Next Article in Journal
Assessment of Indoor Air Quality in Residential Buildings of New England through Actual Data
Next Article in Special Issue
Assessing Firm Readiness to Adopt Cluster-Based Innovative Projects: A Segmentation Analysis
Previous Article in Journal
Planned Application of Sewage Sludge Recirculates Nutrients to Agricultural Soil and Improves Growth of Okra (Abelmoschus esculentus (L.) Moench) Plants
Previous Article in Special Issue
Examining Farmers’ Adoption Decisions towards Precision-Agricultural Practices in Greek Dairy Cattle Farms
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Redistribution and the Abolishment of Historical Entitlements in the CAP Strategic Plans: The Case of Greece

by
Dimitrios Kremmydas
* and
Konstantinos Tsiboukas
Department of Agricultural Economics and Rural Development, Agricultural University of Athens, Iera Odos 75, 11855 Athens, Greece
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2022, 14(2), 735; https://doi.org/10.3390/su14020735
Submission received: 30 November 2021 / Revised: 4 January 2022 / Accepted: 5 January 2022 / Published: 10 January 2022

Abstract

:
A key issue in CAP strategic planning in Greece is the treatment of historical entitlements. An unequal level of payments per hectare is difficult to justify in terms of the CAP’s rationale, and so the abolishment of these entitlements seems to be the most reasonable option. However, for historical reasons, this abolishment may result in a transfer of payments from smaller to larger farms and between different agricultural sub-sectors which could in turn lead to negative effects on the incomes of small farms and lead to farmers leaving the sector. We simulate the change to a flat rate payment in order to quantify these effects, then explore the possibility of employing the new obligatory redistribution measure, termed complementary income support, to mitigate any negative effects. We conclude that redistribution is, indeed, a powerful tool for fine-tuning decoupled payments if historical entitlements are to be abolished.

1. Introduction

The new 2023–2027 CAP [1] will be based on a new policy delivery model that will shift ‘from compliance to performance’. According to this model, the member states (MS) will have increased subsidiarity for planning and implementing CAP. Each MS will establish a single CAP ‘strategic plan’ (SP) covering interventions for both Pillar I (direct payments) and Pillar II (rural development). The preparation of the plan shall be based on quantitative and qualitative up-to-date information that provides a thorough analysis of the current situation in the country, it shall actively involve all related economic and social partners and it shall be connected to a set of common economic and biophysical indicators defined in the regulation.
One key issue for CAP strategic planning in the Greek case is related to the treatment of historical entitlements. These are entitlements to CAP payments with a unit value (i.e., value per hectare) related to the payments that a farmer received in the past. It first appeared in the 2003 Fischler CAP reform and is still applied in several MSs, albeit indirectly, as we explain in a subsequent section.
Historical entitlements lead to an unequal level of payments per hectare that reflects the pre-decoupling CAP regime. Two neighboring plots that belong to different farms may receive different payments per hectare, e.g., if the farms were used for different purposes, growing cotton and trees, for instance. In such cases, it is difficult to justify their maintenance under the CAP’s rationale of decoupled payments.
Indeed, the academic literature has explored their abolishment, especially in the periods preceding the discussions on CAP reforms. Matthews et al. [2] used a GIS model to explore the effects on Scottish agriculture of abolishing historical entitlements and replacing them with a single area payment. Rochi [3] used a social accounting matrix to examine the distributional effects of replacing historical entitlements in Italian agriculture with a regional flat rate. Ciaian et al. [4] discussed the impact of different entitlement settings on the capitalization of the CAP payments. Marchand et al. [5] simulated the impact of a flat rate system for Flanders using a positive mathematical programming model. Severini and Valle [6] used a theoretical model to explore the relation between the availability of entitlements and land shadow prices. Erjavec et al. [7] and Gocht et al. [8] went even further by exploring the impact of an EU-wide flat area payment for CAP, i.e., the payment per hectare to be equal for any hectare in the EU.
From the political and policy side, there was also pressure for leaving historical entitlements behind. The process of decoupling the payments from any actual production choice was incompatible with the entitlements as the latter represented the coupled payments regime. In addition, CAP’s justification was moving slowly from food security and productivity towards the reward of public goods and the offering of ecosystem services. These were also incompatible with the entitlements. Their introduction was a compromise between the new CAP philosophy and the political need to introduce radical reforms gradually. Thus, very soon after their introduction in 2003, the 2008 CAP ‘Health Check’ [9] called for a ‘move away from paying farmers on the basis of historical production towards a more even distribution per region’. The 2013 CAP reform [10] introduced the ‘convergence’ process that would reduce variation between payments per hectare. In the current reform, the EU Parliament Committee on Agriculture and Rural Development in 2018 [11] calls for modernizing the value of entitlements based on “historic references”. Finally, the new CAP regulation [1] sets a minimum convergence threshold of 85%. This means that by 2027 no farm should have a payment per hectare of less than the 85% of the average value. This threshold is much closer to a uniform payment per hectare than the 60% threshold of the previous CAP.
Therefore, for Greek CAP strategic planning, the abolishment of historical entitlements seems to be a reasonable option. Still, this comes with some implications regarding the income of small farms. We gain some qualitative insights when we examine the distributions of payments per hectare and payments per farm.
The distribution of payments per hectare and per beneficiary for the different EU countries is shown in Table 1. Greece had the highest variability (expressed with the interquartile range) in the EU, with many farms that received payments of more than 1000 euros/hectare and many other farms that received less than 100 euros/hectare. At the same time, Greece is among the member states with the lowest dispersion in the level of payments per farm.
Thus, although some farms receive very low payments per hectare and some others receive very high payments per hectare, their payments at the farm level are equal. This happens because the entitlements with high unit values belong to small farms, while the large farms possess low-value entitlements.
The abolishment of historical entitlements will lead to leveling the payment per hectare for all farms. This will reduce the total payments to small farms, since they have less land, and will result in transferring resources to larger farms. Moreover, if the distribution of high- and low-value entitlements is correlated with agricultural sub-sectors, it will be possible to have budgetary transfer across these sub-sectors. In order to take a well-informed decision, the above effects need to be quantified.
The objective of this paper is to provide insights related to the abolishment of historical entitlements. What will be the effect of the abolishment of the historical model on incomes across the various types of farming and farm economic sizes? How can policy makers use the intervention of redistributive payment to reverse any negative income effects? In order to answer these questions, we use static simulations that project income effects on the different economic sizes and types of farming. The innovative aspect of this research is twofold: first, there is the modeling of the redistribution scheme; and, second, there is the exploration of the effects of the abolishment of historical entitlements that is relevant for the strategic plans of ten MSs, as shown in the following section.
We first present a timeline of the historical entitlements across the various CAP reforms. Then, we present the simulated scenarios, the simulation steps and the data used. Finally, we present the results and close the paper with a discussion of our findings and our conclusions.

2. The Historical, Regional and Convergence Models of CAP

As we briefly show in Table 2, CAP has evolved along two main axes. The first relates to the objectives of CAP, which initially focused on increasing productivity and gradually moved to environmental concerns. The second axis relates to the mechanisms employed, shifting from market to producer support and then to decoupled support.
The introduction of the historical entitlements came with the 2003 Fischler reform. The entitlements served the purpose of a smooth transition from the ‘producer support’ of the 1992 CAP (activity-specific payments related to the level of activity) to the decoupled payment regime of the 2003 CAP (payments decoupled from specific activities, not related to the level of activity). For this, the member states had the discretion to choose between two different implementations of the decoupled Single Farm Payment: a historical model that was based on historical entitlements and a regional model that was completely breaking the ties with the ‘producer support’ of the 1992 CAP [15].
Under the historical model, transfers to farmers via the Single Payment Scheme (SPS) equaled the financial support they received in the ‘reference period’ (2000–2002), thus maintaining intact the past distribution of coupled payments across farmers. More specifically, according to this model, every farm received a Single Payment equal to the average payment for arable crops, beef and veal, milk, sheep and goat meat, olive trees, raisins, etc., that it had received in the 2000–2002 reference period. For example, a farm that specialized in cotton for 2000, 2001 and 2002 would receive a higher per hectare payment in CAP 2005–2013 compared to a farm growing apples, since cotton had high payments per hectare while apples had almost zero.
By contrast, under the regional model, all farms in a specific region received the same flat rate payment per hectare; the MSs could freely define the regions based on objective criteria or set a single flat rate payment for all farms at the country level. There was also a so-called hybrid model, where MSs could provide part of the single payment based on historical payments with the rest based on the flat rate per hectare payment. According to whether a part of historical payments was fixed or varied over time, there was a further distinction between static hybrid and dynamic hybrid models.
With the advent of the 2013 CAP, the Single Payment was split into different components. The most important were the Basic Payment and a ‘Greening Payment’ (its full name was ‘Payment for agricultural practices beneficial for the climate and the environment’). The MSs that applied the historical model had to move towards a flatter payment per hectare for the Basic Payment. This adjustment was termed internal convergence and the rate of the adjustment was left within a certain range at the MSs’ discretion. The available convergence options were: (a) a uniform unit value of payments effective either in 2015 or in 2020 (full convergence) or (b) a partial convergence of unit value of payments, so that by 2020 no farm has a very low value of payment per hectare. The redistributive scheme was also introduced, which allowed MSs to provide an extra payment per hectare to smaller farms. For the new MS, a simplified flat rate payment called SAPS (Single Area Payment Scheme) was also available.
In the 2023–2027 CAP, the Basic Payment Scheme will be renamed to Basic Income Support for Sustainability. The Redistributive Payment will become the Complementary income support and will be mandatory for member states to apply. Convergence for Basic Income Support is still an option, albeit more strict, so that no farm at the end of 2027 will have an entitlement value less than 85% of the average entitlement value.
We provide a summary of the above timeline in Table 3.
In the 2003 Fischler reform, Greece selected the historical model, assigning entitlements to farms and connecting the value of each entitlement to the average payment that the farm received in 2000–2002 (implemented in 2008). Then, in the 2013 reform, it followed the partial convergence model. Three agronomic regions were defined: arable land, grassland/pasture and permanent crops. The flat-rate target value was different for each of those regions: 420 euro/ha for arable land, 500 euro/ha for permanent crops and 250 euro/ha for grassland. The implementation details of the Greek regional model were such that a farm could possibly hold some entitlement rights from the arable land region, others from the grassland region and others from the permanent crop regions. Thus, the actual payment that a farm received was an average of the regional payments weighted by the number of entitlements it held in each region. At 2019, due to the convergence, no unit value should be lower than 60% of the regional target flat-rate and the unit values that exceeded 100% of the regional average should have been reduced.

3. Scenarios, Data and the Simulation

The scenarios we simulate have two dimensions. The first one related to the abolishment or preservation of the historical entitlements and the second to the redistribution scheme.
Along the first dimension, we examine three configurations. The first scenario, named C85, is an accelerated convergence model, where, by the end of the programming period, no payment will be lower than 85% of the regional average. This corresponds to maintaining the historical entitlements. The second scenario, named R_F, is a regional flat-rate payment, i.e., within each region all farms receive the same payment per hectare. The third scenario, named C_F, is a country-level flat-rate payment, i.e., all farms in the country receive the same payment per hectare. The last two scenarios correspond to the abolishment of historical entitlements.
We combine these three scenarios with the redistribution measure, which is a mandatory intervention in the forthcoming CAP. For this, we keep the redistribution budget constant at 10% of the direct payments budget and we vary the redistribution payments per hectare. Since the budget remains constant, higher payments per hectare will result in fewer farms getting higher payments per hectare for redistribution and lower payments per hectare will have the opposite effect. We consider two relatively extreme cases. One is relatively tight in terms of how many farms benefit from redistribution and is therefore named R_few. In this scenario, we set the redistributive payment per hectare to be 55% of the maximum allowed payment per hectare, resulting in only around 30% of the farms getting redistribution payments. A second redistribution scenario, named R_many, provides a lower redistribution payment per hectare (25% of the maximum allowed payment), so that around 50% of the farms benefit from redistribution.
A summary of the scenarios is presented in Table 4.
The simulation data is an anonymized random sample of 20,000 farms from the Greek payment authority (OPEKEPE) and corresponds to payments for 2019. For those farms, we have the total value of payments and the number of their entitlements for each agronomic region. In 2019, convergence had already terminated, so this data is valid until the new CAP becomes applicable on 1 January 2023. We also have for each farm the areas for each type of agricultural activity (e.g., durum wheat, barley, apple trees, etc.). Based on this information, we simulated the Type-of-Farming methodology used in the EU’s Farm Accountancy Data Network (FADN), and we assigned each farm to an FADN economic size and Type-of-Farming group.
The simulation steps are as follows. First, we assume that the basic payment (BPS) budget (including greening) of the current CAP 2014–2020 is represented by the payments of the sample farms (Equation (1)). We then deduce the represented national direct payments of CAP 2014–2020 from the BPS of CAP 2014–2020 using a multiplication factor (Equation (2)). In the 2014–2020 CAP’s national envelope for Greece, the basic payment was 871,068,024 euros per year, the direct payment budget was 1,818,660,043 euros per year and the multiplication factor was equal to their ratio, i.e., to 2.171656. Finally, we assume that the redistribution budget of the new 2023–2027 CAP will be 10% of the direct payments. The latter remains constant for both the current and the new CAP (Equation (3)). The new basic payment for 2023–2027 will be that of 2014–2020 with redistribution subtracted (Equation (4)).
B P S 2014 t o t a l = f , r P A Y f , r
D P = 2.171656 · B P S t o t a l
R E D t o t a l = 0.10 · D P
B P S 2023 t o t a l = B P S 2014 t o t a l R E D t o t a l
where B P S 2014 t o t a l is the CAP 2014–2020 national basic payment budget of our sample (greening is included), P A Y f , r is the payment for farm f in agronomic region r (as found in the data), D P is the estimated sample’s direct payment (Pillar I) budget, R E D t o t a l is the estimated sample’s redistribution budget and B P S 2023 t o t a l is the CAP 2023–2027 national budget for the basic income support for the sustainability of our sample.
Then, for each farm and scenario, we estimate the new basic payment. For the two flat-rate scenarios, this is relatively straightforward. In the countrywide flat-rate scenario, each farm will receive the payment per hectare (it is the same across all farms) multiplied by the number of rights it holds (Equation (5)). In this scenario, the payment per hectare equals the 2023–2027 budget divided by the number of rights of all farms (Equation (6)).
For the regional flat-rate scenario, the payment for each farm is the sum of the payments for each agronomic region that it has rights to (Equation (7)). In this case, the payment per hectare is different for each agronomic region and depends on the share of the budget that was allocated in the 2014–2020 CAP to each region (Equation (8)).
B P S f C _ F = r R f , r · T C _ F               f
T C _ F = B P S 2023 t o t a l / f , r R f , r
B P S f C _ R = r R f , r · T r C _ R               f
T r C _ R = B P S 2023 t o t a l · S r / f R f , r               r
where B P S f C _ F is the CAP 2023–2027 basic payment of farm f for the countrywide flat-rate scenario (euros), T C _ F is the payment per hectare for the countrywide flat-rate scenario (euros/ha), R f , r is the number of rights of farm f in agronomic region r (ha), B P S f C _ R is the CAP 2023–2027 basic payment for farm f in the regional flat-rate scenario (euros), R f , r is the estimated sample’s direct payment (Pillar I) budget, T r C _ R is the payment per hectare for region r in the regional flat-rate scenario (euros/ha) and S r is the share of the CAP 2014–2020 budget that was allocated to region r.
In the case of the convergence scenario, the estimations are a bit more complex. The new basic payment is the product of the rights the farm has in each agronomic region multiplied by a farm-specific payment per hectare (Equation (9)). This farm-specific payment depends on the relative position that the farm has in the regional payment-per-hectare distribution (Equation (10)). If the farm’s payment per hectare is between 85% and 100% of the regional average, then its payment per hectare does not change. If it is below 85%, then its new payment per hectare is set to 85% of the regional average, as at the end of the convergence period (2027) no farm shall be below this position. If the farm is above the average, the payment per hectare is reduced by a farm-specific ratio, so that the new CAP 2023–2027 basic payment budget equals the 2014–2020 budget. The calculation of this ratio is too complex to be presented here but the reader can find it in the simulation code in the Supplementary Material.
B P S f C 85 = r R f , r · T f , r , 2020 C 85               f
T 2020 C 85 = T f , r , 2014 C 85   i f   f ϵ F 85 , 100 0.85 · T r C _ R   i f   f ϵ F 0 , 85 D f , r · T f , r , 2014 C 85   i f   f ϵ F 100 ,
where B P S f C 85 is the CAP 2023–2027 basic payment of farm-f for the convergence scenario (euros), T f , r , 2020 C 85 is the CAP 2023–2027 payment per hectare for the convergence scenario, for farm f and region r (euros/ha), T f , r , 2014 C 85 is the CAP 2014–2020 payment per hectare from the data for farm f and region r (euros/ha), D f , r is a farm-specific reduction of the CAP 2014–2020 payment per hectare (%) and F 0 , 85 ,   F 85 , 100 ,   F 100 , are the classes of farms according to the relation of their payment per hectare under CAP 2014–2020 to the regional average.
The above calculations are related to the basic payment of the new CAP 2023–2027. We also need to calculate the redistributive payment. As described at the beginning of the section, we have defined the two redistributive scenarios in relation to the maximum value that the redistribution unit value can theoretically take, i.e., according to the regulation, this equals the direct payment budget distributed to all entitlement rights (Equation (11)). We then estimate the redistribution payment of each farm. In Equation (12) we give the mathematical notation of its calculation. Its details are rather complex to explain here but they are well explained in the simulation script in the Supplementary Material. Each scenario starts with the definition of a percentage of the maximum theoretical payment per hectare of redistribution ( P s ). This leads to an estimate of an area threshold for each region that determines which farms will benefit from redistribution so that we do not exceed the redistribution budget ( E s f a r m s ). This also requires defining the number of hectares for which redistribution will be paid ( R m ). If a small farm has 10 ha but redistribution will be paid only for the first 5 ha, then the payment for this farm will be only for its first 5 ha.
R U V m a x = D P / f , r R f , r
R E D f = 0     i f   n o t   f ϵ E s f a r m s P s · R U V m a x · min R m , r R f , r     i f   n o t   f ϵ E s f a r m s               f
where R U V m a x is the theoretical maximum payment per hectare of redistribution, E s f a r m s is the set of farms that are eligible for getting redistribution in scenario s, P s is the percentage of the maximum theoretical payment per hectare of redistribution for scenario s (%) and R m is the number of hectares for which redistribution will be paid (ha).
After estimating the basic payment for the three historical entitlement abolishment scenarios and the redistribution payments for the two redistribution payment scenarios, we estimate for each farm the overall payment difference between CAP 2014–2020 and CAP 2023–2027.
We provide the simulation script in the Supplementary Material. It contains detailed comments so that one can follow the algorithm. It is coded in R and we provide instructions on how to run it and how to obtain the results that we present in the paper. Unfortunately, due to confidentiality issues, we cannot share the original dataset but instead we share a permutated version of it. The original records have been partitioned into several groups, and the values of each of the columns are shuffled within each group (for more information, see Majeed et al. [17]). Thus, the reader will get slightly different results when running the script with the permutated data, but it is a compromise between the needs for research reproducibility and data confidentiality.

4. Results

First, we explore the direct effects of abolishing the historical entitlements. We compute them by comparing each of the two flat-rate scenarios (C_F and C_R) with the convergence scenario (C85).
In general, as expected, the abolishment leads to a payment decrease for farms of small economic size and a corresponding increase for those of high economic size (Table 5). For farms with an economic size of less than 8000 euros, a reduction of approximately 10% takes place in the C_F (flat rate at the country level) scenario and one of 5% in the R_F scenario (flat rate at the regional level). This means that payments are transferred from small to large farms. However, the regional flat rate (scenario R_F) leads to a lower transfer of payments.
We present the distribution of the above effects across farms in Figure 1. The distributional information is more useful. While the presentation of the results in economic size categories sums negative and positive effects, the distributional view allows one to see the number of farms and the intensity of the effects for farms that lose and gain. Indeed, for small farms (economic sizes of less than 8000 euros), the countrywide flat rate results in losses to almost all farms, while the regional flat rate has significantly milder effects, with the median of the loss/gain distribution being above 0 (i.e., the majority of the farms do not sustain losses).
Regarding the effects of abolishment on the different types of farming, as shown in Table 6, certain sectors, like tobacco, other grapes and other permanent crops, will face a significant decrease of payments. The livestock sector will in general receive increased payments. Again, the regional flat rate leads to milder budgetary transfers
We present the distribution of the effects of the abolishment of historical entitlements for different types of farming in Figure 2. Here it is more apparent that the regional flat rate has significantly more moderate results compared to the countrywide flat rate. Especially for sectors like olives, wine and other permanent crops, while with the countrywide flat rate there are losses for the majority of farms, with the regional flat rate the losses are quite limited.
In Table 7, we present the results of the combination of abolishing or not abolishing historical entitlements with the two redistribution payment scenarios for different economic sizes. In general, redistribution, as expected, results in the transfer of funds from large to small farms. When more farms are included in the redistribution (R_many), the budget transfer is not as intense as in the case where fewer farms receive it (R_few). In the partial convergence scenario (C85), the redistribution effect is quite strong and results in large farms losing more than 10% of the budget. If historical entitlements are abolished (C_F and R_F) and are combined with a redistribution scenario, we get more smooth budgetary changes. Specifically, when the redistributive budget is focused more on the smaller farms (R_few), those farms either have minimal losses or even gains, in contrast to the current CAP.
In Figure 3, we present the distribution of the effects of the above combinations. The columns contain the convergence or the abolishment scenarios, the rows the different redistribution scenarios. Each policy option is a combination of the two. For example, in the first cell of the figure, we show the policy option of continuing convergence (C85) and of providing redistribution to a few small farms (Red_few). The red line in the figure is a visual indication of the 0% losses or gains of a scenario. In general, the Red_few scenario results in some small farms having gains but it does not improve the position of the majority of small farms. This effect can be seen in the ‘2000–8000’ EUR economic size, where the median of Red_many is higher than that of Red_few in all scenarios.
In Table 8, we present the same results but in relation to the different type of farming. In general, the regional flat rate gives smoother budget transfers between farm types and redistribution has mixed effects; sometimes it makes budgetary transfers lower and other times it makes them higher. However, there are sectors that will be negatively impacted in the majority of the scenarios, e.g., tobacco, grapes and citrus. The livestock sector will have budgetary gains in any of the scenarios.

5. Discussion and Conclusions

The abolishment of historical entitlements will lead to a loss of income for small farms. In order to evaluate the impact of this loss we have compiled the average farm income from the FADN public database and the lower quantile (Q25) of the payment changes from our simulations (Table 9).
For small farms (economic size of 2000–8000 euros), the losses are around 3–5% of the net farm income. For example, the highest losses are in the “Countrywide Flat Rate + Redistribution few” scenario. Twenty-five percent of the small farms will have a loss of more than 250 euros where the average net farm income is 4891 euros. For farms of 8000 to 25,000 euros, in the same scenario, 25% of the farms would have a loss of more than 684 euros, where the average net income is 10,819. The reader should have in mind that for Greek farms, CAP payments are often used as working capital, either directly or as bank collateral, for covering the variable costs of the production year (seeds, fertilizers, etc.). Whether these losses are significant and will lead to farms shutting down requires more data. First, the FADN income estimates are mean values and it is possible that there are farms with even lower incomes. It also depends on whether a small farm belongs to a full-time or a part-time farmer; in the latter case, the off-farm income may compensate for the small reductions in CAP payments. In any case, the abolishment of historical entitlements will lead to small farms either reducing the variable costs and/or shutting down, without being able to quantify the latter.
The exit of small farms may have wider impacts in the socio-economic fabric. Davidova et al. [18] argue that very small farms correspond to poor rural households and thus their agricultural income is a kind of ‘social buffer’. In addition, small farms mainly practice mixed farming, which provides biodiversity ecosystem services. From the food system perspective, Rivera et al. [19] found that in the EU there are cases where small farms make important contributions both to production and to local food availability. In Greece, almost 35% of the farms belong to farms with an economic size of less than 8000 euros; thus, the argument of Rivera needs to be taken into account.
The above discussion highlights the compromise that policy makers need to consider regarding the abolishment of the historical entitlements in the new CAP strategic plan. On one hand, the EU-related political target of a uniform payment per hectare and, on the other hand, the CAP objectives of ‘ensuring viable income’ and ‘jobs and growth in rural areas’.
Our results show that the policy makers can utilize the redistribution tool to achieve the desired compromise. However, its configuration can be quite complex. For example, different payments per hectare for different areas of land (e.g., one level of payment per hectare for the first two hectares and another one for the next two hectares, etc.). For this, a more detailed quantitative model is required for planning the redistribution measure; for instance, a goal-programming model that will determine the optimum configuration of land breaks and payments based on policy objectives (e.g., the decrease up to a limit for certain farm groups, the payment of a certain percentage of the redistribution budget to the smallest farms, etc.). The model will be constrained by the available budget.
Beyond the redistribution approach, the inclusion of both Pillar I and Pillar II in the new CAP strategic approach allows for greater flexibility. Policy makers could use rural development funds to compensate for any negative income effects on small farms. In addition, they could direct some of the coupled payment support to target sectors that will face income loss with the abolishment of historical entitlements. To conclude, we have shown that although the abolishment of historical entitlements is a desired and reasonable option in the Greek case, it may have negative implications for small farms and certain farming sectors. More data is required in order to gain insights into the impact of this income loss. Nevertheless, the redistribution scheme, now known as complementary income support, can be configured properly so that any problems can be alleviated. This configuration requires a more accurate quantitative model that will cater for the complexity of the redistribution intervention.

Supplementary Materials

The following supporting information can be downloaded at: https://www.mdpi.com/article/10.3390/su14020735/s1.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization: D.K. and K.T.; methodology: D.K.; software: D.K.; writing: D.K. and K.T. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

The data presented in this study is available in the Supplementary Material.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. European Commission. Regulation (EU) 2021/2115 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 2 December 2021 Establishing Rules on Support for Strategic Plans to be Drawn Up by Member States under the Common Agricultural Policy (CAP Strategic Plans) and Financed by the European Agricultural Guarantee Fund (EAGF) and by the European Agricultural Fund for Rural Development (EAFRD). 2021. Available online: https://eur-lex.europa.eu/eli/reg/2021/2115 (accessed on 20 December 2021).
  2. Matthews, K.B.; Buchan, K.; Miller, D.G.; Towers, W. Land Use Policy Reforming the CAP—With area-based payments, who wins and who loses? Land Use Policy 2013, 31, 209–222. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Rocchi, B. The CAP reform between targeting and equity: A structural policy analysis for Italy. Eur. Rev. Agric. Econ. 2009, 36, 175–201. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Ciaian, P.; Kancs, D.; Swinnen, J.F.M. The impact of the 2013 reform of the common agricultural policy on land capitalization in the European Union. Applied Economic Perspectives and Policy. Appl. Econ. Perspect. Policy 2013, 36, 643–673. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  5. Marchand, F.L.; Buysse, J.; Campens, V.; Claeys, D.; Fernagut, B.; Straeten Vander, B.; Van Huylenbroeck, G. Effects of a flat rate introduction: Shifts in farm activity and impact on farmers’ income. In Proceedings of the 107th EAAE Seminar “Modelling of Agricultural and Rural Development Policies”, Sevilla, Spain, 30 January–1 February 2008. [Google Scholar]
  6. Severini, S.; Valle, S. The Single Payment Scheme of the CAP: Entitlements Availability and Farmers Behavior. In Proceedings of the 11th Congress of the EAAE, The Future of Rural Europe in the Global Agri-Food System, Copenhagen, Denmark, 23–27 August 2005. [Google Scholar]
  7. Erjavec, E.; Chantreuil, F.; Hanrahan, K.; Donnellan, T.; Salputra, G.; Kožar, M.; van Leeuwen, M. Policy assessment of an EU wide flat area CAP payments system. Econ. Model. 2011, 28, 1550–1558. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Gocht, A.; Britz, W.; Ciaian, P.; Gomez, S. Farm Type Effects of an EU-wide Direct Payment Harmonisation. J. Agric. Econ. 2013, 64, 1–32. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Haniotis, T. The “Health Check’’ of the CAP Reform: Lessons from Its Impact Assessment. In The Economic Impact of Public Support to Agriculture: An International Perspective; Ball, V.E., Fanfani, R., Gutierrez, L., Eds.; Springer: New York, NY, USA, 2010; pp. 67–79. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. European Commission. Regulation (EU) No 1306/2013 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 17 December 2013 on the Financing, Management and Monitoring of the Common Agricultural Policy. 2013. Available online: https://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/en/ALL/?uri=CELEX:32013R1306 (accessed on 20 December 2021).
  11. EU. Parliament Committee on Agriculture and Rural Development, 2018, Report “on the Future of Food and Farming”, 2018/2037(INI), Rapporteur: Herbert Dorfmann. Available online: https://www.europarl.europa.eu/doceo/document/A-8-2018-0178_EN.html (accessed on 20 December 2021).
  12. European Commission; Directorate, L. Direct Payments Distribution in the EU-25 after Implementation of the 2003 CAP Reform Based on FADN Data. 2008. Available online: https://ec.europa.eu/agriculture/rica/pdf/hc0304_distribution_eu25.pdf (accessed on 15 June 2020).
  13. Tangermann, S.; von Cramon-Taubadel, S. Agricultural Policy in the European Union: An Overview (Issue 1302). Georg-August-Universität Göttingen, Department für Agrarökonomie und Rurale Entwicklung (DARE). 2013. Available online: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/70909 (accessed on 20 December 2021).
  14. European Commission. Directorate-General for Agriculture and Rural Development, The Common Agricultural Policy: A Story to be Continued, Publications Office. 2012. Available online: https://data.europa.eu/doi/10.2762/35894 (accessed on 20 December 2021).
  15. Henke, R.; D’Andrea, M.R.; Benos, T.; Castellotti, T.; Pierangeli, F.; Lironcurti, S.R.; De Filippis, F.; Giua, M.; Rosatelli, L.; Resl, T.; et al. Implementation of the First Pillar of the CAP 2014–2020 in the EU Member States; European Parliament: Brussels, Belgium, 2015. [Google Scholar]
  16. Terluin, I.; Kuhmonen, T.; Berkhout, P. Research for AGRI Committee–CAP implementation: Flexibility Given to Member States–State of Play and Perspectives; European Parliament, Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies: Brussels, Belgium, 2017. [Google Scholar]
  17. Majeed, A.; Lee, S. Anonymization Techniques for Privacy Preserving Data Publishing: A Comprehensive Survey. IEEE Access 2020, 9, 8512–8545. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Davidova, S.; Bailey, A.; Dwyer, J.; Erjavec, E.; Gorton, M.; Thomson, K. Semi-Subsistence Farming–Value and Directions of Development. European Parliament, Directorate for Internal Affairs. 2013. Available online: https://www.europarl.europa.eu/RegData/etudes/etudes/join/2013/495861/IPOL-AGRI_ET(2013)495861_EN.pdf (accessed on 29 June 2020).
  19. Rivera, M.; Guarín, A.; Pinto-correia, T.; Almaas, H.; Arnalte, L.; Burns, V.; Czekaj, M.; Ellis, R.; Galli, F.; Karanikolas, P.; et al. Assessing the role of small farms in regional food systems in Europe: Evidence from a comparative study. Glob. Food Secur. 2020, 26, 100417. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Distribution of abolishment effects per economic size.
Figure 1. Distribution of abolishment effects per economic size.
Sustainability 14 00735 g001
Figure 2. Distribution of abolishment effects per type of farming.
Figure 2. Distribution of abolishment effects per type of farming.
Sustainability 14 00735 g002
Figure 3. Distribution of combined effects of abolishment and redistribution scenarios.
Figure 3. Distribution of combined effects of abolishment and redistribution scenarios.
Sustainability 14 00735 g003
Table 1. Distribution of payments per hectare and payments per beneficiary (farm) across the EU for 2006 (Source: [12]).
Table 1. Distribution of payments per hectare and payments per beneficiary (farm) across the EU for 2006 (Source: [12]).
Payment per Hectare (euro/ha)Payment per Beneficiary (euro/farm)
Member StateMedianIQR 1MedianIQR 1
Austria290150687590
Belgium36024013,18017,520
Cyprus1100340530
Czech Republic900425010,530
Denmark31012016,32027,610
Estonia401018003050
Finland2409096309530
France30021017,580254
Germany31013014,69018,320
Greece61094034106050
Hungary90012202200
Ireland280190858010,630
Italy200350144042
Latvia30107801010
Lithuania50013501380
Luxembourg2708019716,960
Malta0201090
Netherlands280460737019,210
Poland7008770
Portugal602005902790
Slovakia70010441,680
Slovenia100908201050
Spain1603101,9706120
Sweden2409015,84017,500
EU-2516028021608410
1 IQR means Interquartile Range.
Table 2. Milestones of the Common Agricultural Policy of the EU.
Table 2. Milestones of the Common Agricultural Policy of the EU.
YearShort Description
Market Support1962Introduction of CAP. Based on market support. Guaranteed prices were provided to farmers and tariffs on imports. Farmers were receiving support according to their total level of production. Common market organizations.
1979The Mansholt plan. Overproduction problems. Measures are put in place to align production with market needs. Introduction of market quotas and expenditure ceiling, e.g., milk quotas.
Producer Support1992McSharry reform. The CAP shifts from market support to producer support. Introduction of direct aid payments, ‘set-aside’ payments, measures to encourage retirement. Activity-specific payments according to area cultivated or number of animals maintained. Food quality and caring for the environment are introduced.
1999Agenda 2000. Introduction of ‘Rural Development’ as the second Pillar. Agri-environment schemes became compulsory.
Decoupled suport2003Fischler/Midterm CAP reform. The link between payments and production is cut. Introduction of ‘decoupled payments’ and ‘cross-compliance’ and ‘multifunctionality of agriculture’. ‘Single Payment Scheme’. Environmental, animal welfare and food safety standards are set as pre-requisites to receive payments.
2008Health Check. Enforcement of the 2003 reform.
20132014–2020 CAP reform. Introduction of ‘national envelopes’ for members states, i.e., flexibility in the budgeting and implementation of first pillar measurements. Introduction of ‘Basic Payment Scheme’, ‘Green Payment’, the ‘Young Farmers Scheme’ and ‘Redistributive Payment’. ‘Conditionality’ for receiving payments.
Compiled based on: a. Tangermann and von Cramon-Taubadel [13]; b. European Commission [14].
Table 3. Timeline of the historical and convergence models. (Source: Adaptation from Terluin et al. [16]).
Table 3. Timeline of the historical and convergence models. (Source: Adaptation from Terluin et al. [16]).
CAP 2007–2013CAP 2014–2020
ModelsHistoricalRegional Flat RateStatic HybridDynaimc HybridSSAPSPartial ConvergenceFull Convergence in 2015Full Convergence in 2019SAPS
Belgium, Wallony; France; Ireland; Greece; Spain; Italy; PortugalX X
Belgium, Flanders; Netherlands; Austria; UK, WalesX X
PolandX X
Malta X X
Slovenia X X
Luxemburg; UK, Northern Ireland X X
Sweden X X
Denmark X X
Germany; UK, England X X
Finland; UK, Scotland X X
Romania; Lituania; Bulgaria; Hungary; Estonia; Cyprus; Slovakia; Czech Republic; Latvia X X
SAPS: Single Area Payment Scheme, relevant for new Member States.
Table 4. Summary of scenarios.
Table 4. Summary of scenarios.
Convergence/Flat RateRedistribution
C85
Convergence continues until the payments per hectare of all farms are above 85% of the regional level
Note: The percentage of the budget that will move from farms above the mean to farms below the mean payment per hectare is (per region): arable, 4%; grazing, 4.7%; trees, 6.2%
R_F
Uniform (flat) payment per hectare at the regional level
Note: The uniform unit value per hectare will be (per region): arable, 225.44; grazing, 184.5; trees 283.73
C_F
Uniform (flat) payment per hectare at the country level
Note: The countrywide payment per hectare will be 224.71
R_few
Redistribution unit value is set to 55% of the maximum allowed redistribution unit value, so that fewer farms will benefit
Note: The percentage of farms that will receive a redistribution payment is (per region): arable, 30%; grazing, 27%; trees, 27%
R_many
Redistribution unit value is set to 25% of the maximum allowed redistribution unit value, so that more farms can benefit
Note: The percentage of farms that will receive a redistribution payment is (per region): arable, 52%; grazing, 48%; trees, 49%
Table 5. Effects of abolishing the historical entitlements per economic size.
Table 5. Effects of abolishing the historical entitlements per economic size.
Payments Change in Relation to Scenario C85Countrywide Flat Rate
C_F
Regional Flat Rate
R_F
<2000 EUR−11.60%−6.90%
2000–<8000 EUR−12.64%−3.70%
8000–<25,000 EUR−2.36%−1.20%
25,000–<50,000 EUR8.83%3.67%
50,000–<100,000 EUR11.00%4.26%
100,000–<500,000 EUR11.06%3.01%
>500,000 EUR17.39%10.13%
Table 6. Effects of abolishing the historical entitlements per type of farming.
Table 6. Effects of abolishing the historical entitlements per type of farming.
Payments Change in Relation to Scenario C85
C_FR_F C_FR_F
Cereals1.87%2.29%Cattle + Dairy7.89%−8.16%
Tobacco−29.68%−29.36%Mixed rumninants24.80%7.01%
Cotton−5.84%−5.41%Sheeps22.98%3.83%
Other arable0.68%1.08%Goats22.00%1.77%
Wine−9.38%2.72%Granivores0.96%0.78%
Other grapes−41.09%−27.97%Mixed crops−3.70%−0.06%
Citrus−25.33%−8.70%Mixed livestock9.37%2.53%
Olives−18.28%−0.80%Mixed crop + Livestock12.96%4.40%
Other permanent−15.36%−2.16%
Vegetables + flowers−5.71%2.21%
Table 7. Effects of different CAP 2023–2027 scenarios per economic size in comparison with the current 2014–2020 CAP.
Table 7. Effects of different CAP 2023–2027 scenarios per economic size in comparison with the current 2014–2020 CAP.
Change of Payments in Relation to Current CAPContinuation of Convergence
C85
Abolishment of Historical Entitlements
Countrywide Flat Rate
C_F
Regional Flat Rate
R_F
Economic SizeR_manyR_fewR_manyR_fewR_manyR_few
<2000 EUR−5.80%6.41%−14.84%−2.64%−11.18%1.03%
2000–<8000 EUR9.49%17.59%−0.63%7.47%6.53%14.63%
8000–<25,000 EUR1.78%−0.20%−0.14%−2.12%0.81%−1.17%
25,000–<50,000 EUR−3.66%−8.20%3.78%−0.76%−0.57%−5.11%
50,000–<100,000 EUR−7.12%−11.80%2.22%−2.47%−3.51%−8.19%
100,000–<500,000 EUR−10.41%−14.01%−1.09%−4.68%−7.88%−11.47%
>500,000 EUR−2.23%−5.35%14.00%10.87%7.22%4.10%
Table 8. Effects of different CAP 2020 scenarios per type of farming in comparison with the current 2014–2020 CAP.
Table 8. Effects of different CAP 2020 scenarios per type of farming in comparison with the current 2014–2020 CAP.
C85C_FR_F
Type of FarmingR_manyR_fewR_manyR_fewR_manyR_few
Cereals2.09%2.72%3.63%4.27%3.98%4.61%
Tobacco−14.75%−5.98%−35.50%−26.73%−35.27%−26.50%
Cotton−5.31%−9.01%−9.93%−13.63%−9.59%−13.29%
Other arable−2.21%−3.48%−1.65%−2.92%−1.32%−2.59%
Wine1.07%1.05%−6.83%−6.85%3.37%3.35%
Other grapes−25.02%−26.13%−52.44%−53.54%−43.69%−44.79%
Citrus−6.74%−6.13%−26.09%−25.48%−13.38%−12.77%
Olives0.43%2.90%−14.47%−12.00%−0.22%2.25%
Other permanent−0.81%0.62%−13.30%−11.86%−2.57%−1.14%
Vegetables + flowers5.40%5.59%0.60%0.80%7.26%7.45%
Cattle + Dairy−10.35%−13.52%−4.21%−7.38%−16.70%−19.86%
Mixed rumninants6.12%3.16%27.78%24.82%12.24%9.28%
Sheeps5.54%5.06%24.99%24.52%8.78%8.30%
Goats2.68%0.76%20.90%18.97%4.15%2.22%
Granivores6.76%6.91%7.55%7.71%7.40%7.56%
Mixed crops0.25%1.13%−2.79%−1.90%0.20%1.09%
Mixed livestock7.41%12.42%15.32%20.33%9.54%14.56%
Mixed crop + Livestock6.97%7.07%18.01%18.11%10.72%10.82%
Table 9. Income and the effect of abolishing historical entitlements. (Source: FADN public database and simulation results).
Table 9. Income and the effect of abolishing historical entitlements. (Source: FADN public database and simulation results).
(All Values in Euros)2000–< 80008000–< 25,00025,000–< 50,00050,000–< 100,000100,000–< 500,000
Gross farm income773615,81530,67054,42777,980
Farm net income489110,81920,61434,81146,363
Subsidies, excl. on investments2348514912,62219,73722,840
Changes in CAP 2023–2027 scenarios for Q25
Convergence + Redistribution few−162−605−1199−2123−3490
Convergence + Redistribution many−61−361−1150−2068−3391
Countrywide Flat Rate + Redistribution few−253−684−957−1536−2257
Countrywide Flat Rate + Redistribution many−115−528−824−1503−1918
Regional Flat Rate + Redistribution few−155−619−1082−2,113−3038
Regional Flat Rate + Redistribution many−75−355−998−2003−3069
Represented farms117,850149,83045,61017,6304410
Note: ’Gross farm income’, ‘Net Farm income’ and ‘Subsisidies, excl. on investments’ numbers are sourced from the FADN public database.
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Kremmydas, D.; Tsiboukas, K. Redistribution and the Abolishment of Historical Entitlements in the CAP Strategic Plans: The Case of Greece. Sustainability 2022, 14, 735. https://doi.org/10.3390/su14020735

AMA Style

Kremmydas D, Tsiboukas K. Redistribution and the Abolishment of Historical Entitlements in the CAP Strategic Plans: The Case of Greece. Sustainability. 2022; 14(2):735. https://doi.org/10.3390/su14020735

Chicago/Turabian Style

Kremmydas, Dimitrios, and Konstantinos Tsiboukas. 2022. "Redistribution and the Abolishment of Historical Entitlements in the CAP Strategic Plans: The Case of Greece" Sustainability 14, no. 2: 735. https://doi.org/10.3390/su14020735

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop