1. Introduction
In recent years, the polarization of compensation among Chinese companies has become increasingly serious. Hay Group, a global management consulting firm, noted in its 2015 Global Salary Report that, “the executive-employee compensation gap (EECG) is widening around the world, and it is the largest EECG within Chinese companies at about 12.7 times”. The 2015 Forbes data showed that the Lenovo CEO, Yang Yuanqing, topped the list of CEOs of Chinese listed companies with an annual salary of 119 million yuan, which was more than 700 times the salary of rank-and-file employees. The Chinese Listed Companies’ Executive Compensation Index Report (2017) announced that the average salary of the top three executives of LeTV in 2016 was nearly 450 million yuan, which was far more than a thousand times the salary of ordinary employees. According to principal-agent theory, there is asymmetrical information and inconsistent interests between principal and agent. As operators of an enterprise, senior executives have a basic grasp of the company’s information. As a result of information asymmetry, senior managers will pursue more improvement in their own salary level, social status, and reputation, and expand their own power. The EECG in Chinese enterprises is too broad and the resulting phenomenon of unfair social income distribution has been over-interpreted by the public from all circles, which has become a focal issue that needs to be addressed in Chinese society. To open the “black box” regarding the mechanism of the continuous expansion of the EECG in enterprises, scholars have been digging deeper into the evolutionary mechanism of the EECG [
1]. At present, fruitful progress has been made in this area, confirming that corporate governance and organizational characteristics [
2,
3], top executives’ traits [
4], and industrial and regional features [
5] are important factors affecting the EECG. Even so, the existing literature is far from being effective in explaining the evolution of the EECG. At the same time, the issue of sustainable competitive advantage has been a central concern of both theoretical and business circles. The key to sustainable competitive advantage lies in implementing strategies to break the old equilibrium and gain new advantages. However, there is little literature examining such issues from the perspective of strategic choices for sustainable competitive advantage, and its relationship with EECG remains unclear.
Competition is an objective product of the market economy and an inevitable part of business existence. The pursuit of sustainable development is a fundamental change in the concept of human development and a major shift in an industrial civilization that has lasted for centuries. In 1980, Porter’s book “Competitive Strategy” classified firms’ competitive strategies into differentiation strategy, cost leadership strategy, and concentration strategy, in which differentiation strategy seeks to win a competitive advantage by creating products or services that are difficult to replace by competitors through research and development activities, advertising, and brand image enhancement activities, to meet the diversified and individualized needs of customers. The cost leadership strategy reduces costs by building efficient production facilities and implementing large-scale production on the premise of meeting the requirements of high product quality, while at the same time strictly controlling overhead, financial expenses, and R&D expenses, etc. There are various ways for companies to gain a sustainable competitive advantage. However, the academic community has not yet agreed on which competitive strategy is best. A significant portion of the literature supports a higher level of performance for cost leadership strategies [
6,
7]. In contrast, some scholars argue that firms that adopt a differentiation strategy have higher levels of short-term profitability and long-term competitiveness than those that implement a cost leadership strategy [
8]. Regardless of the controversy over their views, established studies all affirm the substantial value of competitive strategies.
Compared to traditional human resource management (HRM), strategic HRM is a kind of objective management to gain a competitive advantage [
9], which refers to a “full participation” HRM model. According to the theory of human capital, executives are leaders of enterprises, belonging to high-quality heterogeneous human capital in enterprises. If shareholders want executives to make full use of their highly strategic and unique human capital value and encourage them to use their human capital reasonably to create wealth for the company, they must develop more attractive compensation contracts for them from the perspective of competitive strategy. Compensation incentives are an important part of HRM, and the core of the strategic human resource incentive is to motivate employees according to the company’s strategic needs, stimulate their potential, and, ultimately, create value for the company. Therefore, some scholars have introduced strategic choice as a new perspective in the study of executive compensation formation mechanisms. In a pioneering study, Chai Cai et al. [
10] took a sample of A-share listed manufacturing companies in China and empirically found that 82% of companies with differentiated strategies had excessively high internal pay gaps among top executives and 87% of companies with cost leadership strategies had excessively low internal pay gaps among top executives. According to this finding, the implementation of a differentiated strategy is more likely to lead to the “trench effect” caused by excessive pay incentives. Therefore, the implementation of differentiated strategies is more likely to lead to the “trench effect” caused by excessive compensation incentives, which is not conducive to the long-term development of the company. It can be seen that the potential effects of competitive strategy on the compensation gap among top executives have been explored by scholars to an acceptable degree, while EECG, another key dimension of executive pay, has not been studied from the perspective of strategic choices for sustainable competitive advantage.
On the whole, the existing literature still has the following gaps to be addressed: Firstly, although the internal compensation gap among top executives, who act as the main decision-makers and leaders of the competitive strategy [
11], should be paid attention to, employees are the concrete executors of the strategy and are also indispensable for the success of the sustainable competitive strategy [
12]. However, the studies focusing on the competitive strategy’s effects on executive compensation haven’t mentioned the link between competitive strategy and EECG [
10]; therefore, the relationship between competitive strategy and EECG needs to be clarified. Secondly, the existing literature in this area is mostly discursive and normative, focusing on the qualitative matching principles of competitive strategy and compensation structure, compensation level, and compensation management system, while empirical studies based on a large amount of data are relatively scarce; therefore, empirical studies on the relationship between competitive strategy and compensation incentives need to be enriched. In addition, the marketization degree is used to reflect the relationship between the government and the market, the development of a non-state-owned economy, the development of the product market and factor market, the status quo of market intermediary organizations, and the legal environment system [
13]. Due to the uneven economic development between regions in China, there are great differences in the marketization degree, which lead to varying degrees of impact on all aspects of the company’s internal and external governance. Therefore, the marketization degree should be introduced as a contextual factor to address the strategic choice of sustainable competitive advantage in relation to EECG.
Given this, this paper attempts to explore the formation mechanism of EECG from the perspective of strategic choice for sustainable competitive advantage. To be specific, using balanced panel data consisting of 3900 firm-year observations from A-share manufacturing listed companies in Shenzhen and Shanghai Stock Exchange from 2008–2017 as the research sample, we focus on the following three questions: (1) How does a company’s choice of different competitive strategies determine EECG? (2) How will the marketization degree affect the relationship between different competitive strategies and EECG? (3) How can competitive and compensation strategies be scientifically and effectively matched to achieve a sustainable competitive advantage and, thus, a leap in corporate performance?
2. Literature and Hypotheses
The impact mechanism of differentiation strategy on EECG can be interpreted in two ways.
Firstly, a differentiation strategy improves a company’s sustainable competitive advantage through technological innovation [
14], which requires continuous investment and exploration of new areas to capture consumers’ minds and meet market opportunities. Therefore, the implementation of a differentiation strategy is usually accompanied by higher investment in R&D. Executives are key decision-makers in companies’ innovation activities and play a pivotal role in this strategic decision. Because R&D activities are highly uncertain and risky, executives tend to reduce their investment in risky technology innovation to avoid the corresponding operational and decision-making risks [
15]. In this case, according to principal-agent theory, executive compensation, as an incentive mechanism, can effectively solve the problem of moral hazard and adverse selection [
16]. Compensation incentives can compensate executives for the potential loss of short-term earnings from R&D investments [
17] and paying a higher level of compensation in return can weaken their negative risk-resilience attitude and motivate executives to actively invest in R&D. In addition, executives are more knowledgeable than shareholders about the company’s operating conditions and the internal and external environment it faces, and shareholders rely on executives to make accurate analyses and judgments of the complex operating situation. Especially for companies implementing differentiation strategies, achieving a differentiated sustainable competitive advantage depends on the rich experience of executives and keen insight into cutting-edge technologies. According to human capital theory, executives can provide a commercialized decision-making perspective and their own high-quality heterogeneous human capital in the company [
18]. Therefore, from the perspective of shareholders and the board of directors, there is a tendency to give executives higher levels of compensation in return, which can motivate them to continuously develop technological innovation to create value for the company on the one hand and retain the company’s core human capital on the other. Therefore, shareholders and the board of directors would pay more attention to the contribution of executives to the company, while relatively ignoring the value of ordinary employees. As a result, increasing the level of executive compensation will mean widening the EECG.
Secondly, from the CEOs’ perspective, managerial power theory suggests that CEOs usually manipulate their own compensation by misusing their discretion, as evidenced by increasing their compensation levels inappropriately to achieve both material and moral satisfaction [
19]. On the one hand, for companies pursuing a sustainable differentiation strategy, relatively low upfront fixed capital investment [
20] and higher R&D expenditures [
21] are generally accompanied in order to win the competitive advantage of differentiation. Since CEOs have less discretion to manipulate upfront fixed capital investment and more flexibility to manipulate accounting operations for R&D expenses, the capital expenditure structure of low fixed capital investment and high R&D expense investment resulting from the differentiation strategy helps CEOs use their discretion to maximize their own interests; on the other hand, the CEO of a company pursuing the differentiation strategy needs to have excellent foresight of industry development prospects and insight into consumer preferences, which would require higher decision-making power and better risk-control capability from the CEO. In this case, whether trying to motivate the CEO and his executive team who have scarce and valuable human capital in the management market, or trying to make full use of his heterogeneous human capital and business talents to enhance the competitiveness of the company, the CEO needs to be given more discretion [
22]. The greater the CEO’s discretion, the stronger his or her manipulation of compensation gains. Powerful CEOs control the allocation of corporate resources, while rank-and-file employees are in a weak position in the development of compensation programs, and, more often than not, they are only passive recipients of corporate compensation programs [
1]. As a result, the EECG is bound to increase. In view of this, the following hypothesis is proposed.
H1: Differentiation strategy has a significant positive impact on EECG.
The links between cost leadership strategy and EECG can be interpreted in two ways.
On the one hand, the essential nature of the cost leadership strategy is characterized by mass production with low marginal profit under specific quality standards, pursuing a commitment to lower product prices as a way to attract price-sensitive customers. In this case, the company is less engaged in R&D and promotional activities and, instead, gains profit by amortizing unit costs through increased sales [
23]. The relative stability of a company’s production technology determines that the investment activities under the cost leadership strategy are more robust than those under the differentiation strategy. As a result, senior managers need to take significantly fewer operational and decision-making risks, and their bargaining power over compensation is weakened. Therefore, the additional risk compensation premium paid to executives is bound to be reduced, while the less intensive executive compensation incentives are precisely in line with the firm’s goal of reasonably controlling labor costs [
10].
Ordinary employees, from the point of view of risk compensation, only need to efficiently complete the standardized and mechanical tasks required to improve efficiency and work specialization. During their daily work, the requirements for their technical diversity and individual innovative behavior are low, and the demand for risk compensation in employees’ pay structure is limited. From this perspective, the employees’ compensation would also be lower than that in enterprises adopting a differentiation strategy. However, such a decrease in the employees’ compensation would be rather limited. According to behavioral theory, a small wage gap can generate sustained cohesion, improve employee satisfaction, and thus improve business performance. Too large a pay gap can easily breed employee dissatisfaction, which can have a negative impact on business performance. The reason relies on the fact that employees’ compensation has downward rigidity, since reducing employee compensation will trigger extreme dissatisfaction, and negative idle behavior, or even anti-production behavior due to compensation dissatisfaction, will reduce production efficiency [
24]. According to social comparison theory, employees in enterprises compare their own compensation with that of others to gain a perception of the company’s compensation policies. Competitors with cost leadership strategies should therefore be used as a benchmark for determining employee pay to ensure that it is not significantly higher or lower than the average wage level in the same industry or region. At this time, the company will determine the salary paid to employees by using competitors adopting a cost leadership strategy as a benchmark to ensure that it is not significantly higher or lower than the average compensation level in the same industry or region. Hence, while both executive compensation and employee compensation would be constrained by the cost leadership strategy, the reduced size of the former outweighs that of the latter. As a result, adopting cost leadership would potentially reduce the pay gap between executives and employees.
On the other hand, most companies that implement cost leadership strategies adopt job-based pay systems, and moderate pay gaps at different job levels can motivate employees to work harder for promotion opportunities and higher positions, thus increasing productivity. However, too high a pay gap can cause a psychological sense of unfairness among ordinary employees, and employees with lower pay levels are more psychologically sensitive to pay increases. In this case, each unit of pay increase in cost leadership strategy companies can provide a higher marginal incentive effect for such employees compared to employees with higher pay levels in differentiated companies. According to the effective wage theory, higher wages lead to higher productivity and can maintain a lower turnover rate of personnel. Consequently, a slight increase in the pay level of average employees in low-cost companies has a distinct incentive effect. At the same time, a cost leadership strategy that seeks to reduce product costs inherently requires lower compensation incentives for executives [
25], as well as paying employees at levels that do not significantly exceed industry averages. If the pay gap between adjacent job levels is widened, mid- and senior-level salaries are set to be excessively high, contrary to the original principle of the cost leadership strategy. Therefore, companies need to maintain a delicate balance between setting appropriate pay gaps between job levels that are not only high enough to motivate average employees to increase productivity and effort, but also low enough to ensure that they do not hinder their strategic cost-control goals. The existing literature suggests that, compared to the differentiated firms, top executives of low-cost firms are best at maximizing the motivation of their human resources with limited compensation resources to achieve the optimal allocation of assets, equipment, and other resources [
26]. All in all, it can be inferred that firms implementing cost leadership strategies tend to reduce the EECG to some extent.
H2: Cost leadership strategy has a significant negative impact on the EECG.
The level of marketization is used to reflect the quality of the relationship between the government and the market, the development of the non-state economy, the development of product and factor markets, market intermediary organizations, and the legal environment system [
27].
First of all, the higher the marketization process, the more intense the market competition and talent competition become, which would lead to greater labor mobility. There are significant differences in average wages between regions in China. For example, the average pay gap in the eastern regions was generally higher from 2004 to 2013 than in the other regions. A favorable market environment significantly reduces the noise of the relationship between the corporate strategy and the effort level of the strategic decision-makers, and further helps strengthen the link between the sustainable competitive strategy and the executives’ contributions [
28]. At this time, in order to enhance the professional competence of executives and improve their work engagement, especially proactively providing forward-looking decision-making advice on corporate competitive strategy from a long-term competitiveness perspective, companies would like to pay more attention to executives’ efforts in developing corporate strategic solutions and actively pursuing a sustainable competitive strategy, and tend to provide them with more attractive compensation contracts. Tournament theory believes that increasing EECG will provide strong incentives for executives and, ultimately, improve company performance. A well-designed pay gap can effectively motivate executives [
29] and, at the same time, reduce the pressure to lose good talent.
For companies implementing differentiated strategies with a higher marketization degree, executives’ difficulties in making and implementing differentiated strategic decisions are greatly strengthened, and, at the same time, spending on retaining valuable executives increases more sharply. Therefore, marketization degree improves the positive relationship between the differentiation strategy and the EECG. For firms implementing cost leadership strategies with higher degrees of marketization, executives’ difficulties in making and implementing low-cost strategic decisions are greatly reduced, and their bargaining power over pay is significantly reduced, due to the relative wealth of professional managers with cost leadership strategy capabilities in the Manager Market. Therefore, the marketization process reinforces the negative impact of the cost leadership strategy on the EECG.
Secondly, the regions with a lower marketization degree in China are mostly located in the central and western regions, which are relatively backward in terms of social and cultural development, compared with the eastern regions. People in such regions are relatively conservative in their mindsets and severely imprisoned by the traditional concept of the income distribution of “fairness over everything”, and relatively narrow salary structures between different ranks are more likely to be accepted by employees. In addition, the degree of government intervention in the company’s operations is higher in regions with a lower marketization degree [
30]. According to the theory of management power, if the compensation system arrangement of an enterprise is sufficiently transparent, and if senior executives receive compensation from the enterprise far exceeding the amount they deserve under the fair trade model, it will cause complaints from external personnel of the enterprise, and this negative reaction will bring external angry costs to senior executives. Under the influence of both government and public opinion, the “cost of external anger” directly limits the EECG within the company. At this point, to alleviate public discontent with the unequal distribution of income [
31,
32], firms must control the “excessive” growth of the EECG. By contrast, when the marketization process gets higher and the economy develops well, individuals will become more open-minded and inclusive, and their “psychological threshold” for the EECG to change from a reasonable level to an unfair one becomes higher, which means they are more receptive to the EECG. With the increasing marketization process, the government’s intervention in enterprises is becoming less and less.
For enterprises implementing the differentiated strategy, from the perspective of the tournament incentive effects of the pay gap, since the competitive strategies implemented by enterprises need to be related to the compensation design of positions at each level within the enterprises, the EECG tends to increase in accordance with the requirements of the market [
33]. For enterprises implementing the cost leadership strategy, when the marketization process increases, it will be more conducive for such enterprises to play their strategic characteristics. Business leaders committed to cost reduction are best placed to use limited compensation resources to maximize internal motivation, achieve optimal allocation of assets, equipment, and other resources, and place greater emphasis on reducing EECG within businesses. Therefore, the marketing process significantly enhances the promotional effects of the differentiation strategy on the EECG, while, at the same time, the degree of marketing reinforces the marketization degree of the negative effects of the cost leadership strategy on the EECG.
Finally, in regions with poor marketization processes, the degree of standardization of social governance and the legal environment are relatively lagging behind, and enterprises are subject to great resistance to creating differentiated or low-cost competitive advantages; whereas, regions with high marketization processes enjoy a relatively higher degree of standardization of social governance, more abundant social and human capital, a higher degree of foreign capital introduction, and greater economic volume, which form external supportive conditions for the development of enterprises and lay a better material foundation for the implementation of both competitive strategies [
34]. According to the theory of resource dependence, the survival and development of enterprises depend on obtaining resources from the external environment. Therefore, the higher the marketization degree, the higher the government’s support for the implementation of competitive strategies. In addition, the higher the marketization degree, the more the government deregulates compensation within enterprises, leading to a relatively free mechanism for determining compensation. In this case, the pricing of human capital is dominated by the market.
In view of this, in regions with a higher marketization degree, enterprises will actively adjust executive compensation contracts in order to pursue profit maximization [
35]. Therefore, in firms implementing differentiated strategies, market-based compensation mechanisms play a key role in compensation incentives by increasing compensation levels for executives and widening the pay gap across different job levels within firms. In companies with a cost leadership strategy, the increased marketization degree also provides a strong guarantee that the company will be able to produce large quantities of goods with specified quality standards, which is more conducive to the formation of economies of scale, leading to a higher link between cost leadership and the EECG. Therefore, the marketization degree can strengthen the relationship between competitive strategies and the EECG.
H3: The marketization degree reinforces the positive relationship between the differentiation strategy and the EECG.
H4: The marketization degree reinforces the negative relationship between the cost leadership strategy and the EECG.
5. Further Exploration
- a.
Impact of the fit between the competitive strategy and the EECG on firm performance
Since the 1980s, Gmoez Mejia, an expert in human resource management in the United States, has introduced the concept of “matching” into the field of compensation for the first time, arguing that the compensation strategy of a company should change along with changes in the strategic environment and corporate strategy. Matching the competitive strategy with the compensation strategy is conducive to improving the company’s innovation capacity, thus enabling the company to capture profits in competition and achieve a sustainable competitive advantage. Based on the above empirical results of this paper, the competitive strategy may affect the EECG.
Therefore, it is more relevant for enterprise development to consider in-depth the performance consequences of matching strategic choices for sustainable competition with EECG. Tournament theory and behavioral theory illustrate the business performance consequences of EECG from two opposing perspectives. Tournament theory believes that broadening the EECG can lead to healthy competition, motivate employees to work hard, and thus improve corporate performance [
45]; in contrast, the behavioral theory believes that a too large EECG can trigger a sense of unfairness among employees [
43], bring vicious jealousy, and be detrimental to team cohesion and firm performance [
46].
To explore the impact of matching the competitive strategy and the EECG on firm performance, we divide the whole sample into a strong differentiation sub-sample (S_DIFF) and a weak differentiation sub-sample (W_DIFF), by taking the mean value of DIFF as the dividing point, and then dividing the whole sample into a strong cost leadership sub-sample (S_COST) and a weak cost leadership sub-sample (W_COST) by taking the mean value of COST as the dividing point. The return on total assets (ROA
t+1) in period t + 1 is used as the dependent variable, and the primary term of the EECG, the squared term of the EECG, and the selected control variables are included in the same regression model (Model (5), Model (6)). To test the effect of EECG on firm performance under different competitive strategy strengths, the grouped regression results are shown in
Table 8.
Analyzing Columns II-V of
Table 8, the A_EECG coefficient was significantly negative at 1% and the A_EECG
2 coefficient was significantly positive at 1% in the S_DIFF sub-sample. It can be argued that when firms implement a highly differentiated strategy, the U-shaped relationship between the EECG and corporate performance is evident. Similarly, in the W_DIFF sub-sample, the S_COST sub-sample, and the W_COST sub-sample, the positive U-shaped relationships between the EECG and firm performance remain significant. It can be seen that when the EECG is very small, behavioral theory dominates. At this time, employees who are accustomed to “extreme equality” will be psychologically uncomfortable or even show “vicious jealousy” when the EECG increases, which will have a negative impact on corporate performance, while, when the EECG is larger, tournament theory dominates [
47]. At this time, employees who have adapted to the principle of “pay for performance or merit” will have more “benign envy” and positive motivation when they face an appropriate increase in the EECG, which will ultimately promote the improvement of corporate performance.
Based on the above regression results, a comparative analysis of the positive U-shaped effect of the EECG on future firm performance under different competitive strategy intensities is proposed, as shown in
Figure 1 and
Figure 2. The figures show that the symmetry of the U-shaped curve symmetry axis under the weak cost leadership strategy is to the left of the U-shaped curve symmetry axis under the weaker differentiation strategy, while the symmetry axis of the U-shaped curve under the weak cost leadership strategy lies to the left of the symmetry axis of the U-shaped curve under the strong cost leadership strategy. In other words, firms with a strong differentiation strategy are able to exploit the tournament incentive effect of the EECG more fully than firms with a weak differentiation strategy, while firms with a strong cost leadership strategy are relatively less able to exploit the tournament incentive effect of the EECG than firms with a weak cost leadership strategy. However, overall results show that both differentiation and cost leadership strategies can effectively improve firm performance when matched with a higher EECG within a reasonable range.
For firms on the right side of the symmetry axis of the U-shaped curve in
Figure 1 and
Figure 2, the larger the EECG, the better the future firm performance will be. Following this logic, the EECG appears to be infinitely expandable, which is obviously questionable. In view of this, the sample is sorted according to the EECG from the lowest to the highest, starting from the 75% quantile of the EECG, and using two percentage points as incremental units to construct the “>75% quantile sub-sample”, “>77% quantile sub-sample”, “>79% quantile sub-sample”, …, and “>99% quantile sub-sample”, etc. A series of regression results are shown in
Figure 3. Columns VI to VIII of
Table 5 report the typical regression results of Model (7), i.e., “>81% quantile sub-sample”, “>83% quantile sub-sample”, and “>91% quantile sub-sample”. The results show that the overall effect of the EECG on firm performance has shifted from positive to negative if the excessive range of the EECG is too high.
To be specific, the EECG had a significant positive effect on firm performance (p < 0.05) at and before the 81% quantification of the EECG; the positive effect of the EECG on firm performance at the 83% to 89% quantification began to be insignificant at the 10% level; and the effect of the EECG on firm performance after the 91% quantification began to show a trend of negative effect. This indicates that the marginal contribution of the EECG decreases on the right side of the U-shaped curve. The positive effect of higher EECG (83–89%) on business performance has gradually diminished, and extreme EECG (≥91%) shows a tendency to reduce business performance. Therefore, it is reasonable to infer that it is not wise to enhance business performance by infinitely widening the pay gap, which will only lead to more losses than gains.
- b.
The moderating role of female executives in influencing the link between competitive strategy and firm performance
Introducing the ratio of the number of female executives to the number of all executives (RFEMALE) and its cross-item with DIFF (RFEMALE*DIFF) into Model (5), Model (5′) was built. Similarly, with the introduction of RFEMALE and its COST cross-item (RFEMALE*COST) into Model (6), Model (6′) was constructed. The regression results of Model (5′) show that the RFEMALE*DIFF coefficient on ROA
t+1 is significantly negative, indicating that the degree of participation of female executives in corporate governance would harm the performance consequences of the differentiation strategy. The regression results of Model (6′) show that the RFEMALE*COST coefficient on ROA
t+1 is significantly negative, indicating that the degree of participation of female executives in corporate governance would improve the performance consequences of the cost leadership strategy. Results are reported in Column VI to Column X of
Table 8.
6. Discussion and Conclusions
6.1. Conclusions
In response to the latest call for research on strategic human resource management, the impact of strategic choice of sustainable competition on EECG is explored. This paper examines the relationship between the competitive strategy and the EECG using balanced panel data of A-share listed manufacturing companies in Shanghai and Shenzhen Stock Exchange over 2008–2017 as the research sample, and further investigates the moderating role of the marketization degree in the relationship between the two by applying Factor Analysis, Fixed Effects Regression, and Multiple Linear Regression Analysis based on OLS. The empirical results confirmed that the differentiation strategy has a facilitating effect on the EECG, and the marketization degree strengthens the facilitating effect; the cost leadership strategy has a restraining effect on the EECG, and the marketization degree also strengthens the restraining effect.
Further findings suggest that both differentiation and cost leadership strategies need to be matched with a larger EECG to facilitate performance improvement. Therefore, for the implementation of the differentiation strategy, companies should systematically expand the EECG, continuously giving full play to their competitive advantage of differentiation and increasing the degree of differentiation strategy to improve corporate performance. For enterprises aiming to be cost leaders, since the cost leadership strategy itself tends to inhibit the EECG, they should pay particular attention to how they can overcome the inhibitory effect of the cost leadership strategy on the EECG.
6.2. Theoretical Contributions
The potential theoretical contributions of this study include at least two aspects: firstly, it expands the research on the formation mechanism of the EECG, enriches the research on the consequences of the sustainable competitive strategy, and clarifies the influence mechanisms of the differentiation strategy and the cost leadership strategy on the EECG; secondly, it confirms the contingent nature of the relationship between the competitive strategy and the EECG, i.e., the moderating effect of the marketization degree. It provides a theoretical direction for the government to continuously promote economic system reform and improve economic efficiency.
6.3. Managerial Implications
On the one hand, from the government’s perspective, it should continue to deepen the reform of the economic system, make efforts to promote the marketization process in China, use market forces to guide compensation incentives for executives, and promote the EECG of listed companies to maintain a relatively high, but reasonable, level. The government needs to reduce its intervention in the market and businesses need to improve the marketization process in each region as a whole and play the role of effective market regulation. From the company’s perspective, a clear competitive strategy and the matching of the EECG will bring the company rich profits. In contemporary society, to achieve sustainable development, enterprises face complex and all-round competition, which is not only constrained by hardware such as resources, environment, facilities, and equipment, but also by software such as policies, regulations, and management, etc. It is crucial to establish the right development goals and choose the right competitive strategy. Therefore, enterprises should clarify their strategic direction, spare no effort to build a platform to create a competitive strategy suitable for their development, and give full play to their strategic advantages so that they can take their place in fierce market competition, which can enable them to gain stable monopoly power in competition and thus maintain a high level of profitability.
On the other hand, extreme events concerning the excessive incentive of executive compensation in recent years, such as the frequent reports about “sky-high salaries” of Lenovo, LeTV, Shuanghui, and other listed companies, should be treated differently. The above significant pay gaps are abnormal and belong to corporate governance events that are not in line with the law of economic development and the orderly development of society. The “sky-high salaries” have been excessively interpreted and even maliciously speculated by the public from all walks of life, and have been subject to controversy and continuous fermentation, forming a “psychological pay gap” in the public. The public condemnation of “overpriced compensation” has a demonstration effect that far exceeds the harm caused by the incident itself. A series of abnormal wage events have triggered and amplified people’s interpretation of the unfair distribution of labor income. Through the social communication mechanism of “generalization of individual extreme events”, the very few events of “sky-high wages” in practice have distorted the public’s psychological perception of the objective wage gap and seriously damaged harmonious social–labor relations. As a result, the micro-corporate behavior of the ever-increasingly widening EECG has gradually accumulated into an insurmountable pay gap in the public psyche, an unreasonable macro-social phenomenon. Therefore, for companies with the highest EECG, it is no longer effective to improve business performance by broadening the EECG, and it may even produce the opposite result. For companies where the EECG is in the normal range, an increase in the EECG can still contribute to performance improvement.
6.4. Limitations and Prospects
There are several limitations to this paper. Firstly, limited by time and effort, only the data of listed A-share manufacturing companies in China from 2008 to 2017 are selected as the sample. Therefore, the scope of the study is relatively narrow, while future research should include data from listed companies over a longer period of time, and also attempt to collect data from non-listed companies in a wider range to improve the empirical basis of this study. Secondly, limited by the availability of objective data, the lack of investigation and analysis of the subjective data, such as the psychological processes and psychological variables, creates speculation on the influence mechanism of the competitive strategy of the EECG’s lack of direct data verification. Therefore, future research should attempt to directly collect psychological perceptual data from relevant subjects such as CEOs, executives, and shareholders in compensation decision-making processes to accurately analyze the roles and motivations of each party in such processes. Thirdly, due to environmental differences, the marketization degree varies significantly from region to region in China. Regional controls should therefore be increased in future studies. Fourthly, the pay gap within an enterprise is a multidimensional concept, and the EECG cannot reflect its full picture. Future research can also include other dimensions such as the executives’ pay gap, executives’ gender pay gap, and the inter-employee pay gap, and conduct comparative studies on them. Finally, while the EECG can trigger a range of agency issues, it can also guide and retain core talent and stimulate enthusiasm at all levels of work. Therefore, future research could attempt to pay particular attention to companies with large executive pay gaps (the top 10%), assess in real-time whether excessive compensation incentives are detrimental to shareholders and other stakeholders, and prevent executives from turning corporate strategies into personal profit-seeking tools.