Next Article in Journal
Recycling of Tire Waste Using Pyrolysis: An Environmental Perspective
Previous Article in Journal
Your Sustainability Is Not My Sustainability: In-between Spaces for Meaningful Collaboration between Local Stakeholders and Planning Professionals to Construct Congruent Frames over Contested Meanings
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Discriminatory Pricing Strategy for Sustainable Tourism in Theme Parks considering Visitors’ Price Fairness and Service Value Perceptions

1
Department of Information Management and Decision Sciences, School of Business Administration, Northeastern University, Shenyang 110169, China
2
Institute of Behavioral and Service Operations Management, School of Business Administration, Northeastern University, Shenyang 110169, China
3
National Frontiers Science Center for Industrial Intelligence and Systems Optimization, Northeastern University, Shenyang 110819, China
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2023, 15(19), 14180; https://doi.org/10.3390/su151914180
Submission received: 18 August 2023 / Revised: 2 September 2023 / Accepted: 21 September 2023 / Published: 25 September 2023
(This article belongs to the Section Economic and Business Aspects of Sustainability)

Abstract

:
With the increase in carbon emissions in the tourism industry, more tourism enterprises need to make sustained investments in clean energy and green technologies. From the perspective of theme park revenue and operational management, such investments mainly come from admission fees and in-park consumption. The objective of this study is to discuss the role of discriminatory pricing strategies in supporting sustainable tourism in theme parks. Based on transaction utility theory and equity theory, visitors’ price fairness perception and service value perception are incorporated into the visitor utility function. On this basis, a goal-programming-based discriminatory pricing model with three goals is proposed: achieving the established revenue target, achieving distributed justice between visitors with unequal status (advantaged visitors and disadvantaged visitors), and achieving distributed justice between visitors and theme parks. The research results show that, for one thing, the proposed discriminatory pricing model can enable theme parks to secure sufficient funds to invest in low-carbon activities (Goal 1) while for another, visitors’ satisfaction, brand loyalty, and willingness to revisit and sustainably consume in theme parks are improved by the realization of distributed justice through the discriminatory pricing strategy (Goals 2 and 3).

1. Introduction

The number of tourists has risen sharply with the end of the COVID-19 pandemic and a gradual recovery of the global economy. The resurgence of tourism and its growing carbon footprint has brought renewed attention to the impact of the tourism industry on climate change [1,2]. Statistics (https://www3.weforum.org/docs/WEF_Ten_Principles_for_Sustainable_Destinations_2022.pdf, accessed on 30 July 2023) show that tourism contributed about 8% of the global greenhouse gas emissions in 2021. This makes more tourism enterprises want to use clean energy, green materials, and green technologies, and to implement carbon neutral and carbon offsetting technologies to eliminate the impact of their carbon footprints [3,4,5,6]. Some existing studies have indicated that in response to the national dual-carbon strategy and the requirements for sustainable tourism development, investment in carbon emission reduction activities can help theme parks cope with environment-related risks, reduce property operating costs, and lead to asset appreciation [7,8].
Tourists’ consumption attitudes have changed in recent years due to the impact of the COVID-19 pandemic and the global economic downturn; people are more careful with their money and personalized travel has become mainstream. A theme park is a commercially operated enterprise that offers rides, shows, merchandise, food services, and other forms of entertainment in a themed environment [9]. Because of its distinctive theme concept, unique sightseeing, and amusement environment, the theme park industry can fully meet the personalized tourism needs of visitors [10,11,12]. Statistics (https://baijiahao.baidu.com/s?id=1750267574438094487&wfr=spider&for=pc, accessed on 22 April 2023) show that the total number of visitors to 70 theme parks in China reached about 75 million in 2021. The market size of China’s theme park industry was about 30 billion RMB from 2020 to 2022, which represents only half of the peak market size in 2019 (https://baijiahao.baidu.com/s?id=1749259796291381713&wfr=spider&for=pc, accessed on 22 April 2023). In many international theme parks, 30% of the revenue comes from admission fees, 30% from retail, and 40% from food and accommodation. While admission fees are not the biggest source of revenue, visitors’ perceptions of admission fees largely determine whether they visit a theme park. A theme park ticket is a consumption contract between visitors and theme parks [13], thus visitors tend to associate the admission fee they pay with the touring experience they get from theme parks [14,15,16]. They expect the price they pay for their tickets to be commensurate with the quality of the service they receive. If visitors do not get the quality of service or touring experience they expect, they will question the ticket pricing strategy or the operational management level of theme parks, which will affect their willingness to revisit the theme parks and their willingness to spend extra money in theme parks [11,17,18]. In this case, the theme parks’ revenues will be greatly reduced and their sources of investments in clean energy and green technologies will be greatly affected. Therefore, in the context of a low-carbon tourism economy, the reasonable design of theme parks’ admission fees helps improve their revenue management (RM) ability and sustainable development ability. Once theme parks have sustainable funds, they can invest in low-carbon activities within the parks, including using clean energy and green technologies, renovating energy-efficient buildings, and improving the ecological environments of scenic spots.
RM refers to selling perishable services to the most profitable mix of customers to maximize revenue [19,20,21]. Similar to other industries that apply RM, the theme park industry has perishable capacity, high fixed and low variable costs, variable demand, and segmental markets [22]. In reality, most theme parks adopt various RM techniques based on visitors’ diverse characteristics, needs, or the status quo of the tourism market [11]. Discriminatory pricing strategy is one of the commonly used RM techniques [16,23]. Theme parks set different admission fees based on the payment ability and willingness of different visitors, so that all types of visitors can afford and are willing to pay the ticket price. In practice, there are many examples where discriminatory pricing strategies are applied in theme parks. For example, Shanghai Disneyland charges adults 719 yuan for one-day admission, while children, seniors, and people with disabilities are charged 539 yuan. Visitors can buy Shanghai Disneyland tickets at 672 yuan for adults and 500 yuan for children through TikTok. Shenyang Fangte Happy World charges 280 yuan for visitors arriving during the daytime and 199 yuan for visitors entering at night.
The purpose of implementing discriminatory pricing strategies for theme parks is to get visitor surplus in different market segments to increase the theme park’s revenue. In reality, visitors to the same theme park are charged different admission fees. Based on the equity theory [23,24,25], the visitors who get a discount on the admission fee are called advantaged visitors, and the visitors who buy tickets at the full price are called disadvantaged visitors; both are called visitors with unequal status [26]. From the visitor’s viewpoint, the admission fee is a proxy for service quality [27]. If the admission fees for theme parks are set too high or the discriminatory basis of the pricing strategy is unreasonable, the visitors’ service value perception will be low and they will perceive the price to be unfair, which will further lead to a decline in the number of visitors and a decline in the theme park’s revenue. From the viewpoint of sustainability and revenue maximization, the price fairness perception (PFP) and service value perception (SVP) of visitors can influence theme parks’ market demand and the achievement of revenue targets, which are key guarantees for theme parks to secure sustainable funds for investing in clean energy, green technologies, and other low-carbon activities [28]. Therefore, theme parks should focus on the PFP and SVP of visitors with unequal status [16].
Many scholars have studied the application of RM in theme parks [11,16,22,23,29,30]. The majority of existing studies have focused on exploring the factors that impact visitors’ satisfaction and theme parks’ revenues, such as the layout of recreation facilities, the number of themes, the types of rides, and waiting times. However, how to achieve an established revenue target and how to address visitors’ social welfare under the discriminatory pricing scheme have not been elucidated. In particular, with regard to where discrimination exists in the pricing strategies, studies have not differentiated the utilities of visitors with unequal status. To fill the above research gaps, this study aims to investigate the role of discriminatory pricing strategy in supporting sustainable tourism in theme parks. To solve this scientific problem, the following research questions are worth studying:
  • How can theme parks achieve an established revenue target from the perspective of sustainability and revenue maximization?
  • How can theme parks achieve distributed justice between their revenue and visitors’ social welfare in the long run?
  • How can theme parks formulate the utility functions of visitors based on PFP and SVP, and how can theme parks achieve distributed justice between visitors with unequal status?
In this study, the first research question is aimed at ensuring that theme parks secure stable revenue from admission fees and in-park consumption so that they have sufficient money for investment in low-carbon activities, including clean energy and green technologies. The second and third research questions are aimed at ensuring that theme parks maintain a sustainable relationship with their visitors and enhance the satisfaction and brand loyalty of visitors with unequal status.
This study is organized as follows. Related studies are presented in Section 2. In Section 3, the discriminatory pricing model is proposed based on equity theory, transaction utility theory, and the goal programming method, and a numerical example is introduced. In Section 4, some sensitivity analysis experiments are conducted based on factors such as the theme park’s established revenue target, the service homogeneity coefficient, and visitors’ average WTP. Some valuable managerial insights based on the sensitivity analysis results are discussed in Section 5. Finally, the conclusions, limitations, and future work are presented in Section 6.

2. Literature Review

2.1. Revenue Management and Discriminatory Pricing in Theme Parks

The earliest study focusing on discriminatory pricing of theme parks is by Oi [31]. He discussed a two-part tariff consisting of an admission fee and a per-ride fee. Braun et al. [32] proposed a theme park pricing model by investigating some basic conditions, market structures, and non-price activities. Heo and Lee [22] investigated the adoption of RM in theme parks. They suggested using time-based pricing and demand-based pricing instead of the current flat admission rate, discounts for specific visitors, or seasonal pricing promotions. Ko and Park [16] investigated some important factors that could maximize the theme park’s revenue in a dual admission policy. These factors are express admission tickets, the maximum allowed number of express admission tickets per day, and the type of rides that could be included in the express admission tickets. Choi et al. [33] found that theme park management might improve visitors’ perceptions of price fairness or appropriateness by adopting dynamic pricing. In addition, the parks should offer repeat customers some incentives, such as free passes, to attract price-conscious visitors. Chang et al. [28] found that young visitors with income were willing to buy fast-pass tickets and liked exciting amusement facilities. They suggested that theme parks should increase the number of exciting amusement facilities and improve the service performance of such facilities when designing fast-pass tickets.
So far, applying RM and discriminatory pricing strategies has been widely accepted and adopted in the theme park industry. However, from the viewpoint of sustainability and revenue maximization, achieving an established revenue target, maintaining a stable market demand, and concerns about visitors’ social welfare within theme parks have rarely been investigated. In particular, mathematical models for solving such problems are desperately needed.

2.2. Transaction Utility Theory, Equity Theory, and Price Fairness Perception in Theme Parks

Transaction utility theory states that people derive utility from the material consequences of exchange (acquisition utility) and the psychological aspects of the transaction (transaction utility) [34]. Acquisition utility depends on the value of the commodity received compared with the outlay. It is the net utility that accrues from the exchange of money to obtain the commodity. Comparatively, transaction utility depends solely on the price that one pays compared with a reference price [35]. The internal reference price is defined as the price or price scale in people’s memories that serves as a basis for judging or comparing the actual prices [36], or price anchors that people remember based on their previous purchase experiences or price beliefs [26]. The equity theory and the distributive justice principle suggest that PFP or price unfairness perception is induced when a person compares a price with a comparative other. When price discrepancies occur, the degree of transaction similarity and the choice of a comparative other become important elements when judging price fairness [25]. When the degree of transaction similarity (experience similarity in this study) is low, the contrast between the two transactions explains the price difference. As a result, people will judge the price discrepancy as fair or less unfair [25]. Wu et al. [26] found that the basis for discrimination in theme parks’ pricing schemes only influenced the perceived price unfairness among the advantaged visitors. The basis for discrimination included residence, channel through which tickets are bought, entrance time, and age. Similarly, Wang et al. [23] found that if the theme park provided heterogeneous services to visitors with unequal status, a price discrepancy would arouse price unfairness perception in the advantaged visitors, but would not induce the disadvantaged visitors’ price unfairness perception.
In this study, we define a touring experience as spending some money on buying theme park touring services. Based on the transaction utility theory and the equity theory, two unequal statuses of theme park visitors are discussed, taking into account their heterogeneous touring experiences; that is, the advantaged unequal status and the disadvantaged unequal status.

2.3. Service Quality, Service Homogeneity, and Service Value Perception in Theme Parks

Service quality is a measure of how well the service delivered matches customer expectations. Regarding discriminatory pricing strategies in service industries, many enterprises adopt service quality as a differentiation tool to offer different services to different groups at different prices. People generate heterogeneous value perceptions since the money spent on services and services received from the providers vary. Lovelock and Wirtz [37] indicated that people’s SVP is more complex if they receive differentiated services.
In the theme park industry, Saveriades [38] utilized queuing time to express the physical capacity of theme parks and investigated the impact of queuing times on visitors’ SVP. Milman et al. [19] explored the relative influences of perceived crowding and perceived popularity on theme park’s service perceptions, which then influenced the satisfaction and behavioral intentions of visitors. Cheng et al. [39] found that visitors’ SVP and satisfaction strongly affected their brand-switching decisions towards theme parks. Prebensen et al. [40] suggested that visitors’ touring experience could be measured by the number of attractions visited and/or experienced. Jin et al. [41] explored the impact of theme park visitors’ SVP on their satisfaction and behavioral intentions. They found that SVP was a determinant that influenced the theme park’s image. Zhang et al. [42] mentioned that attraction experience and waiting time experience could affect theme park visitors’ SVP. Hernandez-Maskivker et al. [43] introduced the notions of reference dependence and loss aversion to the analysis of waiting times in theme parks. They found that theme park visitors’ WTP was greatly affected by waiting times. Albayrak et al. [18] used big data to analyze the factors that influence theme park visitors’ SVP. They suggested that theme parks should focus on improving the provided services instead of simply cutting prices since customers stressed value for money. Wang et al. [23] explored how visitors perceived the basis for discrimination and price differences in theme parks. They found that price differences did not directly affect visitors’ SVP; however, whether the service provided to visitors was differentiated or not was a decisive factor. Zhang et al. [44] mined and analyzed online review data from tourism websites. They found that some theme parks could improve visitor satisfaction by using supporting technologies such as sharing the waiting time for each attraction and providing intelligent display screens for in-park traffic. Zhu et al. [12] found that visitors’ behavioral intentions, such as revisiting or recommending the theme park to others, were enhanced when they obtained good SVP in their touring experiences.
In this study, the service homogeneity coefficient is used to denote the number of attractions provided to different groups of visitors. Furthermore, the service homogeneity coefficient and heterogeneous admission fees are used to measure the similarity in experiences of visitors with unequal status.

3. Models

3.1. Problem Description

In response to the national dual carbon strategy and the requirements for sustainable development in the tourism industry, a discriminatory pricing strategy aimed at ensuring sustained investment in low-carbon activities is proposed in this study. Theme parks charge discriminatory admission fees for different visitors. In this section, based on the transaction utility theory [45] and the equity theory [24], the PFP and SVP of the interrelationship between visitors’ touring experience and the admission fees paid to theme parks are investigated. The main factors that influence visitors’ PFP and SVP such as unequal status, reference price, and similarity in visitors’ touring experiences are considered. Regarding the discriminatory pricing strategies used by theme parks, visitors with unequal status can access the open information on the admission fee scheme. They may compare similarities in their experiences (namely, the admission fee paid and the touring services received). If visitors are satisfied with the comparative results, price fairness and high service value will be perceived; otherwise, price unfairness and low service value will be induced, probably along with negative reactions. According to previous studies [38,40,43], the number of attractions visited and the expected waiting times are important criteria for measuring visitors’ satisfaction with theme parks. In this study, these criteria are used to describe the experience similarity between advantaged and disadvantaged visitors. For example, some theme parks provide visitors with hedonic and exciting facilities. Adults can access most facilities in such theme parks, although they need to pay the full ticket price. On the contrary, children and the elderly can only access some of the hedonic facilities due to their physical conditions, hence they are offered discounted fares. Real-world examples demonstrate the feasibility of exploring the experience similarity between visitors with unequal status based on the number of attractions visited and the different admission fees paid. These examples also justify the necessity and importance of incorporating experience similarity in the study of discriminatory pricing strategies. Thus, in this study, the visitors’ experience similarity is considered a key factor in describing the utility functions of visitors with unequal status.
Therefore, when formulating their discriminatory price strategies, theme parks need to consider the experience similarities or differences between the utility of visitors who get ticket discounts (the advantaged visitors) and that of visitors who do not get ticket discounts (the disadvantaged visitors). This is because the differences in utilities or the similarities in experiences will affect the satisfaction and brand loyalty of the visitors [29,46] as well as their willingness to consume within the theme park [23]. Under these circumstances, experience similarity is used to evaluate the PFP, SVP, and utilities of visitors with unequal status.
In this section, individual utility functions of visitors with unequal status are first established based on the equality theory and the transaction utility theory, taking into account the PFP and SVP of visitors. Second, the revenue function of the theme park and the utility function of all visitors are constructed. Finally, in accordance with the proposed research questions and based on the goal programming method, a multi-goal programming-based discriminatory pricing model is proposed, taking into account the following three goals: achieving the established revenue target, achieving distributed justice between theme parks and their visitors, and achieving distributed justice between advantaged visitors and disadvantaged visitors. The research framework is shown in Figure 1.
To facilitate modeling, the parameters and symbols used in this study are introduced as follows (Table 1).

3.2. Research Assumptions

Before establishing the model, the following research assumptions are introduced based on the existing literature and real-world practices in the theme park industry.
First, visitors to the theme park are divided into two groups: advantaged visitors and disadvantaged visitors; their admission fees satisfy p d > p a > 0 . The total utility of visitors to the theme park is the sum of the utilities of advantaged and disadvantaged visitors, i.e., U = U a + U d . The total visitor demand of the theme park is the sum of the number of advantaged and disadvantaged visitors, i.e., d = d a + d d . The WTP of the advantaged and disadvantaged visitors to the theme park satisfies the same uniform distribution, i.e., v a i , v d j [ v min , v max ] . The market demand for the advantaged visitors and the disadvantaged visitors is assumed to follow a similar linear function, i.e., d a / d = a b p a / d ,   a > 0 ,   b > 0 .
Second, the parameter β [ 0 , 1 ] denotes the service homogeneity coefficient. The parameter β = 0 means that the services offered to the advantaged and disadvantaged visitors are different. For example, if all attractions in a theme park can only be accessed by visitors over 11 years old and under 65 years old, then visitors under the age of 11 or over the age of 65 will have completely different service experiences from those aged 11–65. Conversely, the parameter β = 1 means that the services offered to the advantaged and disadvantaged visitors are identical. For example, a theme park provides the same service and the same standard of service to visitors who buy tickets online and those who buy tickets on-site.
Third, from a sustainability point of view, if visitors feel that the service they experienced is not worth the price they paid, then they will think that the ticket price is unfair and the quality of service is low. In the long run, the repeat-visit rate and willingness to consume in the theme park will reduce. Therefore, when the theme park is developing a discriminatory pricing strategy, they need to balance the theme park’s revenues and the utility of visitors and realize distributed justice between them (namely, the second goal in the goal programming model) to reduce the negative impact of the decline in visitor satisfaction.
Finally, different visitors are charged different admission fees, leading to visitors’ perceived price unfairness due to price comparisons. When formulating discriminatory pricing strategies, the theme park needs to balance the utility of advantaged visitors against that of disadvantaged visitors and realize distributed justice between them (namely, the third goal in the goal programming model). In this way, although the disadvantaged visitors pay more than the advantaged visitors in terms of admission fees, they will not perceive the system to be more unfair and will therefore not feel dissatisfied.

3.3. Model Setup

The utility of consumers, as described by Thaler [35], Lichtenstein et al. [45], and Bei and Simpson [47], is presented in Equation (1).
Consumer utility = Acquisition utility + Transaction utility
= (Utility of purchased service − Purchase price) + (Reference price − Purchase price)
= (Psychological benefit + Received quality − Purchase price) + (Reference price − Purchase price)
As shown in Equation (1), acquisition utility is positively influenced by the benefits that people believe they are getting from acquiring and using the commodity, but is negatively influenced by the money given up for it. Received quality represents one’s estimation of a commodity’s cumulative excellence [48]. Transaction utility means that people would like to assess the merits or value of a deal by comparing the selling price with their internal reference price [35,49]. It reflects the satisfaction or pleasure people gain from taking advantage of the financial terms of the deal [35,45,49,50].
In the theme park tourism context, and based on findings of previous empirical studies [23,25,26], service homogeneity coefficient, admission fees, price difference, visitors’ unequal status, and reference price are used to represent theme park visitor utility. According to Equation (1), the visitors’ acquisition utility reflects the economic gain or loss from purchasing the theme park ticket. It depends on the reserved price and the value of service quality received compared with the cost. For the advantaged visitor, the psychological benefit is a positive feeling about purchasing the limited service at a discounted price; his received quality depends on the estimated value of the limited service. According to Wang et al. [23], Wu et al. [26], and real-world practices, the reference price for the advantaged visitor is the full price or the price the disadvantaged visitor is charged. For the disadvantaged visitor, the psychological benefit is a positive feeling about purchasing the full service at a full price; his received quality depends on the estimated value of the full service. The reference price for the disadvantaged visitor is the reserved theme park admission fee. The utility functions for advantaged and disadvantaged visitors are given in Equations (2) and (3), respectively.
u a i = ( β × v a i + β × p d p a ) + ( p d p a ) = β × v a i + ( β + 1 ) × p d 2 p a
u d j = ( v d j + p d p d ) + ( v d j p d ) = 2 v d j p d
Accordingly, the average utilities for advantaged and disadvantaged visitors are given in Equations (4) and (5), respectively.
U a ¯ = β × i = 1 d a v a i + d a × [ ( 1 + β ) × p d 2 p a ] d a = β × v a ¯ + ( 1 + β ) × p d 2 p a
U d ¯ = 2 × j = 1 d d v d j d d × p d d d = 2 v d ¯ p d
The total utility for all visitors with unequal status and the theme park’s revenue are given in Equations (6) and (7), respectively.
U = U a + U d = U a ¯ × d a + U d ¯ × d d
R = p a × d a + p d × d d
Based on the descriptions of visitor utility and theme park revenue, the discriminatory pricing model for the theme park is given by the following goal programming model:
min z = P 1 ( d 1 ) + P 2 ( d 2 + d 2 + ) + P 3 ( d 3 + d 3 + )
s . t . { R + d 1 d 1 + = R 0 R U + d 2 d 2 + = 0 U a ¯ U d ¯ + d 3 d 3 + = 0 p a p d p a , p d 0 ,   p a and   p d   are   integer d i d i + = 0 ,   i = 1 , 2 , 3 . d i , d i + 0 ,   i = 1 , 2 , 3 . min { d 1 } = P 1 min { d 2 + d 2 + } = P 2 min { d 3 + d 3 + } = P 3
It should be noted that the goal programming method is a mathematical programming method used in decision analysis [51]. In management practice, there are always conflicting goals that may not be achieved due to limited resources or various other reasons. In the goal programming method, these constraints are regarded as “goals”. The overall optimization objective is to give an optimal result that is as close to the specified value as possible. Priorities classify goals by importance and weigh the different goals in a certain order of priority.
A field study was conducted in Shenyang Fangte Happy World in 2018–2019, including in-depth interviews with the management and random interviews with visitors. In terms of the park’s investment in clean energy and green technologies, the interview results showed that tickets and in-park consumption were the main sources of funds for low-carbon investments in the park. In terms of the factors affecting the satisfaction of theme park visitors, the interview results showed that ticket discounts offered to different groups of visitors, the touring experience, and comparison with other visitors’ touring experiences significantly affected visitors’ willingness to revisit and consume. Based on these interview results, in the context of discriminatory pricing strategies for sustainable tourism in theme parks, three goals are considered in the goal programming model, as shown in Equations (8) and (9). The first goal (P1) is to maximize the theme park’s revenue and a minimum established revenue target R 0 must be met. The second goal (P2) is to balance the theme park’s total revenue and the visitors’ total utility, which is in line with the equity theory and the distributed justice principle. The third goal (P3) is to balance the average utilities of advantaged visitors and disadvantaged visitors, which is also in line with the equality theory and the distributed justice principle. Moreover, d i and d i + are positive and negative deviation variables of Pi. Since the first goal is revenue-oriented, the negative deviation variable d 1 should be as small as possible. For the second and third goals, R U and U a ¯ U d ¯ should be as close as possible, allowing R or U a ¯ to be appropriately greater (or less) than U or U d ¯ , respectively. Thus, d 2 + d 2 + and d 3 + d 3 + should be as small as possible.
These three goals fully reflect the long-term concerns of the theme park from the perspectives of sustainability and revenue maximization. Achieving the first goal allows the theme park to have sufficient and sustained funds to invest in clean energy and green technologies and to maintain the sustainable development of theme park tourism. Achieving the second and third goals can enhance visitors’ satisfaction, brand loyalty, and willingness to revisit and consume in the theme park in the long run, which is conducive to better realization of the first goal. The order of priority of these three goals is P 1 P 2 P 3 , which indicates that the first goal is the most important, the second goal is less important than the first goal, and the third goal comes last. The setting of these three goals and the model’s solution help solve the three research questions proposed in Section 1.

3.4. Numerical Study

Based on interviews from the field study in Shenyang Fangte Happy World in 2018–2019, a numerical study is conducted to justify the effectiveness and feasibility of the proposed model. Based on historical data and interviews with managers, the demand for this theme park is approximately represented as a linear function of its admission fee, i.e., d = 30000 20 p . Based on random interviews with visitors to this theme park, the WTP for theme park admission fees is supposed to follow a uniform distribution U [80, 280]. Based on interviews with the management, the theme park would like to achieve at least 8 × 106 RMB in revenue per quarter during the peak seasons. There are about 20 attractions or rides in this theme park, 6 of which are not suitable for visitors over 65 years old or visitors suffering from heart disease and high blood pressure. This means that the service homogeneity coefficient enjoyed by such visitors is β = 0.7 . Thus, Equation (9) can be rewritten as Equation (10).
{ 30000 p a + 30000 p d 20 p a 2 20 p d 2 + d 1 d 1 + = 8 × 10 6 60 p a 2 40 p d 2 + 92520 p a + 16200 p d + 34 p a p d 14.58 × 10 6 + d 2 d 2 + = 0 2 p a + 2.7 p d 234 + d 3 d 3 + = 0 p a p d p a , p d 0 ,   p a , p d   N d i , d i + 0 ,   i = 1 , 2 , 3 . min { d 1 } = P 1 min { d 2 + d 2 + } = P 2 min { d 3 + d 3 + } = P 3
We used the LINGO 11.0 software to run the model and obtained the following results: the admission fee for advantaged visitors p a = 125 RMB and the admission fee for disadvantaged visitors p d = 212 RMB.

4. Results and Discussion

A series of sensitivity analysis experiments are conducted to determine the discriminatory pricing strategy, taking into account theme park visitors’ PFP and SVP. Valuable managerial insights are also suggested. Additionally, the effects of established revenue target, service homogeneity coefficient, and visitor’s average WTP for theme parks based on admission fees for visitors with unequal status, the number of visitors, the theme park’s revenue, and the utility of visitors are examined. All parameters, except for those examined, are the same as those in Section 3.4.

4.1. Sensitivity Analysis of the Established Revenue Target

In this section, a sensitivity analysis of the established revenue target ( R 0 ) is conducted. The parameter R 0 is assumed to be in the set [10 × 105, 100 × 105], which means that the theme park would like to obtain a minimum revenue target ranging from one million to ten million RMB over a certain period. The results reveal that when the minimum revenue target R 0 is below 86 × 105, the admission fees for advantaged visitors and disadvantaged visitors are 144 and 180, respectively. When R 0 is above 93.5 × 105, there are no optimal solutions for the model. The results are given in Table 2. The trend of changes in admission fees for advantaged and disadvantaged visitors with R 0 are shown in Figure 2, the trend of changes in the number of visitors with R 0 are shown in Figure 3, and the trends of changes in theme park’s revenue and visitors’ utility are shown in Figure 4.
It can be seen from Figure 2, Figure 3 and Figure 4 that when R 0 is below the threshold 86 × 105, the admission fees for advantaged and disadvantaged visitors, the number of visitors, the theme park’s revenue, and the utility of visitors remain relatively stable. Since advantaged visitors such as senior citizens and children are more sensitive to the price paid for limited services, it is suggested that when R 0 exceeds the threshold, theme parks should raise the admission fees for disadvantaged visitors but keep the admission fees of advantaged visitors relatively unchanged. In this way, the high established revenue target will be achieved. Although the total number of disadvantaged visitors and the utilities of disadvantaged visitors will be affected, the proposed discriminatory pricing model can minimize the perceived unfairness among disadvantaged visitors. Therefore, if the theme park wants to increase the established revenue target (for example, there is a need to increase investment in clean energy and green technologies), it needs to increase the admission fees for disadvantaged visitors; at the same time, to reduce the price unfairness perception and increase the satisfaction of the disadvantaged visitors, the theme park should improve the quality of service provided to disadvantaged visitors and increase the total utility of all visitors.

4.2. Sensitivity Analysis of the Service Homogeneity Coefficient

In this section, sensitivity analysis of the service homogeneity coefficient (β) is conducted. It is assumed that the parameter β is in the set [0, 1], where 0 means that the services provided to the advantaged and disadvantaged visitors are different, and 1 means that the services provided to advantaged and disadvantaged visitors are identical. Results reveal that when β is below 0.5, the admission fee for advantaged visitors ( p a ) increases with β and the admission fee for disadvantaged visitors ( p d ) decreases with β (although there is a small reversal when β is equal to 0.1 or 0.15, p d still decreases with β). When β is above 0.5, p a increases with the visitors’ average WTP for theme parks, while p d is kept as the visitors’ average WTP. When β is equal to 1, the admission fee should be the same. The results are given in Table 3. The trends of changes in admission fees for advantaged and disadvantaged visitors with β are shown in Figure 5, the trends of changes in the number of visitors with β are shown in Figure 6, and the trends of changes in the theme park’s revenue and visitors’ utility with β are shown in Figure 7.
It can be seen from Figure 5, Figure 6 and Figure 7 that when the service homogeneity level (β) is relatively low, the admission fee for advantaged visitors is very low while that for disadvantaged visitors is very high. When β increases, the price differences between visitors with unequal status are reduced accordingly. This can be explained using real-world examples. Some outdoor attractions or rides are not suitable for all visitors to access in the winter compared with the summer. In this case, the touring demand in winter will reduce. Thus, the theme park can apply the proposed discriminatory pricing strategy and charge different admission fees for off-peak season visitors and peak season visitors. In this way, the theme parks might have relatively stable market demand and reach an established revenue target that can guarantee stable manpower resources and sustainable operations in the theme parks throughout the year.
The above results also provide other practical managerial insights. For theme parks with many thrilling attractions, meaning that some of the attractions are not suitable for senior citizens and children, the admission fees for visitors should not be too high. For cultural landscape theme parks where the services provided to all visitors are homogeneous, the admission fees should be similar across all groups. In case of price discrimination between morning and afternoon visitors, visitors entering the theme park in the afternoon might not have enough time to go around the entire theme park due to long queue times during the peak season, while during off-peak seasons, afternoon visitors can probably enjoy all the services and attractions in the theme park. In such cases, the theme park can charge a lower admission fee for afternoon visitors during peak seasons, and a lower discounted admission fee during off-peak seasons.

4.3. Sensitivity Analysis of the Average WTP of Visitors

In this section, a sensitivity analysis of visitors’ average WTP ( v ¯ ) for theme parks is conducted. Visitors’ average WTP is assumed to be in the set [100, 280]. Results reveal that when v ¯ is below 180, the admission fee for advantaged visitors ( p a ) increases with v ¯ , while the admission fee for disadvantaged visitors ( p d ) shows some fluctuations (although the general trend is that p d decreases with v ¯ ). When v ¯ is above 180, p a increases while p d is equal to v ¯ . The results are given in Table 4. The trends of changes in admission fees for advantaged and disadvantaged visitors with v ¯ are shown in Figure 8, the trends of changes in the number of visitors with v ¯ are shown in Figure 9, and the trends of changes in the theme park’s total revenue and visitors’ utility with v ¯ are shown in Figure 10.
It can be seen from Figure 8 that when visitors’ average WTP for theme parks ( v ¯ ) is relatively low, it is better for the theme park to charge a premium admission fee for disadvantaged visitors, but an extremely low price for advantaged visitors. In this way, the theme park can reach the established revenue target, although it will negatively affect the utility of the disadvantaged visitors. When v ¯ increases (especially for WTPs higher than 180), it is better for the theme park to increase the admission fees for both advantaged and disadvantaged visitors. This can be explained using real-world examples. For example, for some of the less well-known theme parks, the WTP of visitors is generally low. To reach the established revenue target, the theme park needs to set a higher full-price ticket but put forward a more diversified discount ticket policy to attract visitors to the park. However, for some very famous theme parks, the WTP of visitors is generally high. In this case, the theme parks can be stricter in setting the prices of discount tickets, with no need to give larger discounts.
The figures above also provide other practical managerial insights. If visitors’ average WTP is high, the theme park can obtain more revenue. Thus, the theme park should focus on improving the quality of service to enhance visitors’ WTP. For example, citizens who live around infamous local theme parks have a low desire to go to the parks. To increase revenue, the parks could charge local visitors discounted admission fees or improve the city shuttle bus system to provide local residents with convenient transportation to the park.

5. Practical Implications

The purpose of the proposed goal-programming-based discriminatory pricing model is to increase revenue and visitor satisfaction. In the low-carbon tourism economy, theme parks’ investments in clean energy and green technologies mainly come from ticket revenue and visitors’ in-park consumption. Existing research justifies that visitors’ PFP toward the theme park’s pricing strategy and the SVP toward the theme park’s touring experience could greatly affect the theme park’s revenues and visitor satisfaction [22,23,26,51]. Some suggestions and managerial implications for theme park management are summarized based on the sensitivity analysis results from the viewpoint of sustainability and revenue maximization.
Regarding the formulation of discriminatory pricing strategies, managers first need to consider the impact of the established revenue targets on the pricing strategy. If the expected revenue target is set too high, the theme park needs to raise the admission fees for disadvantaged visitors and keep discount admission fees for advantaged visitors at a more stable level. However, doing so might, to a certain extent, damage the perceptions of price fairness and service value among the disadvantaged visitors, thus the theme park needs to focus on improving service quality in the park, for example, by displaying the waiting time for each attraction and increasing the number of amusement facilities. Second, managers need to consider the impact of service heterogeneity on the pricing strategy. When choosing the basis for price discrimination, theme park managers should pay attention to the degree of service heterogeneity provided by theme parks to visitors with unequal status. For example, if the ticket purchase channel is used as the basis for discrimination, the price difference should not be too large due to the small difference in the services experienced by different types of visitors. Otherwise, this will lead to dissatisfaction and unfair perception by disadvantaged visitors (e.g., those who buy tickets on-site) against advantaged visitors (e.g., those who buy tickets online). As another example, if age is used as the basis for discrimination, since children and the elderly experience fewer thrilling attractions or rides compared with adult visitors, the theme park can formulate reasonable price discounts for advantaged visitors based on the degree of service homogeneity or heterogeneity. Finally, managers need to consider the impact of visitors’ WTP on the pricing strategy. Affected by the COVID-19 pandemic and the global economic downturn, some non-popular theme parks need to lower their expectations about visitors’ WTP. However, a rebound in the tourism industry could see a spurt in the demand for visiting popular theme parks. In this case, such theme parks can raise their expectations of visitors’ WTP. When the visitors’ WTP to pay for a theme park is generally low, the admission fees for advantaged visitors and disadvantaged visitors charged by the theme park can differ greatly. On the contrary, when visitors’ WTP for a theme park is generally high, the difference in ticket prices formulated by the theme park should be small. The theme park can design different discriminatory pricing strategies by adjusting their expectations of visitors’ WTP to reach the established revenue target and achieve sustainable development of the theme park in the long run.
Regarding increasing theme park revenues, when the service heterogeneity or service homogeneity provided by the theme park to visitors with unequal status is larger, the theme park’s revenue will be higher. On the contrary, when the service heterogeneity or service homogeneity provided by the theme park to visitors with unequal status is of a medium level, the theme park’s revenue will be very low. This means that if the theme park wants to obtain higher revenue, it needs to have a clearer positioning, such as focusing on providing thrilling attractions or rides, focusing on providing attraction facilities for young children or focusing on providing cultural landscape tourism projects. If the theme park’s positioning is not clear, it may cause dissatisfaction among visitors, irrespective of the type. On the other hand, when the visitors’ WTP for the theme park is higher, the market size of the theme park is larger and the revenues are higher. On the contrary, when the visitors’ WTP for the theme park is lower, the market size of the theme park is smaller and the revenue is lower. This means that theme park managers should try their best to improve visitors’ WTP for the theme parks, for example by creating online celebrity attractions, promoting green tourism concepts, and improving the quality of support services inside and outside the parks.

6. Conclusions

This article provides a goal-programming-based discriminatory pricing model for sustainable tourism in theme parks. It is a pioneer in discussing the role of discriminatory pricing strategy in supporting theme parks’ sustained investment in clean energy and green technologies. Similarities in touring experiences are studied based on the transaction utility theory, equity theory, unequal status, price fairness perception, and service value perception of visitors. The proposed goal-programming-based discriminatory pricing model achieved three goals: the theme park’s established revenue target, distributed justice between the theme parks and visitors, and distributed justice between visitors with unequal status. Some conclusions that are based on the research questions proposed in Section 1 are summarized.
First, from the perspective of sustainability and revenue maximization, the theme park can adopt the proposed discriminatory pricing strategy to achieve the established revenue target (P1 in the goal programming model) and use it as a source of money for investment in clean energy and green technologies. If the revenue target is set too high, the theme park needs to raise the admission fees for disadvantaged visitors. In the meantime, the corresponding quality of service should also be improved.
Second, in the goal programming model, the second goal (P2) is to realize distributed justice between the theme park and visitors. It guarantees that the total revenue of the theme park and the total utility of visitors with unequal status will not deviate too much from each other. The theme park should balance the admission fees charged with the heterogeneous services provided to different visitor groups.
Third, the PFP and SVP of visitors are considered in the visitor utility function. The similarity in visitors’ touring experience (heterogeneous admission fee and service homogeneity coefficient) is used to describe their PFP and SVP. Based on the utility functions of visitors with unequal status, the realization of the third goal (P3) in the goal programming model realizes distributed justice between advantaged visitors and disadvantaged visitors. It guarantees that the average utilities of advantaged visitors and disadvantaged visitors will not deviate too much from each other.
In the context of sustainable tourism in theme parks, the contribution of the proposed discriminatory pricing strategy has two aspects. For one thing, the proposed discriminatory pricing strategy can help the theme park maintain a relatively stable number of visitors—there will not be too many visitors in peak seasons and too few visitors in off-peak seasons. In addition, the proposed discriminatory pricing strategy can ensure that the theme park will achieve the established revenue target and have sufficient funds for low-carbon activities. These achievements play an important role in coordinating the in-park human resources, managing the energy demands of the theme parks, and realizing low-carbon sustainable development and green transformation. For another, the proposed discriminatory pricing strategy can make the theme park value the social welfare of visitors. This strategy realizes distributed justice between advantaged and disadvantaged visitors and distributed justice between visitors and theme parks. In this way, visitors’ satisfaction, brand loyalty, and willingness to revisit and consume within theme parks will be improved in the long run.
From the perspective of sustainability and revenue maximization in theme parks, this study has limitations that provide avenues for future research. The discriminatory pricing strategy proposed in this study is based on three constraints: the established revenue target, distributed justice between the theme park and its visitors, and distributed justice between advantaged and disadvantaged visitors. In reality, many other factors affect discriminatory pricing, including the types of theme parks, the diverse characteristics of different visitor groups, and the cultural backgrounds of visitors. In the future, all these factors need to be reflected in the discriminatory pricing strategy of theme parks. Additionally, low-carbon investment in clean energy and green technologies has not been accounted for in the revenue function in this study. In future studies, cost subdivisions and revenue composition allocated to low-carbon activities should be considered. On this basis, a more operational discriminatory pricing strategy will be studied to improve long-term sustainable operations in the theme park industry.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, X.W. and Z.-P.F.; Formal analysis, X.W.; Funding acquisition, X.W. and Z.-P.F.; Investigation, X.W., Z.-P.F., H.L. and Y.L.; Software, H.L.; Supervision, X.W. and Z.-P.F.; Validation, X.W., Z.-P.F., H.L. and Y.L.; Visualization, X.W.; Writing—original draft, X.W.; Writing—review and editing, X.W. and Y.L. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research was funded by the Ministry of Education of Humanities and Social Sciences Project (grant number 17YJC630162) and the 111 Project of China (grant number B16009).

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

All relevant data are available upon request from the authors.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Tang, C.; Zhong, L.; Ng, P. Factors That Influence the Tourism Industry’s Carbon Emissions: A Tourism Area Life Cycle Model Perspective. Energy Policy 2017, 109, 704–718. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Wu, J.; Wang, S.; Liu, Y.; Xie, X.; Wang, S.; Lv, L.; Luo, H. Measurement of Tourism-Related CO2 Emission and the Factors Influencing Low-Carbon Behavior of Tourists: Evidence from Protected Areas in China. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2023, 20, 1277. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  3. Zha, J.; Fan, R.; Yao, Y.; Lamei, H.; Meng, Y. Framework for Accounting for Tourism Carbon Emissions in China: An Industrial Linkage Perspective. Tour. Econ. 2020, 27, 135481662092489. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Ma, X.; Han, M.; Luo, J.; Song, Y.; Chen, R.; Sun, X. The Empirical Decomposition and Peak Path of China’s Tourism Carbon Emissions. Environ. Sci. Pollut. Res. 2021, 28, 66448–66463. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Yang, S.; Hao, Q.; Wang, Y.; Zhang, C. Impact of the Participation of the Tourism Sector on Carbon Emission Reduction in the Tourism Industry. Sustainability 2022, 14, 15570. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Tang, Z.; Zhang, M. Evolutionary Game Analysis of Energy Saving Behavior of Tourism Enterprises under Carbon Emission Constraints. Int. J. Low-Carbon Technol. 2023, 18, 49–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Braun, T.; Cajias, M.; Hohenstatt, R. Societal Influence on Diffusion of Green Buildings: A Count Regression Approach. J. Real Estate Res. 2017, 39, 1–38. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Leskinen, N.; Vimpari, J.; Junnila, S. A Review of the Impact of Green Building Certification on the Cash Flows and Values of Commercial Properties. Sustainability 2020, 12, 2729. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Milman, A. Evaluating the Guest Experience at Theme Parks: An Empirical Investigation of Key Attributes. Int. J. Tour. Res. 2009, 11, 373–387. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Milman, A.; Tasci, A.D.A. Exploring the Experiential and Sociodemographic Drivers of Satisfaction and Loyalty in the Theme Park Context. J. Destin. Mark. Manag. 2018, 8, 385–395. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Milman, A.; Tasci, A.D.A.; Wei, W. Crowded and Popular: The Two Sides of the Coin Affecting Theme-Park Experience, Satisfaction, and Loyalty. J. Destin. Mark. Manag. 2020, 18, 100468. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Zhu, C.; Fong, L.H.N.; Shang, Z.; Gan, M. Rethinking the Impact of Theme Park Image on Perceived Value and Behavioral Intention: The Case of Chimelong Ocean Kingdom, China. Sustainability 2022, 14, 2349. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Peráček, T. E-Commerce and Its Limits in the Context of the Consumer Protection: The Case of the Slovak Republic. Jurid. Trib. 2022, 12, 35–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Geissler, G.L.; Rucks, C.T. The Overall Theme Park Experience: A Visitor Satisfaction Tracking Study. J. Vacat. Mark. 2011, 17, 127–138. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Wu, H.-C.; Li, M.-Y.; Li, T. A Study of Experiential Quality, Experiential Value, Experiential Satisfaction, Theme Park Image, and Revisit Intention. J. Hosp. Tour. Res. 2018, 42, 26–73. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Ko, Y.D.; Park, K. Theme Park Revenue Management with a Dual Admission Policy. Asia Pac. J. Tour. Res. 2019, 24, 865–881. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Enrique Bigné, J.; Sánchez, I.; Andreu, L. The Role of Variety Seeking in Short and Long Run Revisit Intentions in Holiday Destinations. Int. J. Cult. Tour. Hosp. Res. 2009, 3, 103–115. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Albayrak, T.; Cengizci, A.D.; Caber, M.; Nang Fong, L.H. Big Data Use in Determining Competitive Position: The Case of Theme Parks in Hong Kong. J. Destin. Mark. Manag. 2021, 22, 100668. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Cross, R.G. Revenue Management: Hard-Core Tactics for Market Domination; Broadway Books: New York, NY, USA, 1997. [Google Scholar]
  20. Dong, Z.; Fan, Z.-P.; Wang, N. An Analysis of Pricing Strategy for Bike-Sharing Services: The Role of the Inconvenience Cost. Transp. Res. Part E Logist. Transp. Rev. 2023, 175, 103146. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Wang, X.; Fan, Z.-P.; Yang, Z.; Teng, X.; Chi, X. Optimal Order Quantities, Buyback Prices, and Government Subsidies for Cars in a Sharing Economy Environment. Comput. Ind. Eng. 2023, 182, 109369. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Heo, C.Y.; Lee, S. Application of Revenue Management Practices to the Theme Park Industry. Int. J. Hosp. Manag. 2009, 28, 446–453. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Wang, X.; Fan, Z.-P.; Li, H. Investigating the Discriminatory Pricing Strategy of Theme Parks Considering Visitor’s Perceptions. Asia Pac. J. Tour. Res. 2021, 26, 1–14. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Bolton, L.E.; Warlop, L.; Alba, J.W. Consumer Perceptions of Price (Un)Fairness. J. Consum. Res. 2003, 29, 474–491. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Xia, L.; Monroe, K.B.; Cox, J.L. The Price Is Unfair! A Conceptual Framework of Price Fairness Perceptions. J. Mark. 2004, 68, 1–15. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Wu, C.-C.; Liu, Y.-F.; Chen, Y.-J.; Wang, C.-J. Consumer Responses to Price Discrimination: Discriminating Bases, Inequality Status, and Information Disclosure Timing Influences. J. Bus. Res. 2012, 65, 106–116. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Yim, E.S.; Lee, S.; Kim, W.G. Determinants of a Restaurant Average Meal Price: An Application of the Hedonic Pricing Model. Int. J. Hosp. Manag. 2014, 39, 11–20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Chang, M.-Y.; Hsu, Y.-S.; Chen, H.-S. Choice Experiment Method for Sustainable Tourism in Theme Parks. Sustainability 2021, 13, 7146. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Milman, A.; Tasci, A.D.A. The Influence of Dynamic Pricing on Consumer Trust, Value, and Loyalty Relationships in Theme Parks. J. Vacat. Mark. 2023, 29, 386–408. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Li, J.; Li, Q. Analysis of Queue Management in Theme Parks Introducing the Fast Pass System. Heliyon 2023, 9, e18001. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Oi, W.Y. A Disneyland Dilemma: Two-Part Tariffs for a Mickey Mouse Monopoly. Q. J. Econ. 1971, 85, 77–96. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Braun, B.M.; Soskin, M.D.; Cernicky, M. Central Florida Theme Park Pricing: Following the Mouse. Ann. Tour. Res. 1992, 19, 131–136. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Choi, D.W.; Lee, S.; Alcorn, M. Influence of culture on purchase decision: Integrative models development of amusement park customers. Int. J. Hosp. Manag. 2020, 87, 102502. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Darke, P.R.; Dahl, D.W. Fairness and Discounts: The Subjective Value of a Bargain. J. Consum. Psychol. 2003, 13, 328–338. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Thaler, R. Mental Accounting and Consumer Choice. Mark. Sci. 1985, 4, 199–214. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Monroe, K.B. Buyers’ Subjective Perceptions of Price. J. Mark. Res. 1973, 10, 70–80. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Lovelock, C.H.; Wirtz, J. Services Marketing: People, Technology, Strategy, 5th ed.; Prentice Hall: Englewood, CO, USA, 2003. [Google Scholar]
  38. Saveriades, A. Establishing the Social Tourism Carrying Capacity for the Tourist Resorts of the East Coast of the Republic of Cyprus. Tour. Manag. 2000, 21, 147–156. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Cheng, Q.; Du, R.; Ma, Y. Factors Influencing Theme Park Visitor Brand-Switching Behaviour as Based on Visitor Perception. Curr. Issues Tour. 2016, 19, 1425–1446. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Prebensen, N.K.; Woo, E.; Uysal, M.S. Experience Value: Antecedents and Consequences. Curr. Issues Tour. 2014, 17, 910–928. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Jin, N.; Lee, S.; Lee, H. The Effect of Experience Quality on Perceived Value, Satisfaction, Image and Behavioral Intention of Water Park Patrons: New versus Repeat Visitors. Int. J. Tour. Res. 2015, 17, 82–95. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Zhang, Y.; Li, X.; Su, Q.; Hu, X. Exploring a Theme Park’s Tourism Carrying Capacity: A Demand-Side Analysis. Tour. Manag. 2017, 59, 564–578. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Hernandez-Maskivker, G.-M.; Nicolau, J.L.; Ryan, G.; Valverde, M. A Reference-Dependent Approach to WTP for Priority. Tour. Manag. 2019, 71, 165–172. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Zhang, T.; Li, B.; Milman, A.; Hua, N. Assessing Technology Adoption Practices in Chinese Theme Parks: Text Mining and Sentiment Analysis. J. Hosp. Tour. Technol. 2021, 13, 195–213. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Lichtenstein, D.R.; Netemeyer, R.G.; Burton, S. Distinguishing Coupon Proneness from Value Consciousness: An Acquisition-Transaction Utility Theory Perspective. J. Mark. 1990, 54, 54–67. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Mutambik, I.; Lee, J.; Almuqrin, A.; Zhang, J.Z.; Homadi, A. The Growth of Social Commerce: How It Is Affected by Users’ Privacy Concerns. J. Theor. Appl. Electron. Commer. Res. 2023, 18, 725–743. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Bei, L.-T.; Simpson, E. The Determinants of Consumers’ Purchase Decisions for Recycled Products: An Application of Acquisition-Transaction Utility Theory. Adv. Consum. Res. 1995, 22, 257–261. [Google Scholar]
  48. Zeithaml, V.A. Consumer Perceptions of Price, Quality, and Value: A Means-End Model and Synthesis of Evidence. J. Mark. 1988, 52, 35–48. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Monroe, K.B.; Chapman, J.D. Framing Effects on Buyers’ Subjective Product Evaluations. Adv. Consum. Res. 1987, 14, 193–197. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Wang, X.; Fan, Z.-P.; Liu, Z. Optimal Markdown Policy of Perishable Food under the Consumer Price Fairness Perception. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2016, 54, 5811–5828. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Charnes, A.; Cooper, W.W. Management Models and Industrial Applications of Linear Programming. Manag. Sci. 1957, 4, 38–91. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Research framework.
Figure 1. Research framework.
Sustainability 15 14180 g001
Figure 2. The impact of the theme park’s established revenue targets on visitors’ admission fees.
Figure 2. The impact of the theme park’s established revenue targets on visitors’ admission fees.
Sustainability 15 14180 g002
Figure 3. The impact of the theme park’s established revenue targets on the number of visitors.
Figure 3. The impact of the theme park’s established revenue targets on the number of visitors.
Sustainability 15 14180 g003
Figure 4. The impact of the theme park’s established revenue targets on the theme park’s revenue and visitors’ utility.
Figure 4. The impact of the theme park’s established revenue targets on the theme park’s revenue and visitors’ utility.
Sustainability 15 14180 g004
Figure 5. The impact of the service homogeneity coefficient on visitors’ admission fees.
Figure 5. The impact of the service homogeneity coefficient on visitors’ admission fees.
Sustainability 15 14180 g005
Figure 6. The impact of the service homogeneity coefficient on the number of visitors.
Figure 6. The impact of the service homogeneity coefficient on the number of visitors.
Sustainability 15 14180 g006
Figure 7. The impact of the service homogeneity coefficient on the theme park’s revenue and visitors’ utility.
Figure 7. The impact of the service homogeneity coefficient on the theme park’s revenue and visitors’ utility.
Sustainability 15 14180 g007
Figure 8. The impact of visitors’ average WTP on visitors’ admission fees.
Figure 8. The impact of visitors’ average WTP on visitors’ admission fees.
Sustainability 15 14180 g008
Figure 9. The impact of visitors’ average WTP on the number of visitors.
Figure 9. The impact of visitors’ average WTP on the number of visitors.
Sustainability 15 14180 g009
Figure 10. The impact of visitors’ average WTP on the theme park’s revenue and visitors’ utility.
Figure 10. The impact of visitors’ average WTP on the theme park’s revenue and visitors’ utility.
Sustainability 15 14180 g010
Table 1. Notations.
Table 1. Notations.
Decision Variables
p a Admission fee for advantaged visitors.
p d Admission fee for disadvantaged visitors.
Parameters
R Theme park’s revenue during a certain period.
U Total utility of all visitors during a certain period.
U a Total utility of advantaged visitors during a certain period.
U d Total utility of disadvantaged visitors during a certain period.
U a ¯ Average utility of advantaged visitors during a certain period.
U d ¯ Average utility of disadvantaged visitors during a certain period.
u a i The utility of the i-th advantaged visitor.
u d j The utility of the j-th disadvantaged visitor.
v a i The reserved price for the i-th advantaged visitor.
v d j The reserved price for the j-th disadvantaged visitor.
d The number of visitors during a certain period.
d a The number of advantaged visitors during a certain period.
d d The number of disadvantaged visitors during a certain period.
β Service homogeneity coefficient.
R 0 The established revenue target of a theme park during a certain period.
a The potential demand of visitors during a certain period.
b Visitors’ sensitivity to the admission fee of a theme park.
P i Priorities of the goals in the goal programming model
d i + , d i Positive and negative deviation variables in the goal programming model
Table 2. Results of sensitivity analysis based on established revenue targets.
Table 2. Results of sensitivity analysis based on established revenue targets.
R 0 (×105) p a p d D (×105)R (×105)U (×105)
114418053.5286.5777.07
1014418053.5286.5777.07
2014418053.5286.5777.07
3014418053.5286.5777.07
4014418053.5286.5777.07
5014418053.5286.5777.07
6014418053.5286.5777.07
7014418053.5286.5777.07
8014418053.5286.5777.07
9014221052.9692.75105.39
9314123652.4697.98128.63
93.514123652.4697.98128.63
Table 3. Results of sensitivity analysis based on the service homogeneity coefficient.
Table 3. Results of sensitivity analysis based on the service homogeneity coefficient.
β p a p d D (×105)R (×105)U (×105)
02245950.38102.07102.06
0.12032553.10090.03107.53
0.26039650.88104.72104.72
0.37932351.96098.4998.49
0.410024053.2088.4888.48
0.512018054.0080.6480.64
0.613218053.7683.6483.64
0.714418053.5286.5786.57
0.815618053.2889.4589.45
0.916818053.0492.2892.28
118018052.8095.0495.04
Table 4. Results of sensitivity analysis based on the average WTP of visitors.
Table 4. Results of sensitivity analysis based on the average WTP of visitors.
v ¯ p a p d D (×105)R (×105)U (×105)
1008029352,54093.4593.45
1209320953,96080.1379.28
14010822853,28088.0788.29
16012521253,26088.9988.98
18014418053,52086.5786.57
20016020052,80094.8894.88
22017622052,080102.92102.92
24019224051,360110.71110.71
26020826050,640118.23118.23
28022428049,920125.48125.48
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Wang, X.; Fan, Z.-P.; Li, H.; Li, Y. Discriminatory Pricing Strategy for Sustainable Tourism in Theme Parks considering Visitors’ Price Fairness and Service Value Perceptions. Sustainability 2023, 15, 14180. https://doi.org/10.3390/su151914180

AMA Style

Wang X, Fan Z-P, Li H, Li Y. Discriminatory Pricing Strategy for Sustainable Tourism in Theme Parks considering Visitors’ Price Fairness and Service Value Perceptions. Sustainability. 2023; 15(19):14180. https://doi.org/10.3390/su151914180

Chicago/Turabian Style

Wang, Xiaohuan, Zhi-Ping Fan, Haibin Li, and Yujie Li. 2023. "Discriminatory Pricing Strategy for Sustainable Tourism in Theme Parks considering Visitors’ Price Fairness and Service Value Perceptions" Sustainability 15, no. 19: 14180. https://doi.org/10.3390/su151914180

APA Style

Wang, X., Fan, Z. -P., Li, H., & Li, Y. (2023). Discriminatory Pricing Strategy for Sustainable Tourism in Theme Parks considering Visitors’ Price Fairness and Service Value Perceptions. Sustainability, 15(19), 14180. https://doi.org/10.3390/su151914180

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop