Next Article in Journal
A Study of Multidimensional and Persistent Poverty among Migrant Workers: Evidence from China’s CFPS 2014–2020
Next Article in Special Issue
Exploring the Multidimensional Perspective of Retail Investors’ Attention: The Mediating Influence of Corporate Governance and Information Disclosure on Corporate Environmental Performance in China
Previous Article in Journal
Improving the Performance of a SME in the Cutlery Sector Using Lean Thinking and Digital Transformation
Previous Article in Special Issue
Does Integrated Reporting Affect Real Activities Manipulation?
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Profitability or Longevity? Cross-Country Variations in Corporate Performance

1
International Christian University, 3-10-2, Osawa, Mitaka-shi, Tokyo 181-8585, Japan
2
School of Commerce, Waseda University, 1-6-1 Nishiwaseda, Shinjuku, Tokyo 169-8050, Japan
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2023, 15(10), 8307; https://doi.org/10.3390/su15108307
Submission received: 15 March 2023 / Revised: 21 April 2023 / Accepted: 5 May 2023 / Published: 19 May 2023

Abstract

:
The previous literature shows that firms’ purposes and behaviors vary across countries, but few studies have empirically examined whether firm performance varies across countries. This study compares the performance of the world’s largest corporations across 47 countries. Using the data for firms listed in the Fortune Global 500 from 1973 to 2020, we explore whether there are cross-country variations in two dimensions of corporate performance: profitability and longevity. We find significant variations in both profitability and longevity across countries. We also observe that firms in some countries are highly (less) profitable but less (more) likely to survive for a long time. We regress profitability and longevity on country-level institutional factors: financial systems, laws, and national cultures. We find that (i) a market-based (bank-based) financial system is positively (negatively) related to a firm’s profitability, but negatively (positively) related to its longevity; (ii) common law (civil law) is positively (negatively) related to the profitability of a firm, but negatively (positively) related to its longevity; and (iii) high individualism, low uncertainty avoidance, and low long-term orientation are positively related to profitability, but negatively related to longevity. These results suggest that a country’s formal and informal institutions significantly affect a firm’s purpose, behavior, and performance.

1. Introduction

This work is a cross-country comparative study on corporate performance. Using company data from 47 countries around the world, we analyze two dimensions of a firm’s performance, profitability and longevity, and examine whether and how they differ from country to country.
In recent years, there has been a lively debate about the purpose of a corporation in a capitalist economy [1,2,3,4]. The previous literature argues that there are several different types of corporations in the world, and that different types of corporations have different purposes [5,6,7,8,9]. The most representative view is that there are both shareholder-oriented and stakeholder-oriented companies in the world, and which of these types of company is dominant varies from country to country [10,11,12,13,14].
A shareholder-oriented company is one whose purpose is to maximize shareholder value and whose primary management goal is to make as much profit as possible. These shareholder-oriented companies are said to be dominant in Anglo-Saxon countries such as the U.S. and the U.K. On the other hand, a stakeholder-oriented company is one that aims to create value for various stakeholders (shareholders, employees, creditors, customers, suppliers, and local communities). These stakeholder-oriented companies are said to be most common in continental European countries, such as Germany and France, as well as in Asian countries such as Japan [15,16]. In fact, Yoshimori’s [17] survey of managers in the U.S., the U.K., Germany, France, and Japan and Witt and Redding’s [18] interviews with managers in the U.S., Germany, Japan, Korea, and Hong Kong revealed that corporate purposes actually differ between Anglo-Saxon countries and European or Asian countries.
Corporate purposes should influence a firm’s behavior. Thus, cross-country differences in corporate purposes should lead to cross-country differences in corporate behavior. Previous empirical studies have shown that there are cross-country differences in firm behavior, such as investment and R&D [19,20,21,22], capital structure [23,24,25,26], dividend policy [27,28], cash holdings [22,29,30], and M&A [31].
However, the question is, even if the corporate purposes and behavior differ from country to country, does the actual performance of companies also differ from country to country? For example, do companies in the U.S. and the U.K., which are said to aim at maximizing shareholder value, really generate more profits than companies in other countries? Meanwhile, do companies in France, Germany, and Japan, which are said to have relationships with their stakeholders, really create more value for their stakeholders?
To date, few studies have empirically examined whether firm performance differs across countries. The few exceptions are Espenlaub et al. [32], La Porta et al. [33], and Liang and Renneboog [34]. Using the data on firms across 27 countries worldwide in 1995–1996, La Porta et al. [33] found that firms in common law countries tend to have higher Tobin’s Q than firms in civil law countries. Espenlaub et al. [32] examined the survival of IPO firms from 32 countries from 2000 to 2008 and showed that IPO firms survive longer in countries with better investor protection. Liang and Renneboog [34] compared the CSR of firms from 112 countries from 1999 to 2014 and found that firms in civil law countries have higher CSR scores than those in common law countries. Compared to the frequent discussion on cross-county differences in corporate purposes and behavior, there is still little empirical evidence regarding cross-country differences in corporate performance.
To fill this gap, this study examines whether corporate performance differs across countries, using data on companies from 47 countries around the world. Compared to Espenlaub et al. [32], La Porta et al. [33], and Liang and Renneboog [34], this study has three unique features.
The first is comparing two dimensions of corporate performance across countries: profitability and longevity. While profitability is a well-known measure of a company’s performance, longevity has not received as much attention as profitability as a measure of a company’s performance. However, if we take a stakeholder-oriented view of the firm, longevity can be considered as one essential corporate performance measure. Stakeholders not only engage in current transactions with the firm, but they also typically make specific investments in the relationship with the firm, expecting that they will obtain monetary/non-monetary value in the future. For example, employees usually invest their human capital as well as off-work related capital (e.g., housing, children’s schools, and social relationships in local community) with the employment relationship [13] and, hence, they seek future job security for their companies. Customers may purchase a particular brand of products and require post-purchase services from the company. Suppliers may invest in specialized equipment to make the company’s products and aim to establish a long-term partnership with the company. These relationships between a firm and its stakeholders are considered as implicit (incomplete) contracts, and they cannot be traded in the market, unlike the relationship between shareholders and the firm, which is embodied in the ownership of shares and tradable in the stock market [13,35]. Thus, the value stakeholders can obtain will depend on the firm’s future circumstances. If the firm goes bankrupt or is acquired by another firm, stakeholders will not get the value they initially expected [6,36]. Therefore, the survival of a company is critically important to its stakeholders. Indeed, Witt and Redding [18] and Witt and Stahl [14] presented interview evidence that, in Germany and Japan (which are considered stakeholder-oriented societies), corporate managers’ goals are to ensure corporate survival and the permanence of the firm. Mayer ([6], p. 155) stated that “longevity and survival are the indicators of corporate success” from the stakeholder-oriented view of the firm.
The second feature of this study is that we further explore how country-level institutional factors are related to these differences if we find cross-country differences in profitability and longevity. In particular, unlike Espenlaub et al. [32], La Porta et al. [33], and Liang and Renneboog [34], who focused only on laws as institutional factors in each country, we examine not only the effect of a country’s laws, but also the effects of a country’s financial system and national culture on corporate performance. This provides us with a broader perspective to understand why cross-country performance differences emerge.
The third feature is that we use the world’s corporation data to cover a long period of time—48 years from 1973 to 2020. This allows us to examine whether or not there are cross-country differences in corporate performance over the long term, after removing the effects of each country’s short-term economic fluctuations that may affect corporate performance.
A challenging task in our research is collecting data to measure corporate longevity. For a company’s profitability, it is relatively easy to calculate profitability measures such as ROS (return on sales), ROA (return on assets), and ROE (return on equity) by collecting financial data figures from databases that include data on companies around the world. However, from such databases, it is not easy to obtain information on a company’s longevity, because data regarding the survival or death of a company are not as easily available as financial data figures. Databases usually stop including a company’s data when the company is delisted from the stock exchange. Thus, we may have the data on a company’s delisted year from the database, but being delisted does not necessarily mean that the company ceased to exist in that year; it may be that the company went private in that year, and it was still running. (For example, in Datastream, a global database, the reason why a company’s data are no longer included in the database is stated such as “company inactive delisted in Sep. 2011. Information will no longer be provided.” However, it does not state the reason why the company was delisted). We thus face difficulty in obtaining information from databases regarding the survival or death of firms, which can be inferred as being one reason why there has been no systematic analysis of firm longevity around the world.
In this paper, we address this problem by restricting our sample to large-scale global companies. More specifically, we choose as our sample companies that appear in Fortune magazine’s annual list of the world’s 500 largest companies (Fortune Global 500). Since the Fortune Global 500 companies are the largest companies in the world, it is easier to collect information on their subsequent survival or death from various sources, including the Internet, than it is for regular public companies. In addition, The Fortune magazine provides a footnote if a company was on the Fortune Global 500 list in a given year and is no longer on the list in the subsequent year due to bankruptcy or acquisition by another company. That is, information on the survival and death of our sample firms can be gathered, in part, from the Fortune magazine itself. We manually collected the data on the survival or death of our sample firms from various sources and checked whether they were still alive 10, 20, or 30 years after the year in which they were on the Fortune Global 500 list.
Analyzing the data, we find significant variations in both a firm’s profitability and longevity across countries. Interestingly, firms in some countries (e.g., the U.S. and the U.K.) are highly profitable, but less likely to survive for a long time, while firms in other countries (e.g., France and Japan) are less profitable, but more likely to survive for a long time. We also find that country-level institutional factors (financial system, law, and national culture) are significantly related to a firm’s profitability and longevity. Some institutional factors (such as a market-based financial system, a common law origin, and individualism) have positive effects on a firm’s profitability, but negative effects on a firm’s longevity. Other factors (such as a bank-based financial system, a civil law origin, uncertainty avoidance, and long-term orientation) have negative effects on a firm’s profitability, but positive effects on a firm’s longevity. This suggests that institutions matter for corporate performance and that each institutional factor has a positive impact on one dimension of corporate performance, but a negative impact on the other.
The findings of this paper not only contribute to the literature in this field, but also have practical and policy implications. Since the late 1990s, there have been policy movements to introduce Anglo-Saxon shareholder-oriented corporate governance to stakeholder-oriented economies such as Germany and Japan. These movements were based on the assumption that U.S. and U.K. companies perform better than German and Japanese companies, and that shareholder-oriented governance enhances a firm’s competitiveness [16,37]. However, to date, the validity of this assumption has not been adequately examined with data. Without empirical evidence on performance differences between the U.S./U.K. firms and German/Japanese firms, it is difficult to predict the effects of the introduction of Anglo-Saxon-style corporate governance to German and Japanese stakeholder-oriented economies. In addition, corporate governance reforms usually involve attempts to change national institutions, particularly laws (including soft laws such as codes) and financial systems. However, it should not be possible to discuss the effects of the pros and cons of changing such institutions without knowing whether and how a country’s institutional environment is related to corporate performance. Therefore, the findings of this study on cross-country differences in a firm’s profitability and longevity and the relationship between a country’s institutional factors and corporate performance provide useful knowledge for these practical and policy issues on corporate governance.
This paper is organized as follows. First, Section 2 describes the data and research methodologies. Section 3 uses these data to examine whether there are variations in firm performance across countries from two performance dimensions: profitability and longevity. Section 4 examines the possibility that a country’s institutional factors (financial system, law, and national culture) affect firm performance. Section 5 provides empirical analyses of the relationship between institutional factors and firm performance. Finally, Section 6 summarizes the results of this paper and discusses the implications.

2. Data and Research Methodology

2.1. Sample

Our original sample consists of firms around the world that were included in one of the three lists of the Fortune magazine—Fortune Global 500, Fortune 500, and Fortune International 500—from 1973 to 2020. The sample firms from 1989 to 2020 were firms listed in the Fortune Global 500 for each year. Since 1990, the Fortune magazine has annually announced the 500 largest companies all over the world ranked by sales (in USD) in the previous year as the Fortune Global 500 (the 1990–1993 period covered the manufacturing sector, and from 1994 onward, all industries). We looked at the Fortune magazine every year from 1990 to 2021 and chose the Fortune Global 500 firms as our sample firms for 1989–2020.
Before 1990, the Fortune annually announced the 500 largest manufacturing firms in the U.S. (Fortune 500) ranked by sales in the previous year, and the 500 largest manufacturing firms outside the U.S. (Fortune International 500) ranked by sales (in USD) in the previous year, separately. Therefore, we combined these two lists and chose the 500 largest manufacturing firms in the world ranked by sales (in USD) for each year, and created our list of the Fortune Global 500 as our sample for 1973–1988 (The Fortune magazine had announced the Fortune 500 and Fortune International 500 before 1973, but they had not included data on the industries of the firms. Therefore, we excluded pre-1973 from the sample).
If the same firm appeared on the list for more than one year, it is treated as a separate observation. Thus, our data are firm-year unbalanced panel data (To address within-firm residual correlations, we use standard errors clustered by the firm in the regression analyses in Section 5). The original sample for all years (1973–2020) was composed of 24,000 firm-year observations (500 firms per each year × 48 years). From this original sample, we excluded firms in the finance and insurance sectors (SIC code 60–63) and firms in current and former socialist countries (China, Hungary, Poland, and Russia) (Firms in the finance and insurance sectors were removed from the sample for three reasons. First, the operations of finance and insurance firms differ in many aspects from those of general business firms, and their financial statements have different formats. Second, the finance and insurance sectors are regulated industries. Third, while the present study explores the impact of the financial system on firm performance, firms in the finance and insurance sectors are themselves members of the financial system. The percentage of finance and insurance firms in the Fortune Global 500 lists for 1994–2020 is 24.7%, and still accounts for 23.9% of the 2020 list). This left us with 19,498 firm-year observations (1384 firms) in 47 countries. The sample compositions by country, industry, and year are summarized in Table 1.
In the Fortune lists, the following data are available for each sample firm: company name, sales, net profits, total assets, stockholders’ equity (these data are in USD). the number of employees, industrial classification, country, and information on M&A, spin-off, bankruptcy, and company name changes. We utilized these data for our analyses.

2.2. Performance Measures

As explained earlier, we focus on two dimensions of corporate performance: profitability and longevity. For profitability, we define three measures: ROS (return on sales; net profits/sales; %); ROA (return on assets; net profits/total assets; %); and ROE (return on equity; net profits/stockholders’ equity; %). (When a company’s fiscal year ends changed, it was dropped from the sample when calculating ROS, ROA, and ROE. We also dropped firms when calculating ROE if the firm’s stockholder’s equity was negative). The data for the calculation of these measures were taken from the Fortune magazine.
For longevity, we looked at a company’s probability of survival for the subsequent 10, 20, and 30 years. To define the survival of a company, following the previous literature [32], we considered two cases of corporate death in this paper. The first case was when a firm went bankrupt, was liquidated, or was dissolved. This case was regarded as death because the firm no longer operates, and it ceases to have any relationship with its stakeholders. The other case was when a company was acquired by another company. This case can also be regarded as death because, when being taken over by another firm, the relationships with existing stakeholders are significantly disrupted [6,36]. We considered a firm to have survived until the year before one of the above two cases occurred. If a firm merged with another firm, we considered both pre-merger firms to have continued to exist for as long as the new firm survived.
We manually surveyed each of our sample firms to determine if they were alive or dead in the subsequent years. To obtain this information, we used four main sources of information. The first source was a company’s information added to the Fortune 500 list, in which the Fortune magazine provides a footnote to the list, including information on any change during the year in the company’s status due to mergers and acquisitions, bankruptcies, liquidations, etc. In addition, if a company was on the Fortune 500 list in a previous year but was not listed in that year, the Fortune magazine sometimes mentions the reason why they were delisted from the list (e.g., the company was acquired by another company, went bankrupt, etc.). We used these pieces of information to see if a company died in that year and the next.
The second source of information was Capital IQ (S&P Global Market Intelligence), which has information on the current status of public and private companies around the world (including those that have already died). Capital IQ also provides the company’s business description, which, for companies that have already died, usually includes information on when they were acquired by other companies, when they went bankrupt, and so on. The third source was OSIRIS (Bureau Van Dijk), which contains information on public companies and major privately held or delisted companies around the world. It provides information on the current status of a company (active or inactive) and, for inactive companies, when their last fiscal year ended. The fourth was Wikipedia, which has information on the history of the company, as well as when the defunct year was for those companies that no longer exist. If we could not clearly determine the subsequent survival or death of the company from these four information sources, we used other information on the Internet, such as company websites and newspaper articles. Consequently, for 1296 of the 1384 firms in our sample, we were able to determine whether they survived or died in the subsequent years (of 1296 firms, 798 continued to survive until 2021; 498 died before 2021. For 481 of the 498 dead firms, we could identify the reason for the deaths: 414 (86.1%) were due to acquisitions by other companies and 67 (13.9%) were due to bankruptcy/liquidation/dissolution).
After obtaining information on the survival or death of the sample firms, we observed whether they survived for the subsequent 10, 20, and 30 years. More specifically, for the 2001–2010 sample, we determined whether the firm survived over 10 years; for the 1991–2000 sample, whether the firm survived over 10 and 20 years; and for the 1973–1990 sample, whether the firm survived over 10, 20, and 30 years. For each survival period (10, 20, and 30 years), 1 was assigned to survivors and 0 was assigned to non-survivors, and the survival rate (the proportion of survivors) was calculated for each category.

2.3. Research Methodology

We conduct our empirical analysis using the following methodologies. First, we present country-by-country values of profitability (ROS, ROA, and ROE) and longevity (10-, 20-, and 30-year survival rates) and observe whether there are cross-country differences in corporate performance (Section 3). Second, we hypothesize that the cross-country differences are caused by country-level institutional factors, the financial system, law, and national culture (Section 4). We then test the hypotheses by using two methods. One is dividing the sample into two groups according to each country’s institutional factors and conducting two-group comparison tests (Section 5.1). The other is conducting regression analyses and examining the effects of institutional factors on firm performance (Section 5.2, Section 5.3 and Section 5.4).

3. Cross-Country Variations in Corporate Performance

Table 2 shows the numbers for performance measures for our sample firms. The left half of the table shows three profitability measures (the medians of ROS, ROA, and ROE), and the right half of the table shows three longevity measures (10-year, 20-year, and 30-year survival rates). Panel A shows the numbers for the entire sample; Panel B shows the country-by-country numbers for countries with more than 100 firm-year observations and more than 10 firm observations.
Starting with profitability measures, in Panel A, we see that the medians of ROS, ROA, and ROE are 3.18%, 3.57%, and 11.21%, respectively, for the full sample. In Panel B, we observe significant cross-country variations in profitability measures. For example, U.S. firms’ median ROS, ROA, and ROE are 4.46%, 5.69%, and 14.29%, respectively; for U.K. firms, they are 4.20%, 4.56%, and 13.04%, respectively; and for Canadian firms, they are 4.22%, 4.56%, and 11.92%, respectively. These U.S., U.K, and Canadian numbers are all higher than the medians for the full sample shown in Panel A. In contrast, the profitability measures of France, Germany, Italy, Japan, and South Korea are lower than the world’s medians (for example, the median ROS, ROA, and ROE of Japanese firms are 1.62%, 1.53%, and 6.72%, respectively). We observe high profitability for U.S., U.K., and Canadian firms, and low profitability for French, German, Italian, Japanese, and Korean firms.
Next, we look at longevity measures: 10-year, 20-year, 30-year survival rates. Panel A shows these three rates for the full sample. We see that the 10-year survival rate is 87.6%, which means that 87.6% of firms listed in the Fortune Global 500 survive for at least another 10 years. The 20-year survival rate is 73.6%, and the 30-year survival rate is 59.8%. Panel B shows the survival rates by country. We observe significant cross-country variations in the survival rates. For example, the 10-year, 20-year, 30-year survival rates for the U.S. firms are 81.2%, 62.5%, and 47.2%, respectively, and these three survival rates are lower than those of the world as a whole shown in Panel A. The U.K. and Canadian survival rates are also lower than those for the full sample. In contrast, the French, Japanese, and South Korean survival rates are higher than those of the world as a whole. For, example, Japanese firms’ survival rates are 97.4% over 10 years, 94.7% over 20 years, and 92.4% over 30 years; over 90% of Japanese firms survive for at least another 30 years.
The survival rates provide us with a very different picture of corporate performance than the profitability numbers. U.S., U.K., and Canadian firms are highly profitable, but they are less likely to survive; French, German, Japanese, and Korean firms are less profitable, but they are more likely to survive for a long period. This observation implies that two dimensions of corporate performance—profitability and longevity—are not necessarily positively correlated with each other. This suggests that we should look at not only profitability, but also longevity when evaluating a company’s performance.
If we compare the performance of U.S. and U.K. firms (which are considered to be shareholder-oriented) with that of French, German, and Japanese firms (which are considered to be stakeholder-oriented) in the two dimensions of profitability and longevity, we can obtain interesting findings. The U.S. and U.K. firms are more profitable than the French, German, and Japanese firms, but the French, German, and Japanese firms are more likely to survive for a long time than the U.S. and U.K. firms.
Observing cross-county differences in profitability and longevity, one may wonder if these performance differences stem not from the country differences, but from the differences in the industry composition of firms in each country. To address this issue, we regress ROA and the 10-year survival on industry dummies or country dummies (year dummies are also added), and observe how much variation in performance measures can be explained by a firm’s industry classification and its country classification (industry classification of sample firms follows two-digit SIC codes). The ROA regression is conducted by means of OLS, and the 10-year survival regression (the dependent variable being 1 or 0) are conducted by means of probit estimation (we trim ROA at the upper and lower one-percent level for the sample of ROA regressions, to reduce the effect of outliers). Table 3 shows the results. We find that country dummies explain more of the variance in profitability and longevity than industry dummies. For example, for ROA regression, the adjusted R2 of the OLS regression with industry dummies (Model 1) is 0.134, and with country dummies (Model 2) it is 0.192. For 10-year survival regression, the Pseudo R2 of the probit regression with industry dummies (Model 3) is 0.046, and with country dummies (Model 4) it is 0.084. These results suggest that the country effect is more significant than the industry effect in explaining the profitability and longevity of the firm. We argue that the country matters even for the performance of the world’s largest corporations.
We can easily predict that a firm’s profitability and longevity are influenced by a number of country characteristics. In particular, we posit that the country’s institutional environment in which a firm operates shapes its purposes and behavior and, hence, affects two dimensions of corporate performance. We empirically explore this possibility in the following sections.

4. Country’s Institutional Factors and Corporate Performance

Greif [38], North [39], and Williamson [40] state that formal and informal institutions of the economy and society significantly influence economic agents’ decisions, actions and outcomes. We consider three country-level institutional factors that affect a firm’s behavior and hence corporate performance: financial systems, laws, and national cultures.

4.1. Financial Systems

Observing the financial systems of countries around the world, we find various differences in terms of laws, institutions, and customs. Researchers classify the financial systems of countries into market-based systems and bank-based systems [41].
A market-based financial system is where financial transactions in a country are mainly conducted through capital markets, such as stock and bond markets. In capital markets, numerous participants engage in financial transactions at arm’s length. The supplier and demander of funds enter into a one-time transaction on a spot basis, and there is no need for them to continue conducting transactions with the same partner. The suppliers of funds (investors) usually hold multiple assets to diversify their investment risk; the demanders of funds (such as a firm) issue standardized securities (e.g., stock and bond) to raise money from a large number of investors. Sometimes, even the ownership of a firm is traded in M&A market transactions.
A bank-based financial system is where financial transactions in a country are mainly conducted through financial intermediation by banks. Banks receive deposits and provide loans to firms, and lending is conducted through one-on-one negotiated transactions. A continual transactional relationship arises between the bank and firms. In the bank-based system, since capital markets are less developed, M&A transactions are less likely to occur compared to in the market-based system.
We expect that a firm’s profitability tends to be higher in countries with a market-based financial system, than in countries with a bank-based financial system. In a market-based system, shareholders are one of the main suppliers of funds, and they seek higher returns and profitability. Additionally, since shareholders usually diversify their investment risk, they encourage each firm’s risk taking, which is likely to realize a firm’s higher (expected) profitability. In a bank-based system, banks expect a firm to realize stable returns rather than higher (but riskier) returns because the payoff of the loan is contractually fixed to interest and principal. Therefore, a firms’ profitability in bank-based system will not be as high as that in market-based system.
In contrast, a firm’s greater longevity is more likely to be observed in countries with a bank-based system than in countries with a market-based system. In a bank-based system, since banks expect firms to avoid risk, firms’ earnings are expected to be stable [42]. Additionally, as banks have continual relationships with their client firms, they prefer a firm’s long-term viability. These factors enable firms to be more likely to survive in a bank-based system compared to a market-based system. In addition, the M&A market is not as active as that in a market-based system, and the firm is less likely to be acquired. This also enhances a firm’s longevity in countries with a bank-based system.
To summarize, we can establish the following hypotheses on the relationship between a country’s financial system and a firm’s profitability and longevity.
H1a: 
A market-based financial system is positively related to a firm’s profitability and negatively related to a firm’s longevity.
H1b: 
A bank-based financial system is negatively related to a firm’s profitability and positively related to a firm’s longevity.

4.2. Laws

The law and finance literature claims that common law provides better protection of shareholder rights than civil law [43]. Shareholders tend to seek higher returns, even at higher risk, because they can diversify the risk of their investments by holding shares in various companies [19]. This suggests that, in countries with a common law origin, shareholders have more power to encourage managers to implement riskier but value-enhancing investments. John et al. [19] reported that companies take more risk and show higher productivity in common law countries than in civil law countries. La Porta et al. [33] showed that Tobin’s Q is higher in common law countries than in civil law countries. Therefore, we predict that a common law origin is positively related to a firm’s profitability. Common law, however, may inhibit firm longevity. With strong shareholder rights, firms take more risks and their outcomes become more volatile, and they are less likely to survive. In addition, strong shareholder rights increase the probability of a corporate takeover. Therefore, it is possible that a common law origin has a negative effect on firm longevity.
In contrast, civil law is usually less protective of shareholder rights [43]. Rather, the law is more protective of workers and consumers, and it is more stakeholder-friendly [34]. Companies are expected to maintain good relationships with their stakeholders for a longer period. Therefore, it is plausible that firms in countries with a civil law origin survive longer, although their profits are lower than those of firms in countries with a common law origin. Thus, we predict that a civil law origin has a negative effect on firm profitability, and that it has a positive effect on longevity.
To summarize, we can establish the following hypotheses on the relationship between a country’s legal origin and a firm’s profitability and longevity.
H2a: 
A common law origin is positively related to a firm’s profitability and negatively related to a firm’s longevity.
H2b: 
A civil law origin is negatively related to a firm’s profitability and positively related to a firm’s longevity.

4.3. National Cultures

Recent empirical studies show that national culture significantly affects corporate decision-making in finance, investment, and accounting [20,21,22,23,26,28,44,45,46,47,48]. Most of these studies used Hofstede’s [49] four cultural dimensions—individualism, uncertainty avoidance, power distance, and masculinity—as proxies for national culture, and explored the relationship between these indexes of cultural dimensions at the national level and corporate behavior at the firm level. Following prior research, we use the indexes of two of Hofstede’s [49] cultural dimensions (individualism and uncertainty avoidance). Additionally, we use an index of Hofstede et al.’s [50] new dimension, long-term orientation, which is likely to affect a firm’s profitability and longevity.
Individualism is defined as “a society in which the ties between individuals are loose: Everyone is expected to look after him/herself and her/his immediate family only. Collectivism stands for a society in which people from birth onwards are integrated into strong, cohesive in-groups, which throughout people’s lifetime continue to protect them in exchange for unquestioning loyalty” ([49], p. 225). In highly individualistic societies, people are more likely to pursue their own success and be willing to take risks. These tendencies are observed even in corporate behavior. Li et al. [20] and Mihet [21] show that corporate risk-taking is higher in countries with high individualism. Therefore, we expect that, on average, firms are more profitable as compensation for high risks in highly individualistic countries. In contrast, firms are less likely to survive in those countries, since they incur higher risk. In contrast, regarding a firm’s longevity, collectivistic countries have a superiority over individualistic countries, because people put more emphasis on the continuity of a firm that is the group they belong to.
Uncertainty avoidance is defined as “the extent to which the members of a culture feel threatened by uncertain or unknown situations” ([49], p. 161). Therefore, it is plausible that people in high-uncertainty-avoidance countries tend to avoid risk. Li et al. [20] and Mihet [21] provided evidence that firms in high-uncertainty-avoidance countries are less likely to take risks. Therefore, we predict that high uncertainty avoidance is negatively related to a firm’s profitability but positively related to a firm’s longevity.
Long-term orientation is defined as “[it] stands for the fostering of virtues oriented towards future rewards—in particular, perseverance and thrift” ([50], p. 239). Hofstede et al. [50] claim that in long-term-oriented countries (especially in Asia), companies invest in building up strong market positions at the expense of immediate results; in short-term-orientated countries, companies are more concerned about the results of the past month, quarter, or year. This indicates that high long-term orientation is negatively related to a firm’s profitability, but positively related to a firm’s longevity.
To summarize, we can establish the following hypotheses on the relationship between a country’s culture and a firm’s profitability and longevity.
H3a: 
High individualism is positively related to a firm’s profitability and negatively related to a firm’s longevity.
H3b: 
High uncertainty avoidance is negatively related to a firm’s profitability and positively related to a firm’s longevity.
H3c: 
High long-term orientation is negatively related to a firm’s profitability and positively related to a firm’s longevity.

5. Empirical Analyses

5.1. Two-Group Comparison Tests

To test these hypotheses, we empirically explore the relationship between a firm’s profitability and longevity measures and each country’s institutional environments, such as the financial system, its laws, and culture. The institutional environments of the countries to which our sample firms belong are summarized in Table 4.
First, we compare profitability and longevity measures by dividing the sample into two groups according to each country’s institutional factors (financial system, law, and national culture). To reduce the effect of outliers, we trim ROS and ROA (ROE) at the upper and lower one-percent (five-percent) level in the following analyses. (Initially, we trimmed ROE at the upper and lower one-percent level as well, but we found that ROE at the 1st percentile is −72.03% and ROE at the 99th percentile is 72.31%; both are large absolute values. This is likely due to the fact that some companies have extremely small stockholders’ equity values. Therefore, we decided to trim ROE at the upper and lower five-percent level to reduce the effect of outliers). The results are summarized in Table 5.
Panel A presents the results of the comparison of profitability and longevity, dividing the sample into firms in countries with a market-based financial system, and firms in countries with a bank-based financial system [41]. The results show that firms in market-based system countries have a higher profitability (higher means of ROS, ROA, and ROE) than those in bank-based system countries. We conducted mean comparison tests and found that the differences in ROS, ROA, and ROE between the two groups are statistically significant. On the other hand, the survival rates over 10, 20, and 30 years, which represent the longevity of a firm, are higher for firms in a bank-based system than for firms in a market-based system. We conducted tests for the difference in proportions and found that the differences in the survival rates between the two groups are statistically significant. These results support H1a and H1b.
Panel B divides the sample into firms from common law countries and firms from civil law countries [43]. The results show that firms in common law countries have significantly higher ROS, ROA, and ROE than those in civil law countries. On the other hand, the 10-, 20-, and 30-year survival rates of firms are significantly higher for firms in civil law countries than for firms in common law countries. These results support H2a and H2b.
Panels C1–C3 compare firms’ profitability and longevity according to the national culture of the firm’s country. To achieve this, we first calculated the median values of the individualism index (IDV), uncertainty avoidance index (UA), and long-term orientation index (LTO) of Hofstede [49] and Hofstede et al. [50] across our sample countries. The medians of IDV, UA, and LTO are 46, 68, and 38, respectively. We then divided the countries into two groups for each of the three indexes: countries whose indexes are greater than the median and countries whose indexes are less than (or equal to) the median. We compare profitability and longevity measures between the two groups. The results in Panels C1, C2, and C3 show that: (1) firms in countries with a high IDV have higher profitability measures (ROS, ROA, and ROE), but lower survival rates (10-, 20-, and 30-year survival rates), than firms in countries with a low IDV; (2) firms in countries with a high UA have lower profitability measures, but higher survival rates, than firms in countries with a low UA; and (3) firms in countries with a high LTO have lower profitability measures, but higher survival rates, than firms in countries with a low LTO. These results indicate that H3a, H3b, and H3c are all supported.
However, we should note that, like many cross-country studies, the U.S. sample comprises a large part of our sample (see Table 1). Therefore, it may be possible that the above results are driven largely by the U.S. firms. To address this concern, we excluded U.S. firms and re-calculated each value in Table 5. We confirmed that the results did not change quantitatively; all the differences between the two groups remain significant at the 1% level. Additionally, Japan is the country with the second largest sample size. Thus, we recalculated the data by excluding Japanese firms, as well as U.S. firms, from the sample. Then, among the 30 pairs of comparisons in Table 5, although the differences became no longer significant in 3 pairs (ROE in Panel C1; 10-year and 20-year survival rates in Panel C3), the differences were still significant for the remaining 27 pairs. Given these results, we can say that the conclusions obtained in Table 5 do not change when the U.S. and Japan are removed from the sample.

5.2. Regression Analyses

Another concern regarding the results in Table 5 would be that these country-level institutional factors are correlated with the country’s economic variables, such as economic conditions and growth rates and the size of the economy, and that the country’s economic variables may cause differences in firm performance—that is, the correlation between the institutional factors and corporate performance may be spurious. To address this problem, we regress the profitability and longevity on country-level institutional factors, controlling for these countries’ economic variables. In the regression analyses below, we use the ROS, ROA, and ROE, and 10-year, 20-year-, and 30-year survival (a dummy variable which takes a value of 1 if a firm survives and 0 if a firm does not survive) as dependent variables. The independent variables for the country’s institutional factors are as follows.
  • [Variables for the financial system]
Market-based: dummy variable which takes a value of 1 if a country’s financial system is classified as a market-based financial system and 0 if it is classified as a bank-based financial system by Demirguc-Kunt and Levine [41].
Market-cap/GDP: market capitalization of listed domestic companies as a percentage of GDP (%; source: World Development Indicators and Financial Structure Database of the World Bank).
Bank credit/GDP: domestic credit given to private sector by banks as a percentage of GDP (%; source: World Development Indicators and Financial Structure Database of the World Bank).
  • [Variables for law]
Common: dummy variable which takes a value of 1 for common law countries and 0 otherwise (source: La Porta et al. [43]).
French civil: dummy variable which takes a value of 1 for French civil law countries and 0 otherwise (source: La Porta et al. [43]).
German civil: dummy variable which takes a value of 1 for German civil law countries and 0 otherwise (source: La Porta et al. [43]).
Scandinavian civil: dummy variable which takes a value of 1 for Scandinavian civil law countries and 0 otherwise (source: La Porta et al. [43]).
  • [Variables for national culture]
Individualism: individualism index suggested by Hofstede [49].
Uncertainty avoidance: uncertainty avoidance index suggested by Hofstede [49].
Long-term orientation: long-term orientation index suggested by Hofstede et al. [50].
For the control variables of the ROS, ROA, and ROE regressions, we use the following variables: the country’s annual GDP growth rate (GDP growth; %), the logarithm of GDP per capita (ln GDP capita; US dollars), the logarithm of a firm’s total assets (ln Size; million US dollars), and the logarithm of [1 + firm age] (ln Age). In the 10-, 20-, and 30-year survival regressions, we use the same control variables, but replace the country’s annual GDP growth rate with the country’s GDP growth rate for the following 10, 20, and 30 years (calculated as the annual rate). We took the data of GDP growth and GDP per capita from World Development Indicators and Financial Structure Database, and the data of firm total assets from the Fortune magazine. The firm age is calculated as [year—founded year], where the data of founded year are obtained from Capital IQ, OSIRIS, Wikipedia, and other Internet sources. Industry and year dummies are added to each regression. The descriptive statics of dependent and independent variables are summarized in Table 6. (We do not include variables representing firms’ decision-making as the control variables in the regression equations to prevent bias in the estimated coefficients. For example, debt ratios and cash holdings ratios are firms’ decision-making variables. They may be affected by country-level institutional factors and, thus, can be the dependent (outcome) variables in the regression equation in which the institutional factors are independent variables [22,23,26,29,30]. It is known that including variables that can be dependent variables as the control variables gives rise to bias in the estimated coefficients [51]. Therefore, we do not include debt ratios and cash holdings, and other variables representing firms’ decision-making as control variables in the regression equations).
We should note that although our data are firm-year unbalanced panel data, the country-level institutional variables shown in Table 6 are time-invariant (constant over time), except for Market-cap/GDP and Bank credit/GDP. This suggests that we cannot estimate fixed effect regressions. Thus, we estimate the regressions by pooled OLS (ROS, ROE, and ROE regressions) and the pooled probit model (10-, 20-, and 30-year survival regressions) by the maximum likelihood method (De Jong et al. [24], Dodge et al. [52], and Kanagaretnam et al. [46,47] also estimate pooled regressions for their panel data set when using time-invariant country-level variables). To address within-firm residual correlations, we use standard errors clustered by the firm [53]. We also estimate the random effect model regressions for robustness checks.

5.3. Regression Results

Table 7 presents the regression results on the effect of a country’s financial system on corporate performance. The left half of the table reports the OLS regression results of the profitability (ROS, ROA, ROE), and the right half reports the probit regression results of the longevity (10-, 20-, and 30-year survival). Looking at the left half, we find that Market-based (dummy variable for market-based system) has significant positive effects on ROS, ROA, and ROE. This suggests that firms in countries with a market-based financial system are more profitable than firms in countries with a bank-based financial system, after controlling for macroeconomic factors (GDP growth, ln GDP capita), firm size (ln Size), firm age (ln Age), and industry and year effects. For example, the ROA regression suggests that the ROA of firms in market-based systems is about 2.8 percentage points higher than that of firms in bank-based systems, all other things being equal. Market-cap/GDP also has significant positive effects on the three profitability measures. In contrast, Bank credit/GDP, the measure of bank dominance in financial system, has negative effects on the three profitability measures.
The right half of Table 7 shows the effect of the financial system on a firm’s longevity. In the tables below, we report the average marginal effect of each variable in the probit estimations. We find that a market-based system has negative effects on firm longevity. The marginal effects of the Market-based dummy are significantly negative in 10-, 20- 30-year survival regressions; this suggests that firms in market-based systems are less likely to survive than firms in bank-based systems. For example, the results suggest that the 20-year survival probability is 16.8 percentage points lower for firms in market-based systems than for firms in bank-based systems, all other things being equal. We also observe that Market-cap/GDP has significant negative effects on the 30-year survival probability and Bank credit/GDP has significant positive effects on the 10-, 20-, and 30-year survival probabilities. These results suggest that firms in bank-based systems have a higher viability than firms in market-based systems.
Overall, the results of Table 7 confirm the results of Panel A in Table 5 and support Hypotheses H1a and H1b. Corporate profitability is higher in market-based financial systems; corporate longevity is higher in bank-based financial systems.
Regarding the effects of control variables, GDP growth has significantly positive effects on the three profitability measures. Both ln Size and ln Age have significantly positive effects on the three survival probabilities: larger firms and long-standing firms are more likely to survive over 10-, 20-, and 30 years.
Table 8 presents the effects of law on corporate performance. We find that Common (dummy variable for common-law-origin countries) has significantly positive effects on all three profitability measures. For example, the results suggest that the ROA of firms in common-law-origin countries is about 2.9 percentage points higher than that of firms in civil-law-origin countries, all other things being equal. We also observe that Common has significantly negative effects on 10-, 20-, and 30-year survival probabilities. This indicates that companies in common-law countries are less likely to survive. In contrast, firms in civil-law countries are less profitable but more likely to survive than firms in common-law countries. For the French-civil, German-civil, and Scandinavian-civil dummies, while the coefficients in ROS, ROA, and ROE regressions are all significantly negative, the marginal effects in survival regressions are all significantly positive. For example, the 20-year survival probabilities of French civil law firms, German civil law firms, and Scandinavian civil law firms are 14.5, 24.2, and 26.6 percentage points higher than those of common law firms, respectively. These results confirm the results of Panel B in Table 5 and support Hypotheses H2a and H2b: common-law firms are more profitable and civil-law firms are more viable.
Table 9 and Table 10 present the regression results for the effects of national culture on a firm’s profitability and longevity, respectively. Table 9 shows that the Individualism index has significantly positive effects on the profitability (ROS, ROA, ROE); the Uncertainty avoidance and Long-term orientation indexes have significantly negative effects on the profitability. For example, the results indicate that a one-standard-deviation increase in a country’s Individualism index raises ROA by 1.44 percentage points (=21.121 × 0.068: 21.121 is the standard deviation of Individualism shown in Table 6 and 0.068 is the estimated coefficient of Individualism in the ROA regression in Table 9). Contrarily, Table 10 shows that the Individualism index has significantly negative effects on the longevity. It also shows that the Uncertainty avoidance and Long-term orientation indexes have significantly positive effects on longevity. For example, the results indicate that a one-standard-deviation increase in a country’s Uncertainty avoidance and Long-term orientation raise 20-year survival probabilities by 10.42 percentage points (=20.844 × 0.005 × 100) and 10.55 percentage points (=26.368 × 0.004 × 100), respectively. These results confirm the results of Panels C1, C2, and C3 in Table 5, and support Hypotheses H3a, H3b, and H3c. A firm’s profitability is higher in individualistic countries and a firm’s long-term viability is higher in uncertainty-avoiding countries and long-term-orientated countries.

5.4. Robustness

We check the robustness of the regression results by using the random effect (RE) model, excluding US and Japanese firms from the sample, adding a country’s corporate tax rate to control variables, and excluding firms whose data were obtained from Wikipedia and other Internet sources.
First, we examined how the RE model changes the regression results. Using the RE model estimation, of the 18 coefficients of the financial system variables, 3 became insignificant and 1 became significant, compared to the pooled OLS and probit regressions shown in Table 7. In Table 8, 2 of the 24 coefficients of the law variables became insignificant; in Table 9 and Table 10, no changes in significance for the 18 coefficients of national culture variables are observed. Therefore, we can say that the RE model does not change the main conclusions of the results.
Second, we run the regressions by excluding firms from the U.S., the country with the largest sample. Without U.S. firms, 1 of the 18 coefficients of the financial system variables became insignificant in Table 7. In Table 8, 2 of the 24 coefficients of the law variables became insignificant; in Table 9 and Table 10, no changes in significance for the 18 coefficients of national culture variables are observed. These results suggest that excluding U.S. firms does not change the results significantly. If we exclude Japanese firms (the second largest sample size), as well as U.S. firms, in Table 7, 7 of the 18 coefficients of the institutional factors became insignificant, but 1 became significant; in Table 8, 3 of the 24 coefficients became insignificant; in Table 9 and Table 10, 4 of the 18 coefficients became insignificant. These results suggest that the main conclusions do not change when excluding both the U.S. and Japanese samples.
Third, we included the corporate tax rate of each country as a control variable in the profitability and longevity regressions. We used the data on the corporate tax rates in the spreadsheet, “1980–2022 Corporate-Tax-Rates-Around-the-World” on the website of Tax Foundation (https://taxfoundation.org/corporate-tax-rates-by-country-2022/ accessed on 18 February 2023). This spreadsheet provides the data on corporate tax rates for each year since 1980 for 251 countries around the world; for some countries, the data are only available later than 1980. Therefore, when conducting the analyses, the sample is limited to observations from 1980 onward and observations in the year and country for which the data on corporate tax rate are available. Therefore, using corporate tax rates reduced the sample size to 50–80% of the original size. The results of the regression including corporate tax rates were almost identical to the original results. For the financial system variables, all 18 coefficients are significant; for the law variables, only 2 of 24 coefficients became insignificant; for the national culture variables, all coefficients remained significant. Therefore, we argue that including the corporate tax rate in the regression does not change the conclusions. We also found that the corporate tax rate tends to have a negative effect on a firm’s profitability and longevity. In the profitability regressions, the coefficient of the corporate tax rate is negative in 19 of the 21 equations, 15 of which are statistically significant. In the longevity regressions, the coefficient of the corporate tax rate is negative in 17 of the 21 equations, 6 of which are statistically significant.
Lastly, we run the regressions by excluding 3518 firm-year observations whose data on survival and founded years were obtained from Wikipedia and other Internet sources, considering that information available on the Internet may be less reliable than the information in databases supplied by data providers. The results were almost identical to the original results: 95 of the 96 institutional factor coefficients in Table 7, Table 8, Table 9 and Table 10 did not change in sign and significance (the only exception was that the coefficient of French-Civil in the regression of 10-Year Survival in Table 8 was no longer significant).

5.5. Limitation

Our results should be interpreted with caution, due to the possibility of sample selection bias. Our analysis restricts our sample to the world’s largest corporations (Fortune Global 500 companies), due to the availability of firm longevity data. If country-level institutional variables affect the probability of a firm becoming a global giant (being in the Fortune Global 500 list), then there could be biases in the estimated coefficients of the institutional variables in the profitability and longevity regressions. However, the directions of the biases are hard to be determined, because it is not easy to predict whether or not the institutional variables affect the probability of a firm being in the Fortune Global 500, and, if they do, whether they have a positive or negative effect. For example, it may be possible that firms in high-uncertainty-avoidance countries are less likely to enter the Fortune Global 500 list newly because they manage less aggressively and are slower to grow. However, it could also be that, once they join the Fortune Global 500, they are more likely to stay on the list because they are more operationally stable than firms in low-uncertainty-avoidance countries. Therefore, it is difficult to determine whether the coefficient estimates of the institutional variables suffer from sample selection bias and, if they do, in which direction. This is a limitation of our regression analyses.

6. Conclusions

Using the data of firms listed in the Fortune Global 500 from 1973 to 2020, this study compares the performance of the world’s largest companies across 47 countries. We found significant cross-country differences in both a firm’s profitability and longevity. For example, companies in the U.S. and the U.K., where shareholder-oriented companies are seen as dominant, have high profitability but low longevity. Conversely, French, German, and Japanese companies, which are considered to be dominated by stakeholder-oriented companies, have low profitability but high longevity. These findings are consistent with the previous literature arguing that the purpose of Anglo-Saxon companies is to maximize shareholder value, and that of continental European and Asian companies is to create value for various stakeholders [10,11,12,13,14,15,16,17,18].
We also found that country-level institutional factors, such as financial systems, laws, and national cultures, are significantly related to a firm’s profitability and longevity. First, a market-based (bank-based) financial system is positively (negatively) related to a firm’s profitability, but negatively (positively) related to its longevity. Second, a common law (civil law) origin is positively (negatively) related to the profitability of a firm, but negatively (positively) related to its longevity. Third, high individualism, low uncertainty avoidance and low long-term orientation are positively related to profitability, but negatively related to longevity. These findings are consistent with empirical evidence provided by previous studies, indicating that financial systems, laws, and national cultures are related to a firm’s risk-taking behavior [19,20,21,42,54,55]. The findings of these prior studies and this paper suggest that a country’s formal and informal institutions affect a firm’s purpose, behavior, and performance. The results also imply that each country-level institutional factor provides an advantage in one dimension of corporate success, but a disadvantage in the other.
From a different perspective, we could argue that countries have varying definitions of “corporate success.” In shareholder-oriented countries, there is an expectation that high corporate profitability will lead to increased shareholder returns. Demanding high profitability from a company encourages high-risk management; it may reduce a firm’s longevity and undermine the welfare of stakeholders. That being said, within shareholder-oriented countries, corporate profitability is considered more important than longevity, and high profitability is regarded as corporate success. On the other hand, in stakeholder-oriented countries, companies tend to survive for a long time to safeguard the welfare of various stakeholders. Several authors argue that corporate longevity may not be desirable from the standpoint of corporate profitability and economic efficiency, as it may result in the emergence of zombie companies [56,57,58]. However, in stakeholder-oriented countries, corporate longevity is considered more important than profitability and a company’s greater longevity is deemed as corporate success [6]. The difference in the definition of corporate success between shareholder-oriented and stakeholder-oriented countries may reflect the differences in corporate purposes, which arise from differences in the institutional environments of each country, such as the financial systems, labor markets, laws, and national cultures.
Our findings add new insights to corporate governance reforms that have been pursued since the late 1990s in stakeholder-oriented economies such as Germany and Japan. The governance reforms are generally aimed at spreading a shareholder value orientation among firms through changes in laws and financial systems. (For example, Germany enacted three Financial Market Promotion Laws in the 1990s and the Corporate Governance Code in 2002 with the aim of making the stock market more attractive to investors. Japan also enacted the Corporate Governance Code in 2015). Based on the evidence of the institutional effects presented in this paper, we posit that the reform is expected to have both positive and negative impacts on stakeholder-oriented firms. One consequence is that it raises their profitability; the other is that it shortens their longevity. While the former may increase shareholders’ returns, the latter may hinder long-term value creation for other stakeholders. We claim that we must also consider this latter negative impact when introducing shareholder-oriented corporate governance into stakeholder-oriented economies.
However, the evidence of significant correlations between national culture and corporate performance suggests that shareholder-oriented governance reforms may have a limited impact on firm performance. Hofstede [49] and Williamson [40] argue that national culture rarely changes in a few decades. Given their arguments, even if governance reforms change formal institutions—laws and financial systems—in a country, corporate performance will be determined, to some extent, by informal institutions—national cultures—which are difficult to change. Then, we can predict that cross-country differences in corporate performance will persist even with corporate governance reforms.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, R.A. and S.H.; methodology, S.H.; formal analysis, S.H.; investigation, R.A. and S.H.; writing—original draft preparation, S.H.; writing—review and editing, R.A. and S.H.; funding acquisition, S.H. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

Financial support from JSPS KAKENHI (Grant Numbers 26590052, 17K03820, and 15H01958; Hirota) is gratefully acknowledged.

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

Not applicable.

Acknowledgments

We thank three anonymous reviewers, Kotaro Inoue, Hajime Katayama, Katsuyuki Kubo, Makoto Nakano, Mitsuharu Miyamoto, Junichi Yamanoi, Alessandro Zattoni, and participants at the seminar at Development Bank of Japan, Free University Berlin, Hitotsubashi, MEW, Tokio Marine Research Institute, Waseda, NFA Annual Meetings, and the Meeting of the INCAS Project in Paris and Oxford for their helpful comments and advice.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Enacting Purpose Initiative. Enacting Purpose within the Modern Corporation: A Framework for Boards of Directors. 2020. Available online: https://enactingpurpose.org/assets/enacting-purpose-initiative---eu-report-august-2020.pdf (accessed on 20 August 2020).
  2. Enacting Purpose Initiative. Enacting Purpose Initiative Report #2: Directors & Investors: Building on Common Ground to Advance Sustainable Capitalism. 2021. Available online: https://enactingpurpose.org/assets/epi-report-final.pdf (accessed on 1 March 2023).
  3. Ricart, J.E.; Rey, C. Purpose in Corporate Governance: The Path towards a More Sustainable World. Sustainability 2022, 14, 4384. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Sjafjell, B. Sustainable Value Creation Within Planetary Boundaries: Reforming Corporate Purpose and Duties of the Corporate Board. Sustainability 2020, 12, 6245. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Hofstede, G.; Van Deusen, C.A.; Muller, C.B.; Charles, T.A. What Goals Do Business Leaders Pursue? A Study in Fifteen Countries. J. Int. Bus. Stud. 2002, 33, 785–803. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Mayer, C. Firm Commitment: Why the Corporation Is Failing Us and How to Restore Trust in It; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 2013. [Google Scholar]
  7. Mayer, C. Prosperity: Better Business Makes the Greater Good; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 2018. [Google Scholar]
  8. Mayer, C.; Wright, M.; Phan, P. Management Research and the Future of the Corporation: A New Agenda. Acad. Manag. Perspect. 2017, 31, 179–182. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Mitchell, R.K.; Weaver, G.R.; Age, B.R.; Bailey, A.D.; Carlson, J. Stakeholder Agency and Social Welfare: Pluralism and Decision Making in the Multi-Objective Corporation. Acad. Manag. Rev. 2016, 41, 252–275. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Aguilera, R.V.; Jackson, G. The Cross-National Diversity of Corporate Governance: Dimensions and Determinants. Acad. Manag. Rev. 2003, 28, 447–465. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Hirota, S. Corporate Finance and Governance in Stakeholder Society: Beyond Shareholder Capitalism; Routledge: London, UK, 2015. [Google Scholar]
  12. Kang, N.; Moon, J. Institutional Complementarity between Corporate Governance and Corporate Social Responsibility: A Comparative Institutional Analysis of Three Capitalisms. Socio-Econ. Rev. 2012, 10, 85–108. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Tirole, J. Corporate Governance. Econometrica 2001, 69, 1–35. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Witt, M.A.; Stahl, G.K. Foundations of Responsible Leadership: Asian versus Western Executive Responsibility Orientations toward Key Stakeholders. J. Bus. Ethics 2016, 136, 623–638. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Amble, B. The Diversity of Modern Capitalism; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 2003. [Google Scholar]
  16. Fiss, P.C.; Zajac, E.J. The Diffusion of Ideas over Contested Terrain: The (Non)adaption of a Shareholder Value Orientation among German Firms. Adm. Sci. Q. 2004, 49, 501–534. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Yoshimori, M. Whose Company Is It? The Concept of the Corporation in Japan and the West. Long Range Plan. 1995, 28, 33–44. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Witt, M.A.; Redding, G. The Spirits of Corporate Social Responsibility: Senior Executive Perceptions of the Role of the Firm in Society in Germany, Hong Kong, Japan, South Korea and the USA. Socio-Econ. Rev. 2012, 10, 109–134. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. John, K.; Litov, L.; Yeung, B. Corporate Governance and Risk-Taking. J. Financ. 2008, 58, 1679–1728. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Li, K.; Griffin, D.; Yue, H.; Zhao, L. How Does Culture Influence Corporate Risk-Taking? J. Corp. Financ. 2013, 23, 1–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Mihet, R. Effects of Culture on Firm Risk-Taking: A Cross-Country and Cross-Industry Analysis. J. Cult. Econ. 2013, 37, 109–151. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Shao, L.; Kwok, C.C.Y.; Zhang, R. National Culture and Corporate Investment. J. Int. Bus. Stud. 2013, 44, 745–763. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Chui, A.C.W.; Lloyd, A.E.; Kwok, C.C.Y. The Determination of Capital Structure: Is National Culture a Missing Piece to the Puzzle? J. Int. Bus. Stud. 2002, 33, 99–127. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. De Jong, A.; Kabir, R.; Nguyen, T.T. Capital Structure around the World: The Roles of Firm- and Country-Specific Determinants. J. Bank. Financ. 2008, 32, 1954–1969. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Fan, J.P.H.; Titman, S.; Twite, G. An International Comparison of Capital Structure and Debt Maturity Choices. J. Financ. Quant. Anal. 2012, 47, 23–56. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Zheng, X.; Ghoul, S.E.; Guedhami, O.; Kwok, C.C.Y. National Culture and Corporate Debt Maturity. J. Bank. Financ. 2012, 36, 468–488. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. La Porta, R.; Lopez-de-Silanes, F.; Shleifer, A.; Vishny, R. Agency Problem and Dividend Policies around the World. J. Financ. 2000, 55, 1–33. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Shao, L.; Kwok, C.C.Y.; Guedhami, O. National Culture and Dividend Policy. J. Int. Bus. Stud. 2010, 41, 1391–1414. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Chen, Y.; Dou, P.Y.; Rhee, S.G.; Truong, C.; Veeraraghavan, M. National Culture and Corporate Cash Holdings around the World. J. Bank. Financ. 2015, 50, 1–18. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Ramirez, A.; Tadesse, S. Corporate Cash Holdings, Uncertainty Avoidance, and the Multinationality of Firms. Int. Bus. Rev. 2009, 18, 387–403. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Rossi, S.; Volpin, P.F. Cross-Country Determinants of Mergers and Acquisitions. J. Financ. Econ. 2004, 74, 277–304. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Espenlaub, S.; Goyal, A.; Mohamed, A. Impact of Legal Institutions on IPO Survival: A Global Perspective. J. Financ. Stab. 2016, 25, 98–112. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. La Porta, R.; Lopez-de-Silanes, F.; Shleifer, A.; Vishny, R. Investor Protection and Corporate Valuation. J. Financ. 2002, 57, 1147–1170. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Liang, H.; Renneboog, L. On the Foundations of Corporate Social Responsibility. J. Financ. 2017, 72, 853–909. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Zingales, L. In Search of New Foundations. J. Financ. 2000, 55, 1623–1653. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Shleifer, A.; Summers, L. Breach of Trust in Hostile Takeovers. In Corporate Takeovers: Causes and Consequences; Auerbach, A.J., Ed.; University of Chicago Press: Chicago, IL, USA, 1988. [Google Scholar]
  37. Yoshikawa, T.; Tsui-Auch, L.S.; McGuire, J. Corporate Governance Reform as Institutional Innovation: The Case of Japan. Organ. Sci. 2007, 18, 973–988. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Greif, A. Institutions and the Path to the Modern Economy: Lessons from Medieval Trade; Cambridge University Press: New York, NY, USA, 2006. [Google Scholar]
  39. North, D.C. Institutions. J. Econ. Perspect. 1991, 5, 97–112. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Williamson, O.E. The New Institutional Economics: Taking Stock, Looking Ahead. J. Econ. Lit. 2000, 38, 595–613. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Demirguc-Kunt, A.; Levine, R. Bank-based and Market-based Financial Systems: Cross-Country Comparisons. In Financial Structure and Economic Growth: A Cross-Country Comparison of Banks, Markets, and Development; Demirguc-Kunt, A., Levine, R., Eds.; The MIT Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2001. [Google Scholar]
  42. Sakawa, H.; Watanabel, N. Main Bank Relationships and Risk Taking in Japanese Listed Firms. Appl. Econ. 2021, 53, 996–1012. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. La Porta, R.; Lopez-de-Silanes, F.; Shleifer, A.; Vishny, R. Law and Finance. J. Political Econ. 1998, 106, 1113–1155. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Ahern, K.R.; Daminelli, D.; Fracassi, C. Lost in Translation? The Effect of Culture Values on Mergers around the World. J. Financ. Econ. 2015, 117, 165–189. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Hope, O. Firm-Level Disclosures and the Relative Roles of Culture and Origin. J. Int. Financ. Manag. Account. 2003, 14, 218–248. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Kanagaretnam, K.; Lim, C.Y.; Lobo, G.J. Effects of National Culture on Earnings Quality of Banks. J. Int. Bus. Studies 2011, 42, 853–874. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Kanagaretnam, K.; Lim, C.Y.; Lobo, G.J. Influence of National Culture on Accounting Conservatism and Risk-Taking in the Banking Industry. Account. Rev. 2014, 89, 1115–1149. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Zingales, L. The “Cultural Revolution” in Finance. J. Financ. Econ. 2015, 117, 1–4. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Hofstede, G. Culture’s Consequences, 2nd ed.; SAGE Publications: Thousand Oaks, CA, USA, 2001. [Google Scholar]
  50. Hofstede, G.; Hofstede, G.J.; Minkov, M. Cultures and Organizations: Software of the Mind; McGraw-Hill: New York, NY, USA, 2010. [Google Scholar]
  51. Angrist, J.D.; Pischke, J. Mostly Harmless Econometrics: An Empiricist’s Companion; Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ, USA, 2009. [Google Scholar]
  52. Doidge, C.; Karolyi, G.A.; Stulz, R.M. Why Do Countries Matter So Much for Corporate Governance? J. Financ. Econ. 2007, 86, 1–39. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Petersen, M.A. Estimating Standard Errors in Finance Panel data Sets: Comparing Approaches. Rev. Financ. Stud. 2009, 22, 435–480. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Sakawa, H.; Watanabel, N. Institutional Ownership and Firm Performance under Stakeholder-Oriented Corporate Governance. Sustainability 2020, 12, 1021. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Sakawa, H.; Watanabel, N.; Duppati, G.; Faff, R. Institutional Ownership and Corporate Risk-Taking in Japanese Listed Firms. Appl. Econ. 2021, 53, 1899–1914. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Acharya, V.V.; Crosignani, M.; Eisert, T.; Steffen, S. Zombie Lending: Theoretical, International, and Historical Perspectives. Annu. Rev. Financ. Econ. 2022, 14, 21–38. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Alvarez, L.; Garcia-Posada, M.; Mayordomo, S. Distressed Firms, Zombie Firms and Zombie Lending: A Taxonomy. J. Bank. Financ. 2023, 149, 106762. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Caballero, R.J.T.; Hoshi, T.; Kashyap, A.K. Zombie Lending and Depressed Restructuring in Japan. Am. Econ. Rev. 2008, 98, 1943–1977. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Table 1. Sample Firms.
Table 1. Sample Firms.
CountryNo. of
Firm-Year
Observations
N
(No. of Firm
Observations)
IndustryNo. of
Firm-Year
Observations
N
(No. of Firm Observations)YearNo. of
Observations
Algeria2(1)Mining, Crude-Oil Production (SIC10)452(38)1973479
Argentina17(1)Engineering and Construction (SIC 15)259(28)1974 492
Australia207(19)Food and Beverages (SIC20)1611(127)1975 495
Austria52(6)Tobacco (SIC 21)229(18)1976 495
Belgium136(11)Texitiles (SIC 22)172(14)1977 495
Brazil101(9)Apparel (SIC 23)89(7)1978 495
Canada495(48)Forest and Paper Products (SIC 24)526(49)1979 496
Chile18(3)Furniture (SIC 25)6(1)1980 496
Colombia9(2)Publishing, Printing (SIC 27)220(16)1981 497
Denmark18(1)Chemicals and Phrmaceuticals (SIC 28)2154(126)1982 496
Egypt2(1)Petroleum Refining (SIC 29)2180(135)1983 497
Finland94(10)Rubber and Plastic Products (SIC 30)213(20)1984 497
France1323(82)Leather (SIC 31)3(1)1985 496
Germany1432(82)Building Materials, Glass (SIC 32)365(31)1986 496
Iran6(1)Metals (SIC 33)1187(88)1987 496
India188(11)Metal Products (SIC 34)332(29)1988 496
Indonesia15(2)Industrial and Commercial Machinery (SIC 35)1277(90)1989 496
Ireland26(2)Electronics, Electrical Equipment (SIC 36)1512(84)1990 497
Israel17(3)Transportation Equipment (SIC 37)2326(121)1991 498
Italy282(25)Scientific and Control Equipment (SIC 38)174(14)1992 499
Japan3469(212)Miscellaneous Manufacturintg Industries (SIC 39)27(5)1993 496
Kuwait13(1)Railroads (SIC 40)125(8)1994 372
Luxembourg33(1)Mail, Package, and Freight Delivery (SIC 43)188(10)1995 364
Malaysia32(1)Shipping (SIC 44)41(5)1996 358
Mexico98(9)Airlines (SIC 45)182(10)1997 365
Netherlands314(25)Communications (SIC 48)753(58)1998 369
New Zealand11(1)Utilities (SIC 49)675(70)1999 362
Norway77(5)Wholesale Trade (SIC 50)596(49)2000 373
Panama6(1)Retail Trade (SIC 52)248(28)2001 369
Philippines5(1)General Merchandisers (SIC 53)246(19)2002 369
Portugal14(4)Food and Drug Stores (SIC 54)608(43)2003 366
Saudi Arabia19(2)Food Services (SIC 58)65(4)2004 364
Singapore40(3)Real Estate (SIC 65)7(1)2005 364
South Africa53(6)Hotels, Casinos, Resorts (SIC 70)17(4)2006 359
South Korea462(35)Business Services (SIC 73)123(8)2007 347
Spain231(23)Health Services (SIC 80)210(16)2008 355
Sweden313(30)Social Services (SIC 83)43(5)2009 339
Switzerland407(22)Miscellaneous57(4)2010 332
Taiwan122(12) 2011 327
Thailand21(1) 2012 310
Turkey73(4) 2013 307
United Arab Emirates8(2) 2014 306
U.K.1560(122) 2015301
U.S.7624(538) 2016295
Venezuela35(1) 2017291
Zaire1(1) 2018285
Zambia17(1) 2019277
2020272
Total19,498(1384)Total19,498(1384)Total19,498
Table 2. Profitability and Longevity: Cross-Country Comparison.
Table 2. Profitability and Longevity: Cross-Country Comparison.
ProfitabilityLongevity
ROS
(Median)
ROA
(Median)
ROE
(Median)
10-Year
Survival Rate
20-Year
Survival Rate
30-Year
Survival Rate
N%N%N%N%N%N%
Panel A: Full Sample
19,2763.18 19,2363.57 18,91311.21 15,92287.6 12,36873.6 834659.8
Panel B: Country
Australia2054.20 2055.05 20411.90 16587.3 12175.2 6373.0
Belgium1362.33 1362.81 13510.07 10889.8 9278.3 6672.7
Canada4954.22 4944.56 48611.92 33884.6 27050.7 21527.0
France13052.39 12942.06 12749.54 104493.8 74784.2 45572.3
Germany14061.68 14062.17 14039.12 112189.2 85571.5 56153.6
India1833.04 1834.75 18314.48 12596.8 75100.0 5592.7
Italy2651.52 2500.93 2536.16 21875.2 16460.4 11253.6
Japan34671.62 34671.53 34486.72 302997.4 241794.7 139092.4
Netherlands3092.56 3092.90 30512.87 22396.4 13489.6 8577.6
South Korea4541.50 4541.74 4517.15 32290.7 21680.6 11477.2
Spain2313.96 2312.88 23112.50 17379.2 11260.7 7926.6
Sweden3122.74 3122.71 31011.71 27390.1 22881.1 16878.0
Switzerland3944.02 3924.03 3909.80 30993.5 23290.5 15783.4
Taiwan1222.43 1223.98 12211.74 60100.0 26100.0 17100.0
U.K.15534.20 15494.56 151613.04 133584.6 111062.8 82542.4
U.S.75314.46 75295.69 733614.29 639381.2 506062.5 362947.2
ROS is the return on sales; ROA is the return on assets; ROE is the return on equity. The 10-year, 20-year, and 30-year survival rates are the proportions of firms that survive for the subsequent 10, 20, and 30 years, respectively.
Table 3. Industry Effect or Country Effect?
Table 3. Industry Effect or Country Effect?
Dependent
Variable
ROA10-Year Survival
(1 or 0)
Model 1Model 2Model 3Model 4
Industry dummiesyes yes
Country Dummies yes yes
Year dummiesyesyesyesyes
Adjusted R2/Pseudo R20.1340.1920.0460.084
N18,85018,85015,69315,476
ROA regressions (Models 1 and 2) are estimated by OLS, and 10-year survival regressions (Models 3 and 4) are estimated by the probit model (maximum likelihood method).
Table 4. Country’s Institutional Environments.
Table 4. Country’s Institutional Environments.
CountryFinancial SystemLawNational Culture
Financial SystemLegal OriginIndividualismUncertainty AvoidanceLong-Term Orientation
Algeria
ArgentinaBank-basedCivil/French468620
AustraliaMarket-basedCommon905121
AustriaBank-basedCivil/German557060
BelgiumBank-basedCivil/French759582
BrazilMarket-basedCivil/French387644
CanadaMarket-basedCommon804836
ChileMarket-basedCivil/French238631
ColombiaBank-basedCivil/French138013
DenmarkMarket-basedCivil/Scandinavian742335
EgyptBank-basedCivil/French38687
FinlandBank-basedCivil/Scandinavian635938
FranceBank-basedCivil/French718663
GermanyBank-basedCivil/German676583
Iran 415914
IndiaBank-basedCommon484051
IndonesiaBank-basedCivil/French144862
IrelandBank-basedCommon703524
IsraelBank-basedCommon548138
ItalyBank-basedCivil/French767561
JapanBank-basedCivil/German469288
Kuwait Civil/French3868
Luxembourg Civil/French607064
MalaysiaMarket-basedCommon263641
MexicoMarket-basedCivil/French308224
NetherlandsMarket-basedCivil/French805367
New ZealandBank-basedCommon794933
NorwayBank-basedCivil/Scandinavian695035
PanamaBank-basedCivil/French1186
PhilippinesMarket-basedCivil/French324427
PortugalBank-basedCivil/French2710428
Saudi Arabia Common386836
SingaporeMarket-basedCommon20872
South AfricaMarket-basedCommon654934
South KoreaMarket-basedCivil/German1885100
SpainBank-basedCivil/French518648
SwedenMarket-basedCivil/Scandinavian712953
SwitzerlandMarket-basedCivil/German66.56474
Taiwan Civil/German176993
ThailandMarket-basedCommon206432
TurkeyMarket-basedCivil/French378546
United Arab Emirates 3868
U.K.Market-basedCommon893551
U.S.Market-basedCommon914626
VenezuelaBank-basedCivil/French127616
Zaire Civil/French
Zambia Common275230
Whether the country has a market-based or bank-based financial system is determined according to Demirguc-Kunt and Levine [41]. Whether it is a common law or civil law country is determined according to La Porta et al. [43]. The Individualism, Uncertainty Avoidance, and Long-Term Orientation indices are from Hofstede [49] and Hofstede et al. [50].
Table 5. Profitability and Longevity: Comparison by Country-Level Institutional Factors.
Table 5. Profitability and Longevity: Comparison by Country-Level Institutional Factors.
ProfitabilityLongevity
ROS (Mean)ROA (Mean)ROE (Mean)10-Year Survival Rate20-Year Survival Rate30-Year Survival Rate
N%N%N%N%N%N%
Panel A: Financial System
(A) Market-based11,4114.91 11,3685.23 10,17713.19 967883.6 759465.6 541250.3
(B) Bank-based72812.39 72802.14 66448.89 612493.9 470286.6 287977.8
Difference (A)−(B) 2.52 *** 3.09 *** 4.30 *** −10.3 *** −21.0 *** −27.5 ***
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
Panel B: Law
(A) Common law99385.07 99015.51 10,17713.67 851682.3 674962.9 487146.3
(B) Civil law89432.66 89402.38 66449.12 740693.6 561986.5 347578.7
Difference (A)−(B) 2.41 *** 3.13 *** 4.55 *** −11.3 *** −23.6 *** −32.4 ***
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
Panel C1: Individualism (IDV)
(A) IDV > 4614,3824.37 14,3284.57 12,83812.60 12,13684.7 944067.5 663251.7
(B) IDV <= 4645072.49 45212.30 41818.10 378596.6 292793.4 171391.1
Difference (A)−(B) 1.88 *** 2.27 *** 4.50 *** −11.9 *** −25.9 *** −39.4 ***
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
Panel C2: Uncertainty Avoidance (UA)
(A) UA > 6863402.48 63472.15 57588.53 531294.4 404989.2 243683.1
(B) UA <= 6812,5494.66 12,5024.98 11,26113.01 10,60984.2 831866.0 590950.2
Difference (A)−(B) −2.18 *** −2.83 *** −4.48 *** 10.2 *** 23.2 *** 32.9 ***
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
Panel C3: Long-Term Orientation (LTO)
(A) LTO > 3810,3072.97 10,3102.78 93659.71 856792.1 657182.2 420471.0
(B) LTO <= 3885565.08 85155.54 763113.69 733582.3 577763.7 412548.2
Difference (A)−(B) −2.11 *** −2.76 *** −3.98 *** 9.8 *** 18.5 *** 22.8 ***
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
*** indicates that the difference is significant at the 1% level. Figures in parentheses are p-values. IDV, UA, LTO are the individualism, uncertainty avoidance, and long-term orientation indices, respectively (Hofstede [49]; Hofstede et al. [50]).
Table 6. Summary Statistics of the Regression Variables.
Table 6. Summary Statistics of the Regression Variables.
NMeanStdMinimumMaximum
Dependent variables
ROS (%)18,8903.9254.897−13.54224.931
ROA (%)18,8504.0254.383−12.87118.896
ROE (%)17,02011.4938.196−12.81133.953
10-Year Survival15,9220.8760.33001
20-Year Survival12,3680.7360.44101
30-Year Survival83460.5980.49001
Country-level institutional variables
Market-based19,2770.6140.48701
Market-cap/GDP (%)17,71372.57945.0590.023345.353
Bank credit/GDP (%)16,80880.11842.6273.189201.256
Common19,4820.5290.49901
French civil19,4820.1400.34701
German civil19,4820.3050.46001
Scandinavian civil19,4820.0260.15801
Individualism19,49572.75621.1211191
Uncertainty avoidance19,49560.82820.8848104
Long-term orientation19,47052.21926.3687100
Country-level control variables
GDP growth (annual; %)18,9282.5382.524−12.91224.370
GDP growth (10-year; annual; %)16,0002.4801.228−4.31110.369
GDP growth (20-year; annual; %)12,4762.4881.015−1.9569.016
GDP growth (30-year; annual; %)84732.4910.818−0.2627.702
GDP capita (US dollars)18,90534,42613,299349108,351
Firm-level control variables
Size (total assets; million US dollars)19,39627,80271,40517,249,934
Firm age (years)18,84476.00250.9710530
Table 7. Financial System and Corporate Performance.
Table 7. Financial System and Corporate Performance.
ProfitabilityLongevity
Dependent VariableROSROAROE10-Year Survival20-Year Survival30-Year Survival
Market-based2.576 ***
(0.000)
2.830 ***
(0.000)
4.196 ***
(0.000)
−0.083 ***
(0.000)
−0.168 ***
(0.000)
−0.239 ***
(0.000)
Market-cap/GDP 0.021 ***
(0.000)
0.018 ***
(0.000)
0.025 ***
(0.000)
−0.000
(0.156)
−0.001
(0.203)
−0.005 ***
(0.000)
Bank credit/GDP −0.017 ***
(0.000)
−0.021 ***
(0.000)
−0.047 ***
(0.000)
0.001 ***
(0.000)
0.002 ***
(0.000)
0.005 ***
(0.000)
GDP growth0.146 ***
(0.000)
0.109 ***
(0.013)
0.116 ***
(0.000)
0.088 **
(0.017)
0.352 ***
(0.000)
0.319 ***
(0.000)
0.006
(0.403)
0.005 ***
(0.513)
0.008
(0.694)
−0.010
(0.681)
0.027
(0.418)
−0.023
(0.522)
ln GDP capita−0.132
(0.600)
0.241
(0.427)
−0.114
(0.603)
0.436 *
(0.068)
−0.007
(0.988)
1.022 **
(0.011)
−0.065 ***
(0.002)
−0.076 ***
(0.004)
−0.165 ***
(0.000)
−0.216 ***
(0.000)
−0.167 ***
(0.002)
−0.247 ***
(0.000)
ln Size0.791 ***
(0.000)
0.861 ***
(0.000)
−0.206 **
(0.027)
−0.190 *
(0.068)
−0.283 *
(0.075)
−0.188
(0.285)
0.047 ***
(0.000)
0.055 ***
(0.000)
0.062 ***
(0.000)
0.065 ***
(0.000)
0.071 ***
(0.001)
0.070 ***
(0.004)
ln Age0.194
(0.107)
0.124
(0.368)
0.306 ***
(0.002)
0.190 *
(0.100)
0.303 *
(0.083)
0.177
(0.402)
0.034 ***
(0.000)
0.031 ***
(0.001)
0.071 ***
(0.000)
0.063 ***
(0.001)
0.101 ***
(0.000)
0.082 ***
(0.003)
Industry dummiesyesyesyesyesyesyesyesyesyesyesyesyes
Year dummiesyesyesyesyesyesyesyesyesyesyesyesyes
N17,69614,38217,70314,37415,96712,98815,07611,98211,714866978685616
Adj.R2/Psd R20.2580.2530.2410.2170.1590.1760.1120.1290.1270.1450.1390.181
The table reports OLS estimates for profitability regressions and probit (maximum likelihood) estimates (average marginal effects) for longevity regressions. ***, **, and * indicate that coefficients are significant at the 1, 5, and 10% levels, respectively. Figures in parentheses are p-values calculated using standard errors clustered by firm. GDP growth is the GDP growth rate for the year in the profitability regressions; it is the GDP growth rate per year for the subsequent 10, 20, and 30 years in the longevity regressions.
Table 8. Law and Corporate Performance.
Table 8. Law and Corporate Performance.
ProfitabilityLongevity
Dependent VariableROSROAROE10-Year Survival20-Year Survival30-Year Survival
Common2.527 ***
(0.000)
2.871 ***
(0.000)
4.426 ***
(0.000)
−0.096 ***
(0.000)
−0.217 ***
(0.000)
−0.305 ***
(0.000)
French-civil −2.279 ***
(0.000)
−2.685 ***
(0.000)
−3.090 ***
(0.000)
0.047 **
(0.045)
0.145 ***
(0.001)
0.209 ***
(0.000)
German-civil −2.739 ***
(0.000)
−3.048 ***
(0.000)
−5.268 ***
(0.000)
0.114 ***
(0.000)
0.242 ***
(0.000)
0.328 ***
(0.000)
Scandinavian-civil −1.502 ***
(0.000)
−1.933 ***
(0.000)
−1.461 **
(0.018)
0.133 ***
(0.007)
0.266 ***
(0.002)
0.412 ***
(0.000)
GDP growth0.188 ***
(0.000)
0.196 ***
(0.000)
0.154 ***
(0.000)
0.160 ***
(0.000)
0.412 ***
(0.000)
0.441 ***
(0.000)
0.007
(0.408)
0.006
(0.489)
0.018
(0.394)
0.020
(0.407)
0.045
(0.182)
0.043
(0.227)
ln GDP capita0.045
(0.846)
0.025
(0.913)
0.065
(0.684)
0.045
(0.774)
0.315
(0.278)
0.275
(0.331)
−0.051 ***
(0.001)
−0.056 ***
(0.001)
−0.098 ***
(0.001)
−0.103 ***
(0.001)
−0.105 ***
(0.006)
−0.114 ***
(0.003)
ln Size0.823 ***
(0.000)
0.828 ***
(0.000)
−0.168 *
(0.066)
−0.164 *
(0.077)
−0.217
(0.155)
−0.223
(0.144)
0.046 ***
(0.000)
0.047 ***
(0.000)
0.058 ***
(0.000)
0.061 ***
(0.000)
0.064 ***
(0.002)
0.068 ***
(0.001)
ln Age0.169
(0.147)
0.183
(0.116)
0.285 ***
(0.003)
0.297 ***
(0.002)
0.289 *
(0.094)
0.336 **
(0.046)
0.036 ***
(0.000)
0.034 ***
(0.000)
0.074 ***
(0.000)
0.070 ***
(0.000)
0.107 ***
(0.000)
0.102 ***
(0.000)
Industry dummiesyesyesyesyesyesyesyesyesyesyesyesyes
Year dummiesyesyesyesyesyesyesyesyesyesyesyesyes
N17,76117,76117,76917,76916,02816,02815,12115,12111,74511,74578917891
Adj.R2/Psd R20.2620.2640.2510.2530.1710.1810.1180.1220.1370.1410.1570.162
The table reports OLS estimates for profitability regressions and probit (maximum likelihood) estimates (average marginal effects) for longevity regressions. ***, **, and * indicate that coefficients are significant at the 1, 5, and 10% levels, respectively. Figures in parentheses are p-values calculated using standard errors clustered by firm. GDP growth is the GDP growth rate for the year in the profitability regressions; it is the GDP growth rate per year for the subsequent 10, 20, and 30 years in the longevity regressions.
Table 9. National Culture and Profitability.
Table 9. National Culture and Profitability.
Profitability
Dependent VariableROSROAROE
Individualism0.059 ***
(0.000)
0.068 ***
(0.000)
0.131 ***
(0.000)
Uncertainty avoidance −0.052 ***
(0.000)
−0.059 ***
(0.000)
−0.104 ***
(0.000)
Long-term orientation −0.047 ***
(0.000)
−0.054 ***
(0.000)
−0.092 ***
(0.000)
GDP growth0.291 ***
(0.000)
0.236 ***
(0.000)
0.215 ***
(0.000)
0.271 ***
(0.000)
0.207 ***
(0.000)
0.185 ***
(0.000)
0.600 ***
(0.000)
0.479 ***
(0.000)
0.440 ***
(0.000)
ln GDP capita−0.579 **
(0.026)
0.103
(0.651)
−0.049
(0.838)
−0.670 ***
(0.000)
0.134
(0.392)
−0.045
(0.796)
−1.378 ***
(0.000)
0.257
(0.341)
−0.127
(0.682)
ln Size0.745 ***
(0.000)
0.818 ***
(0.000)
0.770 ***
(0.000)
−0.256 ***
(0.007)
−0.176 *
(0.063)
−0.229 **
(0.014)
−0.317 **
(0.037)
−0.199
(0.203)
−0.278 *
(0.065)
ln Age0.053
(0.667)
0.106
(0.386)
0.186
(0.118)
0.153
(0.138)
0.214 **
(0.031)
0.305 ***
(0.002)
0.061
(0.721)
0.202
(0.234)
0.325 *
(0.054)
Industry dummiesyesyesyesyesyesyesyesyesyes
Year dummiesyesyesyesyesyesyesyesyesyes
N17,76017,76017,75417,76817,76817,76216,02716,02716,023
Adjusted R20.2470.2510.2600.2230.2330.2490.1800.1730.182
The table reports OLS estimates. ***, **, and * indicate that coefficients are significant at the 1, 5, and 10% levels, respectively. Figures in parentheses are p-values calculated using standard errors clustered by firm. GDP growth is the GDP growth rate for the year.
Table 10. National Culture and Longevity.
Table 10. National Culture and Longevity.
Longevity
Dependent Variable10-Year Survival20-Year Survival30-Year Survival
Individualism−0.003 ***
(0.000)
−0.007 ***
(0.000)
−0.010 ***
(0.000)
Uncertainty avoidance 0.002 ***
(0.000)
0.005 ***
(0.000)
0.007 ***
(0.000)
Long-term orientation 0.002 ***
(0.000)
0.004 ***
(0.000)
0005 ***
(0.000)
GDP growth0.001
(0.927)
−0.000
(0.977)
0.005
(0.557)
0.011
(0.695)
−0.000
(0.989)
0.012
(0.649)
0.031
(0.442)
0.004
(0.887)
0.025
(0.509)
ln GDP capita−0.004
(0.826)
−0.055 ***
(0.001)
−0.046 ***
(0.004)
0.010
(0.800)
−0.106 ***
(0.001)
−0.099 ***
(0.003)
0.039
(0.460)
−0.128 ***
(0.001)
−0.122 ***
(0.006)
ln Size0.047 ***
(0.000)
0.045 ***
(0.000)
0.047 ***
(0.000)
0.061 ***
(0.000)
0.057 ***
(0.000)
0.062 ***
(0.000)
0.069 ***
(0.001)
0.062 ***
(0.002)
0.069 ***
(0.001)
ln Age0.036 ***
(0.000)
0.035 ***
(0.000)
0.033 ***
(0.000)
0.073 ***
(0.000)
0.073 ***
(0.000)
0.067 ***
(0.000)
0.107 ***
(0.000)
0.107 ***
(0.000)
0.096 ***
(0.000)
Industry dummiesyesyesyesyesyesyesyesyesyes
Year dummiesyesyesyesyesyesyesyesyesyes
N15,12015,12015,11411,74411,74411,738789078907887
Pseudo R20.1250.1160.1170.1500.1370.1280.1750.1560.140
The table reports probit (maximum likelihood) estimates (average marginal effects). *** indicates that coefficients are significant at the 1% level. Figures in parentheses are p-values calculated using standard errors clustered by firm. GDP growth is the GDP growth rate per year for the subsequent 10, 20, and 30 years in the 10-, 20-, and 30-year survival regressions, respectively.
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Arai, R.; Hirota, S. Profitability or Longevity? Cross-Country Variations in Corporate Performance. Sustainability 2023, 15, 8307. https://doi.org/10.3390/su15108307

AMA Style

Arai R, Hirota S. Profitability or Longevity? Cross-Country Variations in Corporate Performance. Sustainability. 2023; 15(10):8307. https://doi.org/10.3390/su15108307

Chicago/Turabian Style

Arai, Ryoichi, and Shinichi Hirota. 2023. "Profitability or Longevity? Cross-Country Variations in Corporate Performance" Sustainability 15, no. 10: 8307. https://doi.org/10.3390/su15108307

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop