Climate Change Mitigation in Households between Market Failures and Psychological Barriers
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Barriers of Energy Efficiency Improvement and Assessment of Policies to Overcome Them
- Economic and financial barriers linked to high costs of energy efficiency measures due to not internalized external costs of fossil fuel-based energy and external benefits linked energy efficiency improvements or other financial barriers linked to the problem of access to and availability of capital funds;
- Institutional and regulatory barriers linked to not well-established regulatory requirements and regulations for insulation of buildings, especially regulation of old residential buildings stock;
- Technology barriers linked to lack of knowledge of available renovation technologies, options and other energy efficiency improvement issues and their costs and benefits;
- Informational barriers linked to market failures linked to information asymmetry and split incentives between landlords and tenants;
- Organizational barriers linked to the lack of set process on how to entitle individuals or institutions with the responsibility and authority to identify, plan, and implement renovation of multi-flat buildings. Logistical barriers include a lack of skilled energy renovation service providers in the market. In addition, there are significant switching costs linked to any change.
3. Barriers of Renewable Energy Sources and Assessment Policies to Overcome Them
4. Discussion of Results
5. Conclusions and Future Research Orientations
Author Contributions
Funding
Conflicts of Interest
References
- EC. Communication from the Commission to the European Parliament, the Council, the European Economic and Social Committee and the Committee of the Regions. In A New Circular Economy Action Plan for a Cleaner and More Competitive Europe; COM: Brussels, Belgium, 2020. [Google Scholar]
- Jaffe, A.; Stavins, R. The energy-efficiency gap. What does it mean? Energy Policy 1994, 22, 804–810. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Jaffe, A.; Newell, R.; Stavins, R. Economics of energy efficiency. Encycl. Energy 2004, 2, 79–90. [Google Scholar]
- Ramos, A.; Gago, A.; Labandeira, X.; Linares, P. The role of information for energy efficiency in the residential sector. Energy Econ. 2015, 52, 517–529. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Banfi, S.; Farsi, M.; Filippini, M.; Jakob, M. Willingness to pay for energy-saving measures in residential buildings. Energy Econ. 2008, 30, 503–516. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Alberini, A.; Banfi, S.; Ramseier, C. Energy efficiency investments in the home: Swiss homeowners and expectations about future energy prices. Energy J. 2013, 34, 49–86. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Achtnicht, M. Do environmental benefits matter? Evidence from a choice experiment among house owners in Germany. Ecol. Econ. 2011, 70, 2191–2200. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Chau, C.; Tse, M.; Chung, K. A choice experiment to estimate the effect of green experience on preferences and willingness-to-pay for green building attributes. Build. Environ. 2010, 45, 2553–2561. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kwak, S.; Yoo, S.; Kwak, S. Valuing energy-saving measures in residential buildings: A choice experiment study. Energy Policy 2010, 38, 673–677. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Štreimikienė, D.; Baležentis, A.; Ališauskaitė-Šeškienė, I.; Stankūnienė, G.; Simanavičienė, Ž. A Review of Willingness to Pay Studies for Climate Change Mitigation in the Energy Sector. Energies 2019, 12, 1481. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Li, C. Essays on Climate Change Mitigation, Building Energy Efficiency, and Urban Form. Ph.D. Dissertation, University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill Graduate School, Chapel Hill, NC, USA, 2018. Available online: https://cdr.lib.unc.edu/concern/dissertations/rn301251f?locale=en (accessed on 1 April 2020).
- Li, C.; Song, Y.; Kaza, N.; Burghardt, R. Explaining Spatial Variations in Residential Energy Usage Intensity in Chicago: The Role of Urban Form and Geomorphometry. J. Plan. Educ. Res. 2019. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Li, C.; Song, Y.; Kaza, N. Urban form and household electricity consumption: A multilevel study. Energy Build. 2018, 158, 181–193. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dabija, A.-M. Rehabilitation of Mass Dwellings in Romania. A Critical Approach. Sci. Bull. Electr. Eng. Fac. 2010, 10, 40–45. [Google Scholar]
- Herrero, S.T.; Urge-Vorsatz, D. Trapped in the heat: A post-communist type of fuel poverty. Energy Policy 2012, 49, 60–68. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Boute, A. Modernizing the Russian district heating sector: Financing energy efficiency and renewable energy investments under the New Federal Heat Law. Pace Environ. Law Rev. 2012, 29, 746–810. [Google Scholar]
- Bouzarovski, S. Energy poverty in the European Union: Landscapes of vulnerability. WIREs Energy Environ. 2014, 3, 276–289. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Labanca, N.; Suerkemper, F.; Bertoldi, P.; Irrek, W.; Duplessis, B. Energy efficiency services for residential buildings: Market situation and existing potentials in the European Union. J. Clean. Prod. 2015, 109, 284–295. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Weinsziehr, T.; Grossmann, K.; Groger, M.; Bruckner, T. Building retrofit in shrinking and agening cities: A case-based investigation. Build. Res. Inf. 2017, 45, 278–292. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zorić, J.; Hrovatin, N. Household willingness to pay for green electricity in Slovenia. Energy Policy 2012, 47, 180–187. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Boardman, B. Fixing Fuel Poverty: Challenges and Solutions; Earthscan: London, UK, 2010. [Google Scholar]
- Roe, B.; Teisl, M.F.; Levy, A.; Russell, M. US consumers’ willingness to pay for green electricity. Energy Policy 2001, 29, 917–925. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bigerna, S.; Polinori, P. Italian households’ willingness to pay for green electricity. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2014, 34, 110–121. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Scarpa, R.; Willis, K. Willingness-to-pay for renewable energy: Primary and discretionary choice of British households’ for micro-generation technologies. Energy Econ. 2010, 32, 129–136. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Štreimikienė, D.; Baležentis, A. Assessment of willingness to pay for renewables in Lithuanian households. Clean Technol. Environ. Policy 2014, 17, 515–531. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Su, W.; Liu, M.; Zeng, S.; Štreimikienė, D.; Baležentis, T.; Ališauskaitė-Šeškienė, I. Valuating renewable microgeneration technologies in Lithuanian households: A study on willingness to pay. J. Clean. Prod. 2018, 191, 318–329. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Alberini, A.; Bigano, A.; Ščasný, M.; Zvěřinová, I. Preferences for Energy Efficiency vs. Renewables: What Is the Willingness to Pay to Reduce CO2 Emissions? Ecol. Econ. 2018, 144, 171–185. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Reddy, S.; Painuly, J.P. Diffusion of renewable energy technologies—barriers and stakeholders’ perspectives. Renew. Energy 2004, 29, 1431–1447. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Seetharaman Moorthy, K.; Patwa, N.; Saravanan; Gupta, Y. Breaking barriers in deployment of renewable energy. Heliyon 2019, 5, e01166. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Alam, S.S.; Hazrul, N.; Hashim, N.; Rashid, M.; Omar, N.A.; Ahsan, N.; Ismail, N.M. Small-scale households renewable energy usage intention: Theoretical development and empirical settings. Renew. Energy 2014, 68, P255–P263. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Palm, J.; Tengvard, M. Motives for and barriers to household adoption of small-scale production of electricity: Examples from Sweden, Sustainability: Science. Pract. Policy 2011, 7, 6–15. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Lu, J.; Ren, L.; Yao, S.; Rong, D.; Skare, M.; Streimikis, J. Renewable energy barriers and coping strategies: Evidence from the Baltic States. Sustain. Dev. 2020, 28, 352–367. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gifford, R. The Dragons of Inaction: Psychological Barriers That Limit Climate Change Mitigation and Adaptation. Am. Psychol. 2011, 66, 290–302. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gifford, R.; Kormos, C.; Mclntyre, A. Behavioral dimensions of climate change: Drivers, responses, barriers, and interventions. WIREs Clim. Chang. 2011, 2, 801–827. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Savitz, R.; Gavriletea, M.D. Climate Change and Insurance. Transform. Bus. Econ. 2019, 18, 21–43. [Google Scholar]
- Beillan, V.; Battaglini, E.; Goater, A.; Huber, A.; Mayer, I.; Trotignon, R. Barriers and drivers to energy efficient renovation in the residential sector Empirical findings from five European countries. In European Council for an Energy Efficient Economy; Summer Study: Hyeres, France, 2011. [Google Scholar]
- Byrnes, L.; Brown, C.; Foster, J.; Wagner, L.D. Australian renewable energy policy: Barriers and challenges. Renew. Energy 2013, 60, 711–721. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Levinson, A. How much energy do building energy codes really save? Evidence from California. Natl. Bur. Econ. Res. NBER 2014, 106, 2867–2894. [Google Scholar]
- Aroonruengsawat, A.; Auffhammer, M.; Sanstad, A. The impacts of state level building codes on residential electricity consumption. Energy J. 2012, 33, 31–52. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Jacobsen, G.D.; Kotchen, M.J. Are building codes effective at saving energy? Evidence from residential billing data in Florida. Rev. Econ. Stat. 2013, 95, 34–49. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Gillingham, K.; Newell, R.; Palmer, K. Energy efficiency and policy. Annu. Rev. Resour. Econ. 2009, 1, 597–620. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ryan, L.; Moarif, S.; Levina, E.; Baron, R. Energy Efficiency Policy and Carbon Pricing. Information Paper; International Energy Agency: Parsi, France, 2011. [Google Scholar]
- Mourato, S.; Saynor, B.; Hart, D. Greening London’s black cabs: A study of driver’s preferences for fuel cell taxis. Energy Policy 2004, 32, 685–695. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Nair, G.; Gustavsson, L.; Mahapatra, K. Owners perception on the adoption of building envelope energy efficiency measures in Swedish detached houses. Appl. Energy 2010, 57, 2411–2419. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Stem, P.; Aronson, E.; Darley, J.; Kempton, W.; Hill, D.; Hirst, E. Answering behavioral questions about energy efficiency in buildings. Energy 1987, 12, 339–353. [Google Scholar]
- Allcott, H.; Greenstone, M. Is there an energy efficiency gap? J. Econ. Perspect. 2012, 26, 3–28. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Allcott, H. Social norms and energy conservation. J. Public Econ. 2011, 95, 1082–1095. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Allcott, H.; Mullainathan, S. Behavior and energy policy. Science 2010, 327, 1204–1205. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Shogren, F.; Taylor, L. On behavioral-environmental economics. Rev. Environ. Econ. Policy 2008, 2, 26–44. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Tietenberg, T. Reflections on energy efficiency policy: Pipe dream or pipeline to the future? Rev. Environ. Econ. Policy 2009, 3, 304–320. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gillingham, K.; Palmer, K. Bridging the energy efficiency gap. policy insights from economic theory and empirical evidence. Rev. Environ. Econ. Policy 2013, 8, 18–38. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Stavins, R.; Schatzki, T.; Borck, J. An Economic Perspective on Building Labeling Policies; Analysis Group, Economic Financial and Strategy Consultants: Vigo, Spain, 2013. [Google Scholar]
- Cattaneo, C. Internal and external barriers to energy efficiency: Which role for policy interventions? Energy Effic. 2019, 12, 1293–1311. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Papineau, M. Energy codes and the landlord-tenant problem. In Carleton Economic Papers, CEP 15–03; Carleton University: Ottawa, ON, Canada, 2013. [Google Scholar]
- Schleich, J.; Gassmann, X.; Faure, C.; Meissner, T. Making the implicit explicit: A look inside the implicit discount rate. Energy Policy 2016, 97, 321–331. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Štreimikienė, D.; Baležentis, T. Innovative Policy Schemes to Promote Renovation of Multi-Flat Residential Buildings and Address the Problems of Energy Poverty of Aging Societies in Former Socialist Countries. Sustainability 2019, 11, 15. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Arabatzis, G.; Kyriakopoulos, G.; Tsialis, P. Typology of regional units based on RES plants: The case of Greece. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2017, 78, 1424–1434. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Patterson, J.L. Evaluation of a Regional Retrofit Programme to Upgrade Existing Housing Stock to Reduce Carbon Emissions, Fuel Poverty and Support the Local Supply Chain. Sustainability 2016, 8, 12. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Organ, S.; Proverbs, D.; Squires, G. Motivations for energy efficiency refurbishment in owner-occupied housing. Struct. Surv. 2013, 31, 101–120. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ozarisoy, B.; Altan, H. Adoption of Energy Design Strategies for Retrofitting Mass Housing Estates in Northern Cyprus. Sustainability 2017, 9, 1477. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Horne, R.; Dalton, T. Transition to low carbon? An analysis of socio-technical change in housing renovation. Urban Stud. 2014, 51, 3445–3458. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Claudy, M.; O’Driscoll, A. Beyond Economics—A behavioural approach to energy efficiency in domestic buildings. Euro-Asian J. Sustain. Energy Dev. Policy 2008, 1, 27–40. [Google Scholar]
- Friege, J.; Chappin, E. Modelling decisions on energy-efficient renovations: A review. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2014, 39, 196–208. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Asadi, E.; Gameiro da Silva, M.; Henggeler Antunes, C.; Dias, L. Multi-objective optimization for building retrofit strategies: A model and an application. Energy Build. 2012, 44, 81–87. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Christensen, T.H.; Gram-Hanssen, K.; Adjei, A.; de Best-Waldhober, M. Energy renovation practices in Danish homes: The influence of energy labels on home renovation practices. In Proceedings of the 10th Conference of the European Sociological Association (esa2011): Social Relations in Turbulent Times, Geneve, Switzerland, 7–10 September 2011. [Google Scholar]
- Sirombo, E.; Filippi, M.; Catalano, A. Building monitoring system in a large social housing intervention in Northern Italy. Energy Procedia 2017, 140, 389–397. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Killip, G. Products, practices and processes: Exploring the innovation potential for low-carbon housing refurbishment among small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) in the UK construction industry. Energy Policy 2013, 62, 522–530. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Risch, A.C. Evaluation of the impact of environmental public policy measures on energy consumption and greenhouse gas emissions in the French residential sector. Energy Policy 2012, 46, 170–184. [Google Scholar]
- Crilly, M.; Lemon, M.; Wright, A.J.; Cook, M.B.; Shaw, D. Retrofitting homes for energy efficiency: An integrated approach to innovation in the low-carbon overhaul of UK social housing. Energy Environ. 2012, 23, 1027–1056. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Raza, W.; Saula, H.; Islam, S.U.; Ayub, M.; Saleem, M.; Raza, N. Renewable energy resources: Current status and barriers in their adaptation for Pakistan. J. Bioprocess. Chem. Eng. 2015, 3, 1–9. [Google Scholar]
- Sardianou, E.; Genoudi, P. Which factors affect the willingness of consumers to adopt renewable energies? Renew. Energy 2013, 57, 1–4. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sovacool, B.K. Rejecting renewables: The socio-technical impediments to renewable electricity in the United States. Energy Policy 2009, 37, 4500–4513. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Poortinga, W.; Steg Vlek, C. Values, Environmental Concern, and Environmental Behavior: A Study into Household Energy Use. Environ. Behav. 2004, 36, 70–93. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Golove, W.H.; Eto, J.H. Market Barriers to Energy Efficiency: A Critical Reappraisal of the Rationale for Public Policies to Promote Energy Efficiency; Lawrence Berkeley National Laboratory: Berkeley, CA, USA, 1996. [Google Scholar]
- Liu, L.; Kang, C.; Yin, Z.; Liu, Z. The Effects of Fiscal and Taxation Policies on the Innovation Efficiency of Manufacturing Enterprises: A Comparative Study from the Perspective of Economic Regions. Transform. Bus. Econ. 2019, 18, 206–229. [Google Scholar]
- Burger, V. The assessment of the regulatory and support framework for domestic buildings in Germany from the perspective of long-term climate protection targets. Energy Policy 2013, 59, 71–81. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Frederiks, E.R.; Stenner, K.; Hobman, E.V. Household energy use: Applying behavioural economics to understand consumer decision-making and behaviour. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2015, 41, 1385–1394. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Dias, R.; Mattos, C.; Balesieri, J. Energy education: Breaking up the rational energy use barriers. Energy Policy 2004, 32, 1339–1347. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Frey, B.; Jegen, R. Motivation crowding theory: A survey of empirical evidence. J. Econ. Surv. 2001, 15, 589–611. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Frey, B. Excise taxes: Economics, politics, and psychology. In Theory and Practice of Excise Taxation: Smoking, Drinking, Gambling, Polluting, and Driving; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 2005. [Google Scholar]
- DellaVigna, S. Psychology and economics: Evidence from the field. J. Econ. Lit. 2009, 47, 315–372. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Stadelmann, M. Mind the gap? Critically reviewing the energy efficiency gap with empirical evidence. Energy Res. Soc. Sci. 2017, 27, 117–128. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mullainathan, S.; Thaler, R. Behavioral Economics; MIT Department of Economics: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2000. [Google Scholar]
- Kahneman, D.; Tversky, A. Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica 1979, 47, 263–292. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Loomes, G.; Sugden, R. Regret theory: An alternative theory of rational choice under uncertainty. Econ. J. 1982, 92, 805–824. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Pollitt, M.G.; Shaorshadze, I. The Role of Behavioural Economics in Energy and Climate Policy; University of Cambridge: Cambridge, UK, 2011. [Google Scholar]
- Pothitou, M.; Hanna, R.F.; Chalvatzis, K.J. Environmental knowledge, pro-environmental behaviour and energy savings in households: An empirical study. Appl. Energy 2016, 184, 1217–1229. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Rathi, S.S.; Chunekar, A. Not to buy or can be ‘nudged’ to buy? Exploring behavioral interventions for energy policy in India. Energy Res. Soc. Sci. 2015, 7, 78–83. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Papież, M.; Śmiech, S.; Frodyma, K. Determinants of renewable energy development in the EU countries. A 20-Year Perspective. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2018, 91, 918–934. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Poortinga, W.; Steg, L.; Vlek, C.; Wiersma, G. Household preferences for energy-saving measures: A conjoint analysis. J. Econ. Psychol. 2003, 24, 49–64. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Niamir, L.; Ivanova, O.; Filatova, T.; Voinov, A.; Bressers, H. Demand-side solutions for climate mitigation: Bottom-up drivers of household energy behavior change in the Netherlands and Spain. Energy Res. Soc. Sci. 2020, 62, 101356. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hung, L.-S.; Bayrak, M.M. Wives influence climate change mitigation behaviours in married-couple households: Insights from Taiwan. Environ. Res. Lett. 2019, 14, 124034. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gonzalez-Hernandez, D.L.; Meijles, E.W.; Vanclay, F. Factors that influence climate change mitigation and adaptation action: A household study in the Nuevo Leon Region, Mexico. Climate 2018, 7, 74. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Serrano-Medrano, M.; Garcia-Bustamante, C.; Berrueta, V.M.; Martmez-Bravo, R.; Ruiz-Garcia, V.M.; Ghilardi, A.; Masera, O. Promoting LPG, clean wood burning cook stoves or both? Climate change mitigation implications of integrated household energy transition scenarios in rural Mexico. Environ. Res. Lett. 2018, 13, 115004. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Lekve Bjelle, E.; Steen-Olsen, K.; Wood, R. Climate change mitigation potential of Norwegian households and the rebound effect. J. Clean. Prod. 2018, 172, 208–217. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Barriers and Market Failures | Typologies | Explanations |
---|---|---|
Economic and financial barriers | High costs of energy efficiency measures | High costs of energy efficiency measures and high costs of energy renovation of buildings are linked to the fact that external costs of fossil fuel-based energy and external benefits linked energy efficiency improvements are not internalized and do not sent clear market signals to customers to undertake energy efficiency improvements [5,6,9]. |
Limited access to capital | Households usually encounter problems related to access to capital due to high cost of borrowing and low anticipated earnings. They do not want to take loans due to debt defaults or other individual reasons [11,36]. | |
Uncertainties linked to property prices | Low and uncertain property values are also important barriers torenovation of multi-flat buildings, as owners who anticipate selling their property in the future may not feel encouraged to renovate their property [44,54,55]. | |
Hidden and high transaction costs | There are hidden costs linked to energy renovation in residential buildings. These costs are also linked to risks due to possible irreconcilabilities and associated risks etc. Higher transaction costs for energy renovation are linked with organizational problems in terms of renovation of multi-apartment buildings as there are many actors in process of initiating renovation of multi-flat building and agreement of all apartment owners is necessary making transaction costs higher than in the case of public or commercial buildings [7]. | |
Institutional and Regulatory barriers | Problems with legal framework for renovation of residential buildings | There are no firm frameworks and well-established schemes for implementation of energy renovation programmes, especially in multi-flat buildings [11,12,13,14,15,19,21,52]. |
Insufficient enforcement of standards | For energy efficiency improvements in old buildings there are no standards and any other regulatory enforcements to renovate these buildings [4,39,40]. | |
Lack of equipment for monitoring | Households which do not have possibilities to monitor their energy consumption are unwilling to search for information on energy renovation or energy efficiency improvement options for their homes [36]. | |
Inadequate energy service levels | Energy services provided by utilities to households are not well established like in case of commercial and public buildings [16,17,18]. | |
Technological barriers | Technological difficulties linked to micro generation technologies in buildings | Due to the lack of well-established standards for micro generation technologies and the lack of equipment, components and spare parts for renewable energy technologies create additional barriers [53]. |
Scarcity of investment in R&D of energy efficiency enhancement | R&D investments for energy efficiency improvements are inadequate. Additional R&D investments are necessary in this field to ensure innovations in renovation pro cesses, heating technologies, management and financing [3]. | |
Lack of technical or commercial skills and knowledge | There is a lack of trained professionals and other skills in energy renovation supply chain [16,17]. | |
Information barriers | Lack of awareness and information | No confidence in information about possible energy efficiency improvement options and lack of environmental awareness about energy efficiency benefits and climate change mitigation impacts. In addition, there is a lack of experts and resources in the market to deliver this information to consumers [4]. |
Uncertainties about cost-effectiveness | Uncertainties are mainly linked to the problem that; though cost-effective solutions can be achieved under specific conditions it does not mean that the same benefit will be achieved for all investments in energy efficiency improvements. This is because there is too much conflicting data on the costs and benefits of renovation of multi-flat buildings, often resulting in mistrust of the information [4,21]. | |
Organizational barriers | Ignoring of small energy efficiency improvement options | The households usually ignore small energy saving or energy efficiency improvement options and do not implement them though they can provide energy saving with low or no costs [34,56]. |
Organizational failures | Problems in making common decision and obtaining agreement of all apartment owners for large scale renovation of multi-apartment building due to conflicting interests [46,54,55,56]. | |
Behavioural barriers | Resistance to change | Adoption of energy efficiency measures is associate with customers perceptions of the quality and usefulness of these actions by comparing them to status quo situation. The use of energy efficiency options or energy renovation of residential buildings are often perceived to be associated with discomfort and problems. Households are not interested to make changes in their daily routine, they prefer status quo situation [45,48,49,50]. |
Time constrains, and the ability to use information | Various constrains associated with time, ability to use full information, necessary attention efforts often lead to irrational decisions by households. Additionally, then making decision on energy renovation or other energy efficiency improvement measures households use the advice and consultancy with friends which are not qualified enough instead of consulting experts. Therefore, they make economically irrational decisions in this area [33,34,46,47,48,49,50,51]. |
Policy Instruments | Key Barriers Addressed | Strengths and Weaknesses in Dealing with Barriers |
---|---|---|
Regulatory instruments | ||
Appliance standards | Regulatory and informational barriers | These measures have provided for insignificant success, as they collapse to address information barriers and organizational barriers in decision making for renovation of multi-apartment buildings. These measures can be effective if periodical updated, if independent control is being ensured. Mandatory schemes are more effective than voluntary ones. Mostly they are effective if combined with other measures. Provision of information, communication, education is crucial for success of appliance standards [4,6]. |
Building codes | Regulatory and information barriers | Though building codes had limited success in energy savings, the mandatory schemes are more effective than voluntary ones. These measures also do not tackle organizational barriers of decision making on energy renovation of multi apartment buildings. Therefore, insignificant success was achieved in dealing with energy efficiency or GHG reduction gap and they are efficient if enforced and periodically updated and monitoring and control and proper certification procedures are established. Provision of information, communication, education is crucial for success. Mostly they are effective if combined with other measures [8,37,38,39,40,41,52,65]. |
Mandatory audit requirement | Regulatory and information barriers | These measures alone are not effective. They do not allow to overcome high capital costs barriers. Mostly they are effective if combined with other measures [41,53]. |
Building monitoring system | Regulatory and information barriers | The influence of monitoring system on apartment owner’s decision to renovate apartments is restricted due to other energy efficiency barriers in households [53,60,66]. |
Demand-side management programs | Regulatory and information barriers | These instruments are more cost-effective for the commercial buildings and do not fit very well for residential buildings [66,67]. |
Detailed billing and disclosure programs | Regulatory and information barriers | Successful in combination with other measures. It is necessary to ensure periodic evaluation for success [69]. |
Economic and market-based instruments | ||
Energy savings performance contracting (ESCO) | Economic and financial barriers | These instruments have had slight impact on energy renovation decision making in residential buildings as they are more effective in public buildings. This measure also does not tackle the organizational barriers of energy renovation decision making in multi-flat buildings. Provision of information, communication, education is crucial for success [18,69]. |
Cooperative procurement | Economic and financial barriers | This measure implemented in several countries. Only effective in combination with standards and labeling etc. [53]. |
White certificates or Energy efficiency certificate schemes | Economic and financial barriers | This measure also does not tackle the organizational barriers of energy renovation decision making and require high monitoring and enforcement costs and institutional support, not clear interaction with other measures [41,51,53]. |
Fiscal instruments | ||
Taxation | Economic and financial barriers | Effectiveness is linked to price elasticity. Most effective when combined with other tools. In some countries: Germany, Sweden etc. high taxes have some influence on energy saving in households though in other countries taxes are low and external energy costs are not internalized. GHG taxes are high in several Scandinavian countries but in other countries they are too low to make influence on households’ decisions to invest in energy efficiency improvements [42,43,68]. |
Tax allowances | Economic and financial barriers | Tax allowances for energy efficiency measures like VAT reduction for insulation of buildings are effective just if they are properly structured to stimulate large scale energy renovation [42,43]. |
Public benefit charges | Economic and financial barriers | Successful if independent administration of funds is ensured, regular monitoring and feedback and simple and clear design is necessary [53]. |
Financial instruments | ||
Capital subsidies | Economic and financial barriers | The success of these programs was limited because of free-rider’s problems. There households receiving capital subsidies which is not necessary for them and they can renovate their houses without the subsidy [56,60]. |
Grants, soft loans | Economic and financial barriers | They can provide access to capital of low-income population however cannot address other important barriers of energy efficiency in households like organizational or behavioral [63,68]. |
Support, information and voluntary action | ||
Public leadership programs | Informational barriers | Mandatory leadership programs have higher potential than voluntary programs. Combined with financial incentives can provide for better results [53,69]. |
Education and information programs | Informational and technological barriers | Most effective then they are implemented with other measures [50,60,64]. |
Investments in Research and Development and Demonstration | Technological barriers | Investments in research and development is necessary to ensure the development of new energy saving technologies having long-term market scaling and risky investments [53]. |
Barriers and Market Failures | Typologies | Explanations |
---|---|---|
Economic and financial barriers | High initial capital costs | Renewable energy sources have lower operating costs comparing with fossil fuels however, higher initial capital costs make them less competitive than conventional energy sources as RES project necessitate higher financing for unit of installed capacity. Therefore, the capital markets often require a premium in lending rates for financing of RES projects. RES technologies encounter also import duties providing for the high first-cost attentions relative to fossil energy-based technologies [27,32,37,70]. |
Difficulties to assess fuel price risk | Future development of fossil fuel prices is considered to be reasonably stable. RES technologies do not encounter fuel costs therefore avoid fuel price risk. Nevertheless, the “risk-of fuel price premium,” is usually not included in economic comparisons as it is problematic to assess such risks. Regulated utilities have fuel costs included into regulated electricity tariffs; therefore, consumers should deal with the fuel price risks while utility decisions to invest is not include fuel price risk considerations [72,73,74,75]. | |
Unfavourable electricity pricing rules | RES feeding into the grid sometimes do not receive full payment for the value of their electricity supplied. RES power is generated near to final consumers and do not require transmission and distribution. However, utilities pay only wholesale rates for electricity, as if the capacities require transmission and distribution. Therefore, this benefit of RES also is not taken by the producer. Additionally, as RES energy is an “intermittent” and utilities cannot control such generation at any given time they lower prices for it by imposing a zero price for the “capacity value” and paying the lower price at peak times even if the renewable electricity is produced at peak demand and have to correspond to peak prices [29,37]. | |
High transaction costs | Higher transaction costs make RES technologies more expensive. RES projects are usually minor in comparison with traditional fossil energy projects and sometime require costly extra information or extra time to obtaining permits of finances due to unfamiliarity with RES technologies [28,30]. | |
External costs and benefits | The fossil fuels burning has negative environmental impacts on human health, agriculture, infrastructure decay biodiversity etc. The costs of climate change also matter. As environmental externalities are difficult to evaluate the investors do not include external costs in decision making. Renewable energy generation have external benefits like avoided external costs and creation of new jobs, especially for local communities which are also not taken into account during decision making [32,72]. | |
Institutional and Regulatory barriers | Problems with legal framework for independent power producers | Utilities control energy production and distribution and independent power producers encounter problems then investing in RES projects and selling electricity to the utility or to third parties. Utilities tend to negotiate power purchase agreements with independent energy producers on an ad-hoc basis, creating difficulties for RES project developers to finance projects and to plan investments and they pay back [69,70]. |
Constraints for and construction | RES installations often encounter many constraints based on environmental regulation for height, aesthetics, noise, or safety, especially in urban areas. Urban planning departments are not familiar with RES technologies and lack of established procedures for siting and permitting of such projects. Struggle for land usage with agriculture and tourism sectors often occur [70]. | |
Problems with transmission access | Utilities have to provide transmission access to RES power plants and sometimes charge high prices for transmission access. Transmission or distribution access is also necessary for direct third-party sales between the RES energy producer and a final customer. Sometimes there are problems with transmission access to remote renewable energy sites [28]. | |
Requirements for Utility interconnection | Individual houses or apartments can sometimes encounter unclear utility interconnection to the grid requirements. Unavailable uniform requirements can also increase transaction costs of small producers. The transaction costs will increase due to necessity to pay extra for legal and technical experts in order to satisfy requirements for interconnections [26,28]. | |
Liability requirements | Small power producers usually encounter additional requirements for liability. Although proper equipment standards are in line with safety requirements, the liability is still an issue for RES projects. Utilities usually demanding additional insurance as part of net metering requirements for renewable energy technologies [13,28,70]. | |
Market barriers | Problems with access to credit | RES project developers usually lack access to credit for investing in RES because of distorted capital markets. For example, “microcredits” for RES projects usually do not exist. Loan terms sometimes are very short relative comparing to the long project lifetime. RES project developers have also difficulties in obtaining bank financing because of uncertainty linked to long-term power purchase agreements with utilities [16,17,28]. |
Perceived risks linked to technology performance uncertainties | RES technologies are considered as risky duet to the lack of experience with them. The lack of acquaintance with RES technologies can create wrong perceptions about higher technical risk than for traditional energy carriers. These issues usually result in less capital availability. Utilities may be hesitant to use unfamiliar RES technologies [20,28,37]. | |
Lack of technical or commercial skills and knowledge | Markets need low-cost access to information and the necessary skills. However, there is lack of skilled personnel able to install, proper, operate, and maintain RES equipment. RES project developers also usually do not have sufficient technical, financial, and business development skills. Professionals in supply chain like engineers, architects, lenders, lack information about RES technologies, their costs and benefits, maintenance requirements, sources of finance, etc. These problems can block decisions in favour of RES projects [68,72]. | |
Technological barriers | Technological difficulties related to the intermittency and storage requirements | Due to the lack of well-established standards for renewable energy technologies linked to the intermittency and reliability of performance these technologies encounter additional barriers. The main technical challenge of RES technologies is storage requirements. The lack of equipment, components and spare parts for renewable energy technologies create additional barriers [28,32,72]. |
Lack of investment in R&D for renewable energy technologies | Investments in R&D for RES technologies are inadequate. The risks associated with renewable energy technologies are high and additional R&D investments are essential in this field [28,32,70,72]. | |
Limited availability of infrastructure for renewables | RES projects are often implemented in remote areas, requiring additional transmission lines to connect power plants to the grid, and investments to upgrade this grid are necessary as well [28,70]. | |
Information barriers | Lack of awareness and information | Scholars agree that the adoption of RES technologies are hampered due to the lack of information or knowledge or a lack of confidence in obtaining such information and lack of environmental awareness about benefits of renewables [33,34,71]. |
Not in my backyard (NIMBY) syndrome | NIMBY syndrome is linked with RERS projects then people do support renewable energy sources in general, but do not support them in their neighbourhood; so, renewable energy projects face hostility from individual citizens due to this syndrome as well making additional barriers to RES projects [68,73]. | |
Behavioural barriers | Resistance to change | Adoption of renewable energy technologies are linked with customers perceptions about usefulness of these technologies by comparing them with fossil fuel-based technologies. RES instead of providing energy supply at lower cost. Households do not want to shift from one technology to another as they prefer status quo [33,34,71,72,73]. |
Constraints on time, attention, and the ability to process information | Various constrains associated with time, attention, and ability to process full information often leads to households’ decisions that are not rational. Additionally, while purchasing a renewable energy technology, consumers consult their friends instead of experts and take economically irrational decisions [34,71,72,73]. |
Policies and Measures | Key Barriers Addressed | Strengths and Weaknesses in Dealing with Barriers |
---|---|---|
Regulatory instruments | ||
Standards and certification: building codes, zero building standards, low-carbon fuel standards etc. | Institutional and regulatory barriers | Important for supply chains and snowballing consumer confidence. Unlikely to result in much deployment without financial incentives [37,70]. |
Power grid access policies | Institutional and regulatory barriers | Well-established regulation for independent power producer regulation can provide for better transmission access, the priority of access to grid of renewable energy generators can allow to deal with regulatory barriers for penetration of RES [28,32]. |
Competitive wholesale and retail power markets | Institutional and regulatory barriers as well as economic and financial barriers | Introduction of market in electricity sector. These measures can reduce high costs barriers, transaction costs, and lack of fuel price risk assessment as well as unfavorable power pricing rules, therefore they are quite efficient in dealing with many barriers [28,72]. |
Restructuring of power sector and unbundling of electricity generation, transmission and distribution and privatization of utilities | Institutional and regulatory barriers as well as economic and financial barriers | These measures can guarantee more incentives to self-generate, including RES. This measure also has impact on mitigation of financial barriers like access to subsidies, but may increase barriers of high capital costs and rise perceived risks [28]. |
Net metering and net billing | Institutional and regulatory barriers | The measure can reduce transmission, distribution losses, but the tariffs based on net metring do not reveal the actual value of RES electricity at each location and time period [66]. |
Economic and market-based instruments | ||
Energy savings company performance obligations (ESCO) | Economic and financial barriers | These instruments have had little impact on decision to use renewable energy. Provision of information, communication, and education is crucial for success [29,32,37]. |
Administratively set pricing instruments: feed-in tariffs, feed-in premiums. | Economic and financial barriers | Allows to deal with unfavorable power pricing rules and ensure support during long-term period, however they can cause high snowballing costs effect and do not address properly problems linked to high upfront costs of RES generators [28,29,32]. |
Competitive price instruments: auctions | Economic and financial barriers | Flexible and has potential for real price setting for RES electricity. However, due to high risks of underbidding there are problems for small or new RES generator for entering energy market [29,32]. |
GHG emission trading schemes | Economic and financial barriers | Flexible market-based mechanisms might provide extra revenue to RES generators. However, the scheme has high enforcement and implementation costs [32]. |
Financial instruments | ||
Subsidies and grants | Economic and financial barriers | Subsidies provides for tackling barrier of higher capital costs of renewable energy. These schemes do not provide clear signals for investors in RES projects as support provided is fluctuating due to changes in governments [28,32]. |
Capacity credits for renewable energy generators | Economic and financial barriers - | Allows to overcome the barriers of high transaction costs, lack of access to credit however not always as efficient as supposed to be in overcoming other barriers like uncertainties of perceived risks [37]. |
Renewable energy mandates and portfolios | Technological barriers | This measure provides clear signals to companies as delivers clear information about anticipated RES deployment levels however is applied mostly in new-buildings, corresponding to the small share of energy consumption in residential buildings [32,37]. |
Fiscal instruments | ||
Tax allowances | Economic and financial barriers | Taxation policies to promote renewables, like VAT reduction for electricity from renewables and allows to deal with high initial capital costs problem [23,27,31,32]. |
GHG and energy taxes | Economic and financial barriers | GHG and energy taxes do not deliver clear signals for investors in RES projects as support provided is fluctuating due to changes in governments as taxes are difficult to implement due to political reasons, they are usually too low to internalize externalities and overcome this market failure. In addition, exclusions and rebates are very often making taxes less ineffective measure [30,31,32]. |
Support, information, and voluntary actions | ||
Informational measures: awareness campaigns and labelling. | Information barriers | These measures provide for increase of awareness about RES benefits and are more effective then implemented in the form of tailored energy advice. However, this form of information dissemination is costly [34,68]. |
Public green procurement | Economic and financial barriers | Allows to increase share of RES in final energy consumption however, additional measures are necessary to stimulate RES technologies uptake in the market [68]. |
Voluntary programmes | Market barriers, information barriers | Voluntary measures are less effective then obligatory however, they allow to save cost for government as well as consumers. They should be implemented together with awareness rising and information dissemination programmes [32,68,73,74,75]. |
Investments in R&D and demonstration. | Market barriers, information barriers | Investments in R&D for new technologies allow to improve them and reduce the costs making them more competitive in the market. The pilot commercial demonstration projects are very useful for long-term market scaling perspectives of new RES technologies and reduction of financial risks anticipated in the case of RES project failures [32,73]. |
Climate Change Mitigation Barriers | Market Failure | Behavioral and Psychological Barriers |
---|---|---|
Limited cognition and decision-making heuristics | X | |
Uncertainty and irreversibility | X | X |
Ideologies | X | |
Social comparison and social norms | X | |
Information failures | X | |
Sunk costs | X | |
Discredence | X | |
Perceived risks | X | |
Limited behavior | X |
Climate Change Mitigation Policies and Measures | Kay Market Barriers Addressed | Behavioral and Psychological Barriers |
---|---|---|
Regulatory instruments | Regulatory, institutional, informational and economic barriers | Limited cognition and decision-making heuristics; limited behavior; social comparison and social norms |
Economic and market-based instruments | Economic and financial barriers | Decision-making heuristics; sunk costs, discordance, and perceived risks |
Financial instruments | Economic and financial barriers, technological barriers | Decision-making heuristics; sunk costs, discordance, and perceived risks |
Fiscal instruments | Economic and financial barriers | Decision-making heuristics; sunk costs, discordance, and perceived risks |
Support, information and voluntary actions | Informational, organizational market; economic and financial barriers | Limited cognition and decision-making heuristics, limited behavior; ideologies, social comparison, and social norms discordance and perceived risk. |
© 2020 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Streimikiene, D.; Balezentis, T.; Alebaite, I. Climate Change Mitigation in Households between Market Failures and Psychological Barriers. Energies 2020, 13, 2797. https://doi.org/10.3390/en13112797
Streimikiene D, Balezentis T, Alebaite I. Climate Change Mitigation in Households between Market Failures and Psychological Barriers. Energies. 2020; 13(11):2797. https://doi.org/10.3390/en13112797
Chicago/Turabian StyleStreimikiene, Dalia, Tomas Balezentis, and Irena Alebaite. 2020. "Climate Change Mitigation in Households between Market Failures and Psychological Barriers" Energies 13, no. 11: 2797. https://doi.org/10.3390/en13112797
APA StyleStreimikiene, D., Balezentis, T., & Alebaite, I. (2020). Climate Change Mitigation in Households between Market Failures and Psychological Barriers. Energies, 13(11), 2797. https://doi.org/10.3390/en13112797