t ) f ( ρ i t ) d Δ c (Figure 2).

4. Results

4.1. Spatio-Temporal Evolution of CO2 Footprints

4.1.1. Accuracy Checking of Municipal CO2 Footprints

After comparing the accuracy obtained in several experiments, we selected 30 provincial districts (excluding Tibet, Hong Kong, Macao, and Taiwan) to fit the total brightness values of nighttime light and CO2 footprints. The fitted curves were determined based on three sets of panel data during the periods 2000–2006, 2007–2013, and 2014–2019 to estimate the CO2 footprints of 275 municipalities. We extracted the CO2 footprints of 41 municipalities in the YRD. Table 1 and Figure 3 show that all had R2 values higher than 0.7, and all relative errors were 5.013–5.209%, which means that the estimation results had good accuracy.

4.1.2. Evolutionary Characteristics of the CO2 Footprints

Overall, the growth in energy demand in the YRD has led to a rise in CO2 footprints, from 745,919 million tons in 2000 to 1,881,457 million tons in 2019. In particular, from 2004 to 2011, the growth rate was the fastest, with an average annual growth rate of 8.69%. The pressure to reduce emissions is increasing. The growth rate in CO2 footprints from 2012 to 2019 has converged, with the average annual growth rate falling to 0.49%. The effectiveness of CO2 reduction continues to emerge.
Figure 4 shows the trends observed in the municipal CO2 footprints. Eleven municipalities, such as Shanghai (12,000–13,500 million tons), Suzhou (J.S.) (12,000–15,000 million tons), and Ningbo (7500–10,000 million tons), were in the CO2 peak range between 2010 and 2014, after which, they showed a decline. This indicates that the energy consumption structure of these municipalities has shown clean and low-carbon characteristics, and the effectiveness of CO2 reduction is beginning to show. Since 2014, the CO2 footprints of thirteen municipalities, including Hangzhou, Shaoxing, and Hefei, have stabilized. This indicates that the energy consumption of these municipalities has entered a period of ‘steady-to-moderate’ adjustment and that their economic development and industrial structures are undergoing a process of quantitative to qualitative change. The CO2 footprints of thirteen municipalities, including Fuyang and Bozhou, exhibited a vigorous increase. This is partly due to energy savings from technological progress being compensated for by additional energy consumption from economic growth. On the other hand, it is due to CO2 leakage from inter-municipality product trade and industrial transfers. Huangshan, Chizhou, Zhoushan, and Tongling, the CO2 footprints of which grew slowly and only crossed the 10 million tons threshold after 2010, have long maintained a robust supply of ecological products in the YRD.
Spatially, CO2 footprints decreased from the core of Shanghai to the marginal regions, with a significant spatial gradient. Figure 5 shows an inverted U-shaped development in the Moran’ I based on global spatial autocorrelation analysis. Between 2000 and 2008, CO2 emissions showed a high–high (HH) and low–low (LL) positive spatial agglomeration pattern, with the Moran’s I showing an upward trend from 0.338 to 0.490. This indicates that municipalities tended to focus on energy development and transport construction to improve the investment environment. Energy storage conditions and supply prices became an essential consideration standard for many enterprises to select locations during that period, leading to the spatial concentration of energy-consuming economic activities. After 2009, the proportion of high–low (HL) and low–high (LH) heterogeneous agglomeration patterns increased, and the Moran’s I showed a downward trend to 0.301. This indicates that people’s awareness of environmental protection has increased, and the type and amount of energy utilized affect the image of enterprises and the public’s acceptance of industrial activities. Many energy-intensive enterprises have either upgraded or moved out of their original locations. Figure 6 shows that CO2 footprints have club convergence characteristics based on local spatial autocorrelation analysis. The spatial distribution of HH agglomeration patterns (Shanghai, Suzhou (J.S.), Nantong, etc.) and LL agglomeration patterns (Chizhou, Huangshan, Tongling, etc.) was stable. This indicates that the spatial stability of the CO2 footprint agglomeration pattern in the YRD formed a local spatial pattern of ‘the lower is always lower, and the higher is always higher’. This is mainly because of the neighborhood and spatial spillover effect of CO2 emissions. The policy measures and strategic actions adopted by surrounding municipalities in terms of economic development and industrial layout have effects related to imitating, learning, and competing. There is convergence or complementarity in economic structures among neighboring municipalities.

4.2. Spatio-Temporal Evolution of CO2 Emissions Efficiency

Overall, the average value of CO2 emissions efficiency in the YRD has shown a fluctuating upward trend, with a significant fluctuation between 2008 and 2013. The main reason for this is that in 2008, China introduced a series of measures to expand domestic social consumption demand, such as the ‘package’, in response to the international financial crisis, which led to a large amount of capital flowing to energy-intensive industries. This led to a decline in CO2 emissions efficiency for two consecutive years in 2009 and 2010. In 2011, the outline of the 12th Five-Year Plan included CO2 intensity as a binding target. The YRD has responded positively to constructing a low-carbon economy, and CO2 emissions efficiency has been significantly improved, with the average value rising from 0.642 in 2010 to 0.739 in 2013.
Specifically, in this study we classified CO2 emissions efficiency into five levels (Figure 7): extreme low-value (0.201–0.400), low-value (0.401–0.700), medium-value (0.701–1.000), high-value (1.001~1.300), and extreme high-value (1.301–1.700). Between 2000 and 2006, CO2 emissions efficiency was generally low. Except for Nantong (ρ2003 = 1.079 and ρ2005 = 1.021), Jinhua (ρ2006 = 1.048), and Jiaxing (ρ2006 = 1.068), which reached an effective frontier in individual years, all other municipalities exhibited a non-effective status (ρt < 1). The low-value areas were the most widely distributed. The medium-value areas evolved from a discrete point shape in 2000 to an inverse S-shape in 2006. Southern Jiangsu and the Hangzhou Bay region became growth hotspots, with Wuxi and Shaoxing showing slower growth rates and lagging behind surrounding municipalities in CO2 emissions efficiency. Between 2007 and 2013, the CO2 emissions efficiency of more municipalities reached the efficiency frontier. The low-value areas contracted further, and the medium-value areas expanded to become the most widely distributed type. The overall spatial pattern of CO2 emissions efficiency was high in the east and low in the west, with a symmetrical north–south distribution. Between 2014 and 2019, the extreme high-value and high-value areas were distributed along the Shanghai–Wuhan and Zhuji–Yongjia highway axes, with the formation of a backbone structure of Shanghai–Nanjing and Shanghai–Hangzhou–Ningbo. At the same time, some of the medium-value areas degenerated into low-value areas. Spatial homogenization evolved into spatial fragmentation with a mosaic driven by multiple cores.

4.3. Horizontal CO2 Compensation Scenarios

4.3.1. Horizontal CO2 Compensation Based on CO2 Footprints

Each municipality needs to take responsibility for CO2 reduction and share the cost of environmental protection through financial payments to compensate its CO2 footprints. In this study, we used the historical CO2 intensity method to allocate CO2 allowances to municipalities. The CO2 emissions rights within these allowances maintain the sustainable development of each municipality’s economy, so each municipality pays its baseline CO2 footprint compensation amounts at a lower baseline CFIE (δq). Figure 8a shows that the curve expressing the baseline CO2 footprint compensation amounts evolved from a general-normality to a standard-normality distribution. Namely, this curve flattened out from N~(884.228, 669.2062) in 2003 to N~(1804.084, 853.3612) in 2019. This suggests that the baseline compensation amounts increased significantly between 2003 and 2019, whereas the gap in the baseline compensation amounts among municipalities continued to narrow. This indicates that the baseline compensation amounts increases the absolute cost of emission reduction for municipalities, which is conducive to forcing municipalities to form a self-restraint mechanism, but it is difficult to have an effect on the relative cost of emission reduction. Therefore, it is necessary to pay the additional compensation amounts in case of exceeding the CO2 allowance.
To curb the negative economic externalities of CO2 emissions, CO2-deficit municipalities need to pay additional amounts for their CO2 footprints at a higher additional CFIE (δq). At the same time, these amounts are used to compensate CO2-surplus municipalities at the same rate. Figure 8a shows that the curve expressing additional CO2 footprint compensation amounts evolved from a single peak to double peaks, with the peak gradually moving away from ‘y = 0’, indicating the evolution of the degree of CO2 surplus and deficit in the YRD towards polarization. In 2003, most municipalities did not exceed their CO2 allowances, and the additional CO2 footprint compensation amounts were concentrated around ‘y = 0’. Since then, some municipalities have shown increasing CO2 deficits, whereas others have gradually left more space for CO2 emissions. Between 2010 and 2019, the additional CO2 footprint compensation amounts paid by CO2-deficit municipalities and the amounts returned to CO2-surplus municipalities evolved towards a normal distribution, with symmetrical changes between the two. The difference in the additional CO2 footprint compensation amounts paid among CO2-deficit municipalities is small, and its curve is short and fat. However, the difference in the amounts returned among CO2-surplus municipalities is larger and its curve is thin and high.
Securing economic growth is a prerequisite for a low-carbon transition. Figure 8b shows that the ratio of the CO2 footprint compensation amounts (baseline compensation amounts + additional compensation amounts) to GDP in most municipalities from 2003 to 2011 was more than 0.01%. This suggests that the CO2 footprint compensation amounts would impose a disproportionate burden on local enterprises. Since 2011, the ratio of the CO2 footprint compensation to GDP has been decreasing. Except for some municipalities in Anhui, all others are capable of synergizing CO2 emissions reductions with economic development. Therefore, it is appropriate for the YRD to introduce CO2 footprint compensation amounts after 2011. The process requires compensation for some municipalities to reduce the distortionary effect of the CO2 footprint compensation amounts.
A horizontal CO2 compensation system based on CO2 footprints requires both stability in the long term and volatility in the short term. Figure 9 shows that before 2011, some municipalities in the Huaihai Urban Cluster and the Hefei Metropolitan Area frequently shifted from surplus to deficit status, with CO2 compensation zones increasingly shrinking. If a horizontal CO2 footprint compensation system were to be imposed in this period, it would increase the cost of policy implementation and governmental regulation. After 2011, CO2-surplus municipalities were mainly located in the marginal regions, and the status of CO2 surpluses and deficits remained stable over time. Additionally, the migration trajectory of the center of gravity of CO2 footprint compensation amounts showed that it oscillated back and forth in a southeast–northwest direction with irregularities between 2003 and 2010. After 2011, it shifted in a northwest direction, with the distance moved increasing every three years. The standard deviation ellipses in the 2011–2013, 2014–2016, and 2017–2019 periods were largely overlapping. Therefore, a horizontal CO2 footprint compensation system with a three-year adjustment period after 2011 could not only lead to savings in the cost of policy implementation but also help to avoid the problem of ‘incorrect collection and omission’ caused by delays in policy implementation and untimely feedback.

4.3.2. Horizontal CO2 Compensation Based on CO2 Trading with a Price Mechanism Determined by CO2 Emissions Efficiency

Figure 10a shows that between 2003 and 2007, the CO2 surplus/deficit differential fluctuated around zero. This indicates that some municipalities had remaining CO2 space to meet the excess emissions of CO2-deficit municipalities and that the supply and demand in the CO2 market were relatively balanced. After 2007, the CO2 market was in short supply for a long time, reaching the lowest level in 2011 and 2016, with a significant imbalance between supply and demand. After 2016, the contradiction between supply and demand in the CO2 market gradually eased. The gap between supply and demand rebounded from −41,685,600 tons in 2016 to −12,090,600 tons in 2019.
The CO2 emissions efficiency of both sides of the transaction shows that most of the purchasing municipalities had significantly higher CO2 emissions efficiency than the selling ones. The purchasing municipalities tended to have high GDP and low CO2 emissions per unit of input and output indicators, whereas the selling ones tended to have the opposite. Therefore, the CO2 emissions space left by the selling municipalities for the purchasing ones increased the economic added value of CO2 emissions. In particular, the positive economic benefits increased rapidly after 2012, from RMB 105,619.81 million to RMB 383,468.02 million in 2019 (Figure 10b). The operation of a ‘you reduce emissions and I pay’ CO2 trading strategy would not only optimize the allocation of CO2 emissions rights but also improve the overall economic benefits of low-carbon development in the YRD.
Under government regulation, municipalities with higher CO2 emissions efficiency would achieve higher economic benefits per unit of CO2 emissions by purchasing the emissions rights of other municipalities. Following the principle of ‘I gain and I pay’, the purchasing municipalities pay CO2 trading compensation amounts. Figure 10a shows that the total CO2 trading compensation amounts increased significantly, from RMB 1055.17 million in 2003 to RMB 22,040.81 million in 2019. The area’s Gini coefficient first increased and then decreased, from 0.817 in the 2003–2006 period to 0.829 in the 2007–2013 period, and then fell to 0.789 in the 2014–2019 period, consistently above 0.5 (Figure 10c). This indicates a wide disparity in CO2 trading compensation amounts among municipalities. In particular, between 2007 and 2013, CO2 trading was highly dependent on a few economically advanced municipalities, such as Shanghai and Nanjing, increasing the vulnerability of the CO2 market. Since 2013, the vulnerability of the CO2 market decreased as the property rights and traceability of CO2 emissions became clear. Municipalities have become more active in CO2 trading and are generally more receptive to CO2 trading compensation amounts.
The CO2 trading data among municipalities showed that the CO2 surplus and deficit status were unstable between 2003 and 2006. This led to frequent role changes and complex game relationships among municipalities in the trading process, which was not conducive to government regulation. For example, Huaibei, Yancheng, and Suzhou (A.H.) gradually shifted from being purchasing municipalities to selling municipalities, whereas Bengbu, Yangzhou, and Chuzhou gradually shifted from being selling municipalities to purchasing municipalities. Between 2007 and 2013, more municipalities, such as Lianyungang and Wuhu, exceeded their CO2 allowances and shifted from selling municipalities to purchasing ones, whereas a few switched from purchasing municipalities to selling ones. During this period, the volatility of the YRD’s CO2 emissions efficiency led to high fluctuations in the CO2 unit prices. For example, the CO2 unit prices for selling municipalities such as Zhoushan declined due to a decline in CO2 emissions efficiency, which significantly reduced the profitability of CO2 trading in an environment where demand exceeded supply. The CO2-deficit municipalities such as Nanjing and Jiaxing had seen their CO2 emissions efficiency decline, leading to a gradual shift of the ‘right of first refusal’ to Ningbo and Wuxi, where CO2 emissions efficiency was rapidly increasing. Between 2013 and 2019, the trading roles, CO2 unit prices, tradable volumes, and rights of first refusal of municipalities all stabilized. In an environment in which demand exceeded supply for long periods, the game among CO2 market players was mainly played among purchasing municipalities. For example, Shanghai and Suzhou (J.S.) were in a race for the right of first refusal (lower CO2 buy-in unit price), whereas Bozhou and Fuyang were competing for purchasing rights to CO2 emission space.

5. Conclusions and Discussion

5.1. Conclusions

In this study, we estimated the CO2 footprints of 41 municipalities in the YRD based on nighttime lighting data and calculated their CO2 emissions efficiency using the super-SBM model. Based on this, we discussed the scenarios of horizontal CO2 compensation among municipalities from binary perspective—CO2 footprints and CO2 trading. Our main conclusions were as follows.
(1) With the relocation and upgrading of energy-intensive industries, the overall spatial correlation of CO2 footprints in the YRD has weakened. However, the HH and LL agglomeration patterns are still characterized by significant club convergence. Low-carbon economic development is a long-term process of a change in energy structure, with different municipalities located at various stages of evolution. Shanghai and others have experienced a decline in their CO2 footprints, whereas Hangzhou and others are in the transition phase toward a CO2 peak. The CO2 footprints of Taizhou (J.S.) and others are rising strongly, whereas Huangshan and others continue to maintain slow growth.
(2) The average value of CO2 emissions efficiency in the YRD has shown a fluctuating upward trend and a high degree of responsiveness to national policies. From 2000 to 2006, the southern Jiangsu and Hangzhou Bay regions were the growth hotspots of CO2 emissions efficiency, with Wuxi and Shaoxing showing relatively slow growth rates. From 2007 to 2013, the overall spatial pattern of CO2 emissions efficiency was high in the east and low in the west, with a symmetrical north–south distribution. From 2014 to 2019, the extreme high-value and high-value areas of CO2 emissions efficiency were distributed along the Shanghai–Wuhan and Zhuji–Yongjia highway axes, with the formation of a backbone structure of Shanghai–Nanjing and Shanghai–Hangzhou–Ningbo.
(3) In terms of CO2 footprint compensation amounts (baseline amounts + additional amounts), the ratio of CO2 footprint compensation to local GDP was less than 0.01% in most municipalities after 2011, and the trajectory of its standard elliptical center of gravity showed a regular shift. Therefore, it was appropriate for the YRD to implement a horizontal CO2 footprint compensation system after 2011. In the process, it would be necessary to strengthen ecological compensation for some municipalities in Anhui and implement dynamic adjustments for three years.
(4) In terms of CO2 trading compensation amounts, the CO2 emissions efficiency of most purchasing municipalities was higher than that of selling municipalities, which enhanced the economic added value of CO2 trading in the YRD. From 2000 to 2006, Huaibei and others exhibited fluctuating role transformations in CO2 trading, and the game relationship among municipalities was complex. From 2007 to 2013, the volatility of CO2 emissions efficiency led to high volatility in CO2 unit prices, reinforcing the fluidity of the ‘right of first refusal’ advantage. From 2014 to 2009, the role of municipalities, CO2 unit prices, tradable volume, and the right of first refusal gradually stabilized, the CO2 trading mechanism was improved, and the CO2 trading compensation amounts increased significantly.

5.2. Recommendations

Based on the above conclusions, we propose two potential routes for CO2 reduction: cross-border governance and the internal management of municipalities.
(1) We recommend the building of a closed-loop CO2 compensation management system consisting of ‘council + executive committee + regulator + industrial sector’ at the level of cross-border governance, rotating among three provinces and one provincial municipality. (i) The council should scientifically set the milestones of the ‘carbon peak’ and ‘carbon neutrality’ for each municipality and reasonably allocate CO2 allowances. At the same time, the council should establish an early-warning red line for the degradation of input/output indicators, as well as formulating policies for sharing responsibility and compensation for CO2 emission reductions. (ii) The executive committee should be responsible for financial transfer payments and horizontal compensation among local governments, according to whether the municipalities exceed their CO2 allowances. At the same time, it should regularly take stock of new trends in the development of low-carbon technologies and new changes in the CO2 emissions efficiency of municipalities and provide macro-guides for the inter-regional flow of production elements. (iii) The regulator should mainly supervise and arbitrate the decisions of the council and the ‘accountability and cash system’ of the executive committee, as well as managing the CO2 credits of each municipality. (iv) On the one hand, the industrial sector should regulate the industry and eliminate the problem of an underdeveloped production capacity. On the other hand, it should build a multilateral exchange platform to circumvent the problems of market information asymmetry and transaction hedging, as well as encouraging the organization of the main body to reach a green contract across the region.
(2) Each municipality should take into account its situation in order to develop a differentiated CO2 reduction route. In ‘high-efficiency and low-emissions’ municipalities, the labor- and energy-intensive industries showed outward decentralization. Compared with the industrial ‘carbon peak’, the reduction of CO2 emissions at the consumption end is relatively lagging. Therefore, these municipalities need to develop a broader carbon tax base. They should not only levy carbon taxes on energy-intensive industries, forcing industries to upgrade, but also gradually levy carbon taxes on residents to achieve a shift from a high-carbon society to a low-carbon society.
In ‘high-efficiency and high-emissions’ municipalities, the ‘CO2 decoupling’ phenomenon of economic development was not yet significant. Their higher CO2 emissions efficiency also relaxes the ecological constraints for these municipalities to take over the industrial transfer from ‘high-efficiency and low-emissions’ municipalities. However, if these municipalities only undertake purely replicative industries, this will introduce hidden problems for their sustainable development in later years. Therefore, these municipalities should levy a carbon tax on the production process, raise the entry threshold of energy-intensive industries, and improve the structure of domestic and international investment in the region.
For ‘low-efficiency and high-emissions’ municipalities, taking over resource-based industries is a vital choice to maximize resources and drive economic growth. However, resource-intensive industries are mostly high-carbon industries, which seriously hinder the development of a low-carbon economy. Therefore, these municipalities can decompose various by-products in the industrial chain level by level and form an efficient resource recycling system through the vertical and horizontal coupling of the industrial chain.
For ‘low-efficiency and low-emissions’ municipalities that are technologically underdeveloped and have a superior ecological background, a carbon tax should serve to build a firm ecological protection barrier. These municipalities should guide their industrial layouts and development in a centralized manner, and they should use their CO2 compensation amounts for the ecological transformation of industrial areas. They can also adopt the compensation method of ‘off-site development’ to find new development platforms in the neighboring ecological beneficiary municipalities, thus promoting the synergistic development of the local ecology and economy.

5.3. Discussion

Horizontal CO2 compensation studies have significant theoretical and practical implications for regional equity and sustainable development. The footprints method is an effective way to determine horizontal CO2 compensation. While accounting for CO2 footprints, Hu et al. introduced the ‘CO2 sink’ concept into the calculation, measured the difference between the two from the perspective of CO2 balance, and then multiplied it with the CO2 price to determine their CO2 compensation standards [9]. However, such compensation standards are based on the absolute amount of the CO2 deficit and do not consider the differences in resource endowments and emission reduction potential among different regions. The historical CO2 intensity method is a convenient solution to this problem. It calculates CO2 intensity based on municipalities’ historical production data and CO2 emissions, which are used as a basis to decrease year by year and thus determine the CO2 allowances for the following year. CO2 allowances can be adjusted in line with changes in input/output indicators, urging municipalities to reduce their own emissions [59]. Therefore, in this study, we applied the historical CO2 intensity method to allocate CO2 allowances to the 41 municipalities, as well as differentially levied CO2 compensation amounts based on whether the CO2 footprints exceeded their allowances. This approach differs from those presented in the studies of Hu et al. [9] and Yang et al. [10] in that they only levied amounts on CO2/environmental-deficit cities, probably due to the consideration of reducing the economic burdens on CO2/environmental-surplus cities. In this study, the CO2 emission rights within the CO2 allowances maintain sustainable economic development, and the government levies the CO2 footprint baseline compensation amounts to each municipality at a lower baseline CFIE (δq). In addition, the CO2-deficit municipalities need to pay additional CO2 footprint amounts at a higher additional CFIE (δq) to compensate CO2-surplus municipalities, which reduces the distortionary effect of horizontal compensation to a certain extent. Moreover, in this study we also considered the ratio of CO2 footprint compensation to local GDP and the stability of the CO2 surplus and deficit status. When the ratio is too high or when the surplus and deficit status is unstable, horizontal CO2 compensation is not recommended.
In addition, we considered the added value and fairness of CO2 trading with a price mechanism determined by CO2 emissions efficiency. Shi et al. focused on the operational mechanisms of inter-city CO2 trading, the allocation model of CO2 allowances, and the impact of market supply and demand on CO2 emissions [59]. However, their study did not discuss the economic value added to CO2 emission rights in CO2 trading. In response, our study represents a continuation of this research. As municipalities have different CO2 emission efficiencies, the economic benefits generated per unit of CO2 emissions vary. CO2-deficit municipalities require the purchase of CO2 emissions rights from CO2-surplus ones. CO2 emission rights for trading receive a higher economic value if the CO2 emissions efficiency of the purchasing municipalities is higher than that of the selling ones. Although the selling municipalities receive turnover for the sale of CO2 emissions rights, the purchasing ones acquire a higher added value. Therefore, the purchasing municipalities are required to pay CO2 trading compensation amounts. This approach helps to establish a mechanism to share the responsibility for emissions reductions among the municipalities in the YRD and provides a model for a horizontal CO2 compensation system for the whole country.
Ultimately, we believe it is feasible to establish a mechanism for apportioning responsibility for emissions reductions from both a ‘CO2 footprint’ and ‘CO2 trading’ perspective. There is strong empirical evidence that some countries are implementing a combination of the CO2 tax and CO2 trading. For example, Denmark, Finland, and Norway have introduced CO2 taxes and followed them up with the EU Emissions Trading Scheme. Although such policies have targeted enterprises or industries, they have inspired China to develop regional policies to reduce emissions. For example, the Opinions on Improving the Compensation Mechanism for Ecological Protection mentioned establishing a system for the initial allocation of CO2 emissions rights and promoting horizontal ecological protection compensation. The Study on China’s CO2 Balance Trading Framework recommended introducing an inter-provincial CO2 emissions trading system. This paper provides a methodological basis for developing innovative regional CO2 reduction policies.
There are still shortcomings of this study. The optimal CO2 footprint compensation amounts depended on the marginal damage or marginal pollution cost per unit of pollutant, determined at the optimal pollution emission level. However, in reality, this cost is difficult to measure, and to some extent, it affects the setting of the optimal CFIE (δq and δ∆q). In this study, we initially established the CFIE with a 3-year adjustment cycle and the value-added coefficient for CO2 turnover based on the VAT rate for intangible asset transfers. Refinements and development should be carried out in subsequent studies in order to reach a more desirable CO2 reduction state. There is also a need to further clarify the municipalities’ CO2 emission reduction targets and set entry thresholds for CO2 trading.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, L.W.; methodology, L.W.; software, L.W., Y.F. and Y.Z.; validation, Q.Z., Y.F. and C.R.; formal analysis, L.W. and T.W.; investigation, Q.Z., C.R.; resources, L.W. and Y.Z.; data curation, L.W.; writing—original draft preparation, L.W. and Q.Z.; writing—review and editing, L.W. and Q.Z.; visualization, L.W.; supervision, T.W.; project administration, T.W.; funding acquisition, T.W. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research was funded by ‘National Natural Science Foundation of China, grant number 41471103’, ‘National Natural Science Foundation of China, grant number 42271183’ and ‘Major Projects of Philosophy and Social Science Research in Universities in Jiangsu Province, grant number 2020SJZDA135’.

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

No new data were created or analyzed in this study. Data sharing is not applicable to this article.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Mohsin, M.; Naseem, S.; Sarfraz, M.; Azam, T. Assessing the effects of fuel energy consumption, foreign direct investment and GDP on CO2 emission: New data science evidence from Europe & Central Asia. Fuel 2022, 314, 123098. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Sarfraz, M.; Naseem, S.; Mohsin, M.; Bhutta, M.S.; Jaffri, Z.U.A.; Chen, C.; Zhang, Z.; Wei, L.; Qiu, Y.; Xu, W.; et al. Recent analytical tools to mitigate carbon-based pollution: New insights by using wavelet coherence for a sustainable environment. Environ. Res. 2022, 212, 113074. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  3. Ali, U.; Guo, Q.; Kartal, M.T.; Nurgazina, Z.; Khan, Z.A.; Sharif, A. The impact of renewable and non-renewable energy consumption on carbon emission intensity in China: Fresh evidence from novel dynamic ARDL simulations. J. Environ. Manag. 2022, 320, 115782. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  4. Zhou, S.; Li, W.; Lu, Z.; Lu, Z. A technical framework for integrating carbon emission peaking factors into the industrial green transformation planning of a city cluster in China. J. Clean. Prod. 2022, 344, 131091. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Tian, S.; Xu, Y.; Wang, Q.; Zhang, Y.; Yuan, X.; Ma, Q.; Chen, L.; Ma, H.; Liu, J.; Liu, C. Research on peak prediction of urban differentiated carbon emissions—A case study of Shandong Province, China. J. Clean. Prod. 2022, 374, 134050. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Sheng, J.; Qiu, W.; Han, X. China’s PES-like horizontal eco-compensation program: Combining market-oriented mechanisms and government interventions. Ecosyst. Serv. 2020, 45, 101164. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Yang, G.; Shang, P.; He, L.; Zhang, Y.; Wang, Y.; Zhang, F.; Zhu, L.; Wang, Y. Interregional carbon compensation cost forecast and priority index calculation based on the theoretical carbon deficit: China as a case. Sci. Total. Environ. 2019, 654, 786–800. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Welch, R. Monitoring urban population and energy utilization patterns from satellite Data. Remote Sens. Environ. 1980, 9, 1–9. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Hu, X.F.; Zou, Y.; Fu, C. Spatial and temporal patterns of the ecological compensation criterion in Jiangxi Province, China based on carbon footprint. Chin. J. Appl. Ecol. 2017, 28, 493–499. [Google Scholar]
  10. Yang, Y.; Zhang, Y.; Yang, H.; Yang, F. Horizontal ecological compensation as a tool for sustainable development of urban agglomerations: Exploration of the realization mechanism of Guanzhong Plain urban agglomeration in China. Environ. Sci. Policy 2022, 137, 301–313. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Yuan, X.; Sheng, X.; Chen, L.; Tang, Y.; Li, Y.; Jia, Y.; Qu, D.; Wang, Q.; Ma, Q.; Zuo, J. Carbon footprint and embodied carbon transfer at the provincial level of the Yellow River Basin. Sci. Total Environ. 2022, 803, 149993. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Zhang, L.; Ruiz-Menjivar, J.; Tong, Q.; Zhang, J.; Yue, M. Examining the carbon footprint of rice production and consumption in Hubei, China: A life cycle assessment and uncertainty analysis approach. J. Environ. Manag. 2021, 300, 113698. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  13. Long, Y.; Yoshida, Y.; Liu, Q.; Zhang, H.; Wang, S.; Fang, K. Comparison of city-level carbon footprint evaluation by applying single- and multi-regional input-output tables. J. Environ. Manag. 2020, 260, 110108. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  14. Zhu, W.; Feng, W.; Li, X.; Zhang, Z. Analysis of the embodied carbon dioxide in the building sector: A case of China. J. Clean. Prod. 2020, 269, 122438. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Li, Q.; Gao, M.; Li, J. Carbon emissions inventory of farm size pig husbandry combining Manure-DNDC model and IPCC coefficient methodology. J. Clean. Prod. 2021, 320, 128854. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Liu, Z.; Guan, D.; Wei, W.; Davis, S.J.; Ciais, P.; Bai, J.; Peng, S.; Zhang, Q.; Hubacek, K.; Marland, G.; et al. Reduced carbon emission estimates from fossil fuel combustion and cement production in China. Nature 2015, 524, 335–338. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  17. Ohms, P.K.; Laurent, A.; Hauschild, M.Z.; Ryberg, M.W. Consumption-based screening of climate change footprints for cities worldwide. J. Clean. Prod. 2022, 377, 134197. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Elvidge, C.D.; Baugh, K.E.; Kihn, E.A.; Kroehl, H.W.; Davis, E.R.; Davis, C.W. Relation between satellite observed visible-near infrared emissions, population, economic activity and electric power consumption. Int. J. Remote Sens. 1997, 18, 1373–1379. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Doll, C.H.; Muller, J.-P.; Elvidge, C.D. Night-time Imagery as a Tool for Global Mapping of Socioeconomic Parameters and Greenhouse Gas Emissions. AMBIO J. Hum. Environ. 2000, 29, 157–162. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Li, J.; He, S.; Wang, J.; Ma, W.; Ye, H. Investigating the spatiotemporal changes and driving factors of nighttime light patterns in RCEP Countries based on remote sensed satellite images. J. Clean. Prod. 2022, 359, 131944. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Liu, H.; Ma, L.; Xu, L. Estimating spatiotemporal dynamics of county-level fossil fuel consumption based on integrated nighttime light data. J. Clean. Prod. 2021, 278, 123427. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Wei, W.; Zhang, X.; Zhou, L.; Xie, B.; Zhou, J.; Li, C. How does spatiotemporal variations and impact factors in CO2 emissions differ across cities in China? Investigation on grid scale and geographic detection method. J. Clean. Prod. 2021, 321, 128933. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Dar, A.A.; Hameed, J.; Huo, C.; Sarfraz, M.; Albasher, G.; Wang, C.; Nawaz, A. Recent optimization and panelizing measures for green energy projects; insights into CO2 emission influencing to circular economy. Fuel 2022, 314, 123094. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Shah, W.U.H.; Hao, G.; Yan, H.; Yasmeen, R.; Jie, Y. The role of energy policy transition, regional energy efficiency, and technological advancement in the improvement of China’s environmental quality. Energy Rep. 2022, 8, 9846–9857. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Zhang, J.; Xing, Z.; Wang, J. Analysis of CO2 Emission Performance and Abatement Potential for Municipal Industrial Sectors in Jiangsu, China. Sustainability 2016, 8, 697. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  26. Tian, Z.; Ren, F.-R.; Xiao, Q.-W.; Chiu, Y.-H.; Lin, T.-Y. Cross-Regional Comparative Study on Carbon Emission Efficiency of China’s Yangtze River Economic Belt Based on the Meta-Frontier. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2019, 16, 619. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
  27. Sun, J.; Dong, F. Decomposition of carbon emission reduction efficiency and potential for clean energy power: Evidence from 58 countries. J. Clean. Prod. 2022, 363, 132312. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Wen, S.; Jia, Z.; Chen, X. Can low-carbon city pilot policies significantly improve carbon emission efficiency? Empirical evidence from China. J. Clean. Prod. 2022, 346, 131131. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Teng, X.; Liu, F.-P.; Chiu, Y.-H. The change in energy and carbon emissions efficiency after afforestation in China by applying a modified dynamic SBM model. Energy 2021, 216, 119301. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Zhao, P.; Zeng, L.; Li, P.; Lu, H.; Hu, H.; Li, C.; Zheng, M.; Li, H.; Yu, Z.; Yuan, D.; et al. China’s transportation sector carbon dioxide emissions efficiency and its influencing factors based on the EBM DEA model with undesirable outputs and spatial Durbin model. Energy 2022, 238, 121934. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Wu, H.; Huang, H.; Chen, W.; Meng, Y. Estimation and spatiotemporal analysis of the carbon-emission efficiency of crop production in China. J. Clean. Prod. 2022, 371, 133516. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Xie, Z.; Wu, R.; Wang, S. How technological progress affects the carbon emission efficiency? Evidence from national panel quantile regression. J. Clean. Prod. 2021, 307, 127133. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Qu, Y.; Cang, Y. Cost-benefit allocation of collaborative carbon emissions reduction considering fairness concerns—A case study of the Yangtze River Delta, China. J. Environ. Manag. 2022, 321, 115853. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  34. Sheng, W.; Zhen, L.; Xie, G.; Xiao, Y. Determining eco-compensation standards based on the ecosystem services value of the mountain ecological forests in Beijing, China. Ecosyst. Serv. 2017, 26, 422–430. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Arowolo, A.O.; Deng, X.; Olatunji, O.A.; Obayelu, A.E. Assessing changes in the value of ecosystem services in response to land-use/land-cover dynamics in Nigeria. Sci. Total Environ. 2018, 636, 597–609. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  36. Zugravu-Soilita, N. The impact of trade in environmental goods on pollution: What are we learning from the transition economies’ experience? Environ. Econ. Policy Stud. 2018, 20, 785–827. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Sturm, B.; Pei, J.; Wang, R.; Löschel, A.; Zhao, Z. Conditional cooperation in case of a global public good – Experimental evidence from climate change mitigation in Beijing. China Econ. Rev. 2019, 56, 101308. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Liu, M.; Zhou, C.; Lu, F.; Hu, X. Impact of the implementation of carbon emission trading on corporate financial performance: Evidence from listed companies in China. PLoS ONE 2021, 16, e0253460. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Teixidó-Figueras, J.; Steinberger, J.K.; Krausmann, F.; Haberl, H.; Wiedmann, T.; Peters, G.P.; Duro, J.A.; Kastner, T. International inequality of environmental pressures: Decomposition and comparative analysis. Ecol. Indic. 2016, 62, 163–173. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  40. Byrne, J.; Martinez, C.; Ruggero, C. Relocating Energy in the Social Commons. Bull. Sci. Technol. Soc. 2009, 29, 81–94. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  41. Engel, S.; Palmer, C.; Taschini, L.; Urech, S. Conservation Payments under Uncertainty. Land Econ. 2015, 91, 36–56. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Xiong, K.; Kong, F. The Analysis of Farmers’ Willingness to Accept and Its Influencing Factors for Ecological Compensation of Poyang Lake Wetland. Procedia Eng. 2017, 174, 835–842. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Cui, Q.; Wang, X.; Li, C.; Cai, Y.; Liu, Q.; Li, R. Ecosystem service value analysis of CO2 management based on land use change of Zoige alpine peat wetland, Tibetan Plateau. Ecol. Eng. 2015, 76, 158–165. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Alberini, A.; Bigano, A.; Ščasný, M.; Zvěřinová, I. Preferences for Energy Efficiency vs. Renewables: What Is the Willingness to Pay to Reduce CO2 Emissions? Ecol. Econ. 2018, 144, 171–185. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Fu, B.; Wang, Y.; Xu, P.; Yan, K.; Li, M. Value of ecosystem hydropower service and its impact on the payment for ecosystem services. Sci. Total Environ. 2014, 472, 338–346. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Yu, B.; Xu, L.; Yang, Z. Ecological compensation for inundated habitats in hydropower developments based on carbon stock balance. J. Clean. Prod. 2016, 114, 334–342. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Jing, X.; Tian, G.; Li, M.; Javeed, S.A. Research on the Spatial and Temporal Differences of China’s Provincial Carbon Emissions and Ecological Compensation Based on Land Carbon Budget Accounting. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2021, 18, 12892. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  48. Peng, Z.; Pu, H.; Huang, X.; Zheng, R.; Xu, L. Study on public willingness and incentive mechanism of ecological compensation for inter-basin water transfer in China in the carbon neutral perspective. Ecol. Indic. 2022, 143, 109397. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Hu, T.; Wang, T.; Yan, Q.; Chen, T.; Jin, S.; Hu, J. Modeling the spatiotemporal dynamics of global electric power consumption (1992–2019) by utilizing consistent nighttime light data from DMSP-OLS and NPP-VIIRS. Appl. Energy 2022, 322, 119473. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Zheng, Y.; Tang, L.; Wang, H. An improved approach for monitoring urban built-up areas by combining NPP-VIIRS nighttime light, NDVI, NDWI and NDBI. J. Clean. Prod. 2021, 328, 129488. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Zhang, Y.; Pan, J. Spatio-temporal simulation and differentiation pattern of carbon emissions in China based on DMSP/OLS nighttime light data. China Environ. Sci. 2019, 39, 1436–1446. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Li, X.; Zhou, Y.; Zhao, M.; Zhao, X. A harmonized global nighttime light dataset 1992–2018. Sci. Data 2020, 7, 168. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  53. Wei, L.; Wang, Z. Differentiation Analysis on Carbon Emission Efficiency and Its Factors at Different Industrialization Stages: Evidence from Mainland China. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2022, 19, 16650. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Fu, J.; Ding, R.; Zhang, Y.; Zhou, T.; Du, Y.; Zhu, Y.; Du, L.; Peng, L.; Zou, J.; Xiao, W. The Spatial-Temporal Transition and Influencing Factors of Green and Low-Carbon Utilization Efficiency of Urban Land in China under the Goal of Carbon Neutralization. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2022, 19, 16149. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Zeng, T.; Jin, H.; Geng, Z.; Kang, Z.; Zhang, Z. The Effect of Urban Shrinkage on Carbon Dioxide Emissions Efficiency in Northeast China. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2022, 19, 5772. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  56. Zheng, R.; Cheng, Y.; Liu, H.; Chen, W.; Chen, X.; Wang, Y. The Spatiotemporal Distribution and Drivers of Urban Carbon Emission Efficiency: The Role of Technological Innovation. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2022, 19, 9111. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Liu, L.; Zhang, Y.; Gong, X.; Li, M.; Li, X.; Ren, D.; Jiang, P. Impact of Digital Economy Development on Carbon Emission Efficiency: A Spatial Econometric Analysis Based on Chinese Provinces and Cities. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2022, 19, 14838. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  58. Xu, Y.; Cheng, Y.; Zheng, R.; Wang, Y. Spatiotemporal Evolution and Influencing Factors of Carbon Emission Efficiency in the Yellow River Basin of China: Comparative Analysis of Resource and Non-Resource-Based Cities. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2022, 19, 11625. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Shi, B.; Li, N.; Gao, Q.; Li, G. Market incentives, carbon quota allocation and carbon emission reduction: Evidence from China’s carbon trading pilot policy. J. Environ. Manag. 2022, 319, 115650. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Zhao, R.; Liu, Y.; Ma, L.; Li, Y.; Hou, L.; Zhang, Z.; Ding, M. County-level carbon compensation of Henan province based on carbon budget estimation. J. Nat. Resour. 2016, 31, 1675–1687. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Diagram of the horizontal CO2 compensation mechanism in the YRD. Note: eff. and emi. are abbreviations for efficiency and emissions, respectively.
Figure 1. Diagram of the horizontal CO2 compensation mechanism in the YRD. Note: eff. and emi. are abbreviations for efficiency and emissions, respectively.
Ijerph 20 01369 g001
Figure 2. Diagram of the economic benefits based on CO2 trading. Note: When ∆c < ∆cG, the CO2 emissions efficiency of all the purchasing municipalities is higher than that of the selling ones, and CO2 emission rights for ∆c tons lead to positive economic benefits in CO2 trading (SDCEF), which is also the overall economic benefit. when ∆c > ∆cG, the CO2 emissions efficiency of some purchasing municipalities is lower than that of the selling ones, and ∆c tons of CO2 emission rights generate positive benefits (SEDG), while (∆c − ∆cG) tons lead to negative economic benefits (SHKG), and the overall economic benefit is (SEDGSHKG).
Figure 2. Diagram of the economic benefits based on CO2 trading. Note: When ∆c < ∆cG, the CO2 emissions efficiency of all the purchasing municipalities is higher than that of the selling ones, and CO2 emission rights for ∆c tons lead to positive economic benefits in CO2 trading (SDCEF), which is also the overall economic benefit. when ∆c > ∆cG, the CO2 emissions efficiency of some purchasing municipalities is lower than that of the selling ones, and ∆c tons of CO2 emission rights generate positive benefits (SEDG), while (∆c − ∆cG) tons lead to negative economic benefits (SHKG), and the overall economic benefit is (SEDGSHKG).
Ijerph 20 01369 g002
Figure 3. Deviation of the fitted CO2 footprints based on night-time light from the CO2 footprints based on energy statistics.
Figure 3. Deviation of the fitted CO2 footprints based on night-time light from the CO2 footprints based on energy statistics.
Ijerph 20 01369 g003
Figure 4. Spatio-temporal evolution of the CO2 footprints in the YRD from 2000 to 2019.
Figure 4. Spatio-temporal evolution of the CO2 footprints in the YRD from 2000 to 2019.
Ijerph 20 01369 g004
Figure 5. Global spatial autocorrelation Moran’s I of CO2 footprints in the YRD.
Figure 5. Global spatial autocorrelation Moran’s I of CO2 footprints in the YRD.
Ijerph 20 01369 g005
Figure 6. Spatial distribution of night light and CO2 footprints in the built-up area of the YRD.
Figure 6. Spatial distribution of night light and CO2 footprints in the built-up area of the YRD.
Ijerph 20 01369 g006
Figure 7. Spatio-temporal evolution of CO2 emissions efficiency in the YRD.
Figure 7. Spatio-temporal evolution of CO2 emissions efficiency in the YRD.
Ijerph 20 01369 g007
Figure 8. CO2 footprint compensation amounts and its ratio to local GDP in the YRD.
Figure 8. CO2 footprint compensation amounts and its ratio to local GDP in the YRD.
Ijerph 20 01369 g008
Figure 9. Evolution of CO2 surplus and deficit and CO2 footprint compensation amounts in the YRD.
Figure 9. Evolution of CO2 surplus and deficit and CO2 footprint compensation amounts in the YRD.
Ijerph 20 01369 g009
Figure 10. Evolution of supply–demand relationship and economic benefits in CO2 trading of the YRD.
Figure 10. Evolution of supply–demand relationship and economic benefits in CO2 trading of the YRD.
Ijerph 20 01369 g010
Table 1. Parameters and estimation accuracy of the CO2 footprints fitting curve.
Table 1. Parameters and estimation accuracy of the CO2 footprints fitting curve.
PeriodsωτR2Relative Error
2000~20060.03510.8015.041%
2007~20130.03610.7995.209%
2014~20190.03210.8075.014%
Note: In determining the CO2 footprints fitting curve, τ was set to 1/2, 1, 2, and 3 separately. The results showed that the R2 of the fitting curve was optimal when τ = 1 (linear fit). Therefore, only the results for τ = 1 are listed in the table.
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Wang, L.; Zhang, Y.; Zhao, Q.; Ren, C.; Fu, Y.; Wang, T. Horizontal CO2 Compensation in the Yangtze River Delta Based on CO2 Footprints and CO2 Emissions Efficiency. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2023, 20, 1369. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph20021369

AMA Style

Wang L, Zhang Y, Zhao Q, Ren C, Fu Y, Wang T. Horizontal CO2 Compensation in the Yangtze River Delta Based on CO2 Footprints and CO2 Emissions Efficiency. International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health. 2023; 20(2):1369. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph20021369

Chicago/Turabian Style

Wang, Luwei, Yizhen Zhang, Qing Zhao, Chuantang Ren, Yu Fu, and Tao Wang. 2023. "Horizontal CO2 Compensation in the Yangtze River Delta Based on CO2 Footprints and CO2 Emissions Efficiency" International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health 20, no. 2: 1369. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph20021369

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop