1. Introduction
The Chinese government attaches great importance to rural revitalization, as well as agricultural product production and quality safety. As stated in the No.1 Document which was published by the State Council and the Central Committee of the Communist Party of China at the beginning of 2022, to comprehensively promoting rural revitalization, the development of agricultural socialization services should be accelerated, and entities including agricultural service firms, farmers’ cooperatives, rural collective economic organizations, and others, should be supported to actively carry out business activities such as contract farming, logistical processing, product marketing, and so on. Under the model of contract farming, farmers produce the products completely according to the requirements of enterprises, and the types, quality, and quantity of products are more in line with market demands compared with other business models, which can to some extent solve the contradiction between small production and large markets of agricultural products in China, and help farmers better cope with prices fluctuations and imbalances between supply and demand [
1]. Due to government support and market operation, contract-farming has gradually become one of the important forms of cooperation between farmers and enterprises in agricultural industrialization. It plays a positive role in improving their performance and promoting modern agricultural development and rural revitalization [
2]. As is known, under the influence of political, military, environmental, and other factors, the development of the world economy is highly uncertain, and agriculture is the same. Under the influence of factors such as economic environment, e-commerce, consumers, technology, and climate, the demands and yields of the products are always stochastic, so the supply chain players have optimal decisions about order (or production) quantity [
3,
4,
5,
6]. When the supplier’s supply quantity is uncertain due to random yield, distributors often do not know how to choose transaction contracts to maximize their profits. Therefore, we propose the following research questions and objectives: for the contract Farming supply chain composed of a dealer and suppliers (such as farmers, farmers’ cooperatives, and so on), the dealer orders products and signs a contract with the suppliers according to demand forecasting before the production of agricultural products, when the demand and yield of agricultural products are random and the supply of a supplier is flexible. We establish three models, including a wholesale price contract, centralized decision making, and a mixed wholesale-option-contract. Under different models, we examine the optimal order and production quantity decisions of each organization and compare the differences in their profits, then we analyze the advantages of the mixed wholesale-option-contract and put forward the conditions that should be met to achieve Pareto improvement for each organization under mixed contracts.
Based on the research on the above issues, the theoretical significance of the paper is as follows: in response to the highly uncertain world economy, when the supply of the upstream organization is flexible, it first proposes a mixed wholesale-option-contract for the downstream distributor when the distributor can trade with more than two suppliers, and theoretical derivation and numerical analysis are carried out to examine mixed contracts’ advantages in supply chain coordination and benefit allocation. This work can enrich the theory of supply chain management and contract coordination. The practical values of this paper is as follows: for the contract farming supply chain in China with uncertain supply and demand, optimization measures and policy recommendations are proposed in terms of business collaboration, supply mode, transaction contracts, supplier management and supervision, interest coordination, price decision making and structural reform of agricultural products on the supply side, which can promote high-quality development of China’s agricultural product industry, and meet the specific requirements of rural revitalization and lofty goal of achieving the Chinese path to modernization that proposed by China today.
2. Literature Review
For the contract farming supply chain, Peng and Pang (2020) built a sequential supply chain game model to decide prices of all entities and planting area of the supplier under an agricultural subsidy policy when the yields are subject to uniform distribution [
7]. Chen and Yano (2010) proposed a risk compensation contract to achieve supply chain coordination while the weather impact market demands of products [
4]. Inderfurth and Clemens (2014) and Ling et al. (2013) successively designed a risk sharing mechanism to improve supply chain performance [
8,
9]. Dan et al. (2013) designed revenue sharing and risk compensation mechanisms which are related to a weather index and farmers’ risk aversion to coordinate supply chains [
10].
The above studies all built game models and designed coordination mechanisms based on wholesale price contracts and obtaining optimal decisions about prices and order or production quantities. Compared to wholesale price contracts, option contracts have significant advantages in responding to demands and price fluctuations, and can provide buyers with opportunities for delayed selection and flexible ordering [
11,
12,
13]. The main research on option contracts with uncertain demand or supply are as follows.
For the general product supply chain, Zhao et al. (2013) and Luo and Chen (2017) compared option contracts with wholesale price and purchase discount contracts [
11,
12]. Wang and Chen (2015) compared joint ordering strategies including option and wholesale price contracts with a single ordering strategy [
14]. Zhu and Hu (2014), as well as Zhang and Luo (2016) proposed a supply chain coordination contract based on the combination of options and quantity flexibility [
15,
16]. Wang et al. (2017) and Hamed et al. (2016) proposed a revenue sharing contract and joint mechanisms of a spot purchase and out of stock penalties based on call option contracts [
17,
18]. Cao and Chen (2023) introduced the combined call and put options for the two-level supply chain system to achieve supply chain coordination [
19]. Zhang (2023) constructed an ordering and dual reserve decision model based on option contracts and studies the conditions satisfied by option contracts to achieve supply chain coordination [
20]. Peng et al. (2022) investigated the production and procurement plans in a two-echelon supply chain, the study show that a pure option contract only can coordinate supply chain with perfect market signal and a novel option contract with buyback mechanism can achieve supply chain coordination with imperfect market signal [
21].
For the green product supply chain, Mohamad et al. (2021) compared a call option contract and a revenue-sharing contract for a two-echelon supply chain network containing one retailer and two suppliers (a non-green supplier and a green supplier). The results show that both proposed contracts create a win–win situation for each member and heighten the profitability of the entire SC [
22]. Mohamad and Jafar (2022) developed and compared a penalty-based contract and a modified call option contract mixed with a cost-sharing mechanism and discovered that the proposed reservation-based contract outperforms the penalty-based contract for both parties’ profitability and retailing channel’s improvement [
23].
For the relief supply chain, Li et al. (2023), Meng et al. (2023), and Patra and Jha (2022) designed bidirectional option contracts (BOC) to coordinate of the relief supply chain, analyze the optimal reserve decisions of the purchaser and compare the results of BOC with the benchmark wholesale price contract to show the superiority of BOC [
24,
25,
26]. Ghavamifar et al. (2022) proposed a novel hybrid relief procurement contract with an option contract and quantity flexibility to coordinate the relief supply chain and revealed that the proposed contract can significantly improve the procurement process by reducing the shortage and overstocking risks in humanitarian organizations [
27].
Regarding contract farming or agricultural product supply chains, Cao and Shi (2016) constructed a profit maximization model based on option contracts when the natural factors influencing the growing of the crops [
28]. Under the influence of adverse weather in a contract farming supply chain, Fu and Dan (2015) designed a mechanism of “weather (call) option + risk compensation + franchise fee” to ensure the income of the company and farmers [
29]. When the information of freshness or cost is symmetrical or asymmetric, Tang et al. (2019) put forward the conditions about option pricing and cost sharing to achieve supply chain coordination [
30]. As the supply of fresh agricultural products fluctuates greatly, Yu et al. (2022) introduced CVaR and option contracts to obtain the optimal ordering and production decisions and coordinate the supply chain [
31]. Zhao and Cheng (2023) considered the freshness-keeping effort and proposed an option contract to realize the coordination and optimization of a two-echelon supply chain [
32].
The above studies, which research the wholesale price contract or option contracts, are all based on fix supply, which means that the supply quantity of the manufacturer (or supplier) must be equal to the order quantity of the buyer. In fact, when the dealer orders goods from the supplier, the supplier often fail to supply on time, with quality and quantity problems as a result of uncontrollable factors, so the supplier can provide part of or more than the order quantity to the dealer when the delivery time is coming, this is means ‘flexible supply’ [
33,
34]. Some research studies supply chain decision making and coordination mechanisms based on the mode of flexible supply. He and Zhang (2017) proposed a flexible procurement mode for the manufacturer, to then derive the optimal ordering decisions and coordination conditions for single-source and dual-source ordering [
35]. Hu et al. (2013) and Pal et al. (2018) studied a procurement model in which the manufacturer can flexibly change the order quantities within a certain range. They successively put forward a revenue sharing coordination mechanism that includes order penalties and price discount, as well as a revenue sharing contract based on supply shortage penalties and cost sharing [
33,
36]. Tang and Kouvelis (2011) found that flexible procurement can alleviate the problems of channel efficiency caused by randomness of suppliers’ outputs [
37]. Jaksic and Franso (2018) found that flexible procurement can reduce overall expected costs [
38]. Wang et al. (2024) constructed a two-stage credit financing model for supply chains based on bidirectional option flexible contracts and the results show that an increase in the bidirectional option price and the exercise price of call options will lead to a decrease in the order quantity of the retailers, while the impact of the exercise price of put options on the order quantity is opposite [
39]. The above research explores the advantages of flexible procurement (or flexible supply), but it is not always advantageous. Demirel et al. (2018) designed a strategy for manufacturers to flexibly purchase from multiple suppliers (including fixed unreliable suppliers and alternative reliable suppliers), and found that, when an alternative supplier exists, the manufacturer’s profits may be worse and the supply chain members’ performance may decline [
40].
The above research indicates that the mode of fixed supply is partly bad for distributors and suppliers because both of them have losses of mismatch between demand and supply, while the mode of flexible supply can avoid farmers’ out-of-stock losses and reduce the risk of excessive expected demands. This mode has important practical significance under the current complex economic situation. On the one hand, it reduces the risk of residual inventory of the buyers, and on the other hand, it is beneficial for the suppliers to alleviate production pressure, so they can focus on product quality rather than the quantity from the order. This paper establishes optimization models of decentralized decision making and centralized decision making for a contract farming supply chain, and proposes a coordination mechanism of a mixed wholesale-option-contract (abbreviated as mixed contracts, the same below) based on flexible supply. It assumes that the buyer signs a wholesale price contract with the preferred supplier and an option contract with the alternative supplier, and the buyer has two ordering opportunities. If the preferred supplier is in short supply, the option will be executed, and the risk of insufficient or excessive inventory for the buyer is reduced as the alternative supplier meets his ordering needs; for the two suppliers, compared to wholesale price contracts, they have two sources of revenue and their profits may increase. Compared to the above studies, this paper has the following innovations. Firstly, a comprehensive coordination mechanism with mixed contracts under the mode of flexible supply is first proposed for both the buyer and suppliers. Secondly, it compares and analyzes the differences between decentralized decision-making and centralized decision-making models under flexible supply with wholesale price contracts, and firstly uses mixed contracts to achieve Pareto improvement of every member in the supply chain. It found that if the option price and the option exercise price are reasonably determined, the profits of all the players are not only higher than that under decentralized decision making, but also may be higher than that under centralized decision making.
The other parts of the paper are as follows.
Section 3 contains the assumptions and parameters for the research.
Section 4 contains the comparison between decentralized and centralized decision making under the mode of flexible supply with a wholesale price contract.
Section 5 is the coordination mechanism of the supply chain based on mixed contracts under flexible supply.
Section 6 is an example analysis. Finally, we put forward suggestions and conclusions in
Section 7.
3. Assumptions and Parameters
3.1. Model Assumptions
Firstly, for a contract farming supply chain consisting of a distributor and two suppliers (which can also be named as farmers), the distributor can sign two types of contracts with suppliers based on demand forecasting to determine the order quantity before the production of agricultural products. The first type is the wholesale price contract, in which only a supplier supplies products to the distributor. I other type is a mixed contract, in which two suppliers produce products (see
Figure 1).
Second, referencing some studies in the literature [
6,
11,
34], the demand and the yield of agricultural products are random. Under the wholesale price contract, with decentralized decision making, the supplier’s supply quantity is flexible, which means the quantity can vary between the dealer’s order quantity and the actual outputs. Then, the dealer and supplier, respectively, determine order or production quantity. Under centralized decision making, the members make decisions as a whole. Under mixed contracts, the dealer signs a wholesale price contract with the preferred supplier and the supply quantity is flexible. At the same time, the dealer signs an option contract with the alternative supplier to reduce the risk of supply and demand mismatch. If the preferred supplier under-supplies, the alternative supplier can supply finished goods in time with good quality, and the quantity is not more than the option order quantity.
Thirdly, the risk of each member is neutral and completely rational, the information related to the decisions is symmetrical, the dealer is the leader while the suppliers are subordinate. Under flexible supply, as the agricultural product is perishable, the buyer may have mismatch costs between supply and demand, while the suppliers do not have shortage costs of outputs. Generally speaking, the normal loss cost and non-conforming product values during the period of growing process are ignored, and there is no damage during the transportation of goods.
Finally, the problems that we study are as follows. Regarding a contract farming supply chain composed of a distributor and two suppliers, based on the mode of flexible supply, optimization models are constructed to compare and analyze the differences in order quantity, production quantity, and expected profits among the members under a wholesale price contract, centralized decision making, and mixed contracts. The advantages of mixed contracts in achieving Pareto improvement of the members of the supply chain are proposed, the impacts of option price and exercise price on the transaction modes are analyzed, and recommendations for the collaborative management mechanism of the contract farming supply chain are put forward.
3.2. Parameters
The parameters are introduced as followed so as to build the models.
We first set prices and demand parameters of the agricultural product: is the retail price, is the wholesale price, is the option price, and is the option exercise price. indicates the demand and it follows a random distribution, and represent the probability density function and cumulative distribution function of in turn, and is the expected value of D.
Then, we set parameters about the dealer: under the wholesale price contract, indicates the initial order quantity, and under mixed contracts, and , respectively, indicate the initial order quantity and option order quantity. is the unit residual value if the dealer has surplus goods after the selling season, and is the unit cost of opportunity losses when the inventory quantity is less than the demand. It is easy to infer that .
The parameters about the suppliers are as follows:
is the qualified rate (i.e., the ratio of the final qualified outputs quantity to the planned production quantity),
and
represent the probability density function and cumulative distribution function of
in turn, and
indicates the expected value of
. Under a wholesale price contract, if
represents the production quantity of the preferred supplier, then the final output quantity is
. Based on the mode of flexible supply,
is used to indicate the supply quantity from the supplier to the distributor. We know that the expression for
X is as follows:
Under mixed contracts, we set that the planned production quantity of the preferred supplier is , and the planned production quantity of the alternative supplier is . To facilitate the comparison of two types of contracts, the following parameters are assigned the same values under different contracts: represents the suppliers’ unit production cost (including purchasing cost), and indicates the unit residual value. Under the wholesale price contract, suppliers do not suffer from losses of insufficient supply. Under mixed contracts, for the alternative supplier, if the supply is less than the quantity required by the distributor when the option is executed, the distributor will make up for it by urgently ordering from the supplier’s peers, with representing the unit emergency procurement cost.
The profit functions are as follows.
represents the profit function of every member in the supply chain, subscript
, or
(representing the distributor, supplier, preferred or alternative suppliers by turn), superscript
, or
, where
represents the wholesale price contract,
represents centralized decision making, and
indicates mixed contracts.
represents the expected value of the corresponding functions. We define the symbols in some equations as below:
Finally, we explain the relationships among some parameters according to this actual situation: all parameters are positive. As the supplier’s excess qualified products are fresher than the distributor, and to make the distributor profitable and avoid unlimited orders or production from the members in the supply chain, we have: . To ensure positive profits for the supplier and avoid unlimited production, we have: . When the supplier’s output is insufficient, his emergency procurement cost will be higher than the wholesale price (otherwise, the distributor will trade with other suppliers), then: . Under mixed contracts, in order to prioritize the signing of a wholesale price contract by the distributor and make it profitable to sign an option contract, we have: . In order to make the option contract valuable, we have: (if the option exercise price is too large, the dealer will not be willing to buy the option, and if it is too small, the alternative supplier would rather store the goods as the surplus inventory than sell the option). Due to , then: . (Note: the above parameters related to price or cost all indicate the average value of the same batch of agricultural products.)
5. Mixed Contracts of Wholesale Price and Option under Flexible Supply
5.1. Modeling and Decisions
Under flexible supply, the supplier can be divided into two entities, namely, a preferred supplier and an alternative supplier. The distributor signs a wholesale price contract with the preferred supplier and an option contract with the alternative supplier, so the distributor has two purchasing opportunities, and the risks of over-inventory or under-supply will be greatly reduced, and the two suppliers obtain returns. Under flexible supply with mixed contracts, the models and related decision are as follows.
Under mixed contracts, the expected profit function of the distributor is:
Equation (14) includes the sales revenue, order cost, residual value, option purchasing cost, option execution cost, and opportunity loss cost of insufficient inventory.
The expected profit function of the preferred supplier is the same as Equation (2), where
I1 is the decision variable.
Let:
. Obviously,
is the expected supply quantity of the alternative supplier, and the profit function of the alternative supplier is (where
I2 is the decision variable) as below:
Equation (16) calculates the option sales revenue, option execution revenue, emergency procurement cost of short supply, residual value, and production cost.
Let:
.
, and the expected profit function of the alternative supplier is:
Under mixed contracts, the decision-making process of each member is as follows. First, the distributor determines the initial order quantity from the preferred supplier. Next, the preferred supplier determines its production quantity. Then, the distributor determines the option order quantity from the alternative supplier based on demand forecasting and the yield distribution of the preferred supplier. Finally, the alternative supplier determines its production quantity based on the quantity of options execution. Based on the above decision-making process, Proposition 3 is proposed.
Proposition 3. Under flexible supply with mixed contracts, and have maximum value, and the decision variable at the maximum point satisfies Equations (19)–(21). Proof about Proposition 3 is as below.
Proof. According to the definition of
, we have:
The first and second derivatives of
,
and
with respect to
and
, are as below:
Let Equations (23) and (24) equal zero. Equations (19) and (20) can be obtained. Due to
:
,
. When Equations (26) and (27) are feasible:
Therefore, the Hesse matrix of is negative about the extreme point, and reaches the maximum at the extreme point. Equation (21) is the same as Equation (6). The existence of the optimal solution for Proposition 3 is explained as follows. From Proposition 1, it is obvious that , and , and Equation (19) is feasible. The range of values for the left and right expressions of Equation (27) is between 0 and 1, so Equation (20) holds. Equation (21) is the same as Equation (6) and it also holds.□
According to Proposition 3, let the dealer’s option order quantity is
, then the optimal production quantity (i.e.,
) of the alternative supplier is expressed as follows:
We can obtain the optimal order quantity of the distributor according to Proposition 3. Regarding Equation (20), let:
If the value of is determined, the value of can be determined based on Equation (19), and the value of can be calculated based on Equation (21), then can be calculated. Obviously, as increases, continues to increase. According to Equation (19), we know: .
If , then and , so: . If: , we have: . At this time, the initial order quantity of the distributor reaches the maximum value, i.e., . The above analysis indicates that if the option price and exercise price are so high that , the distributors will not sign an option contract with the alternative supplier. As a result, mixed contracts are the same as the wholesale price contract. From Proposition 1, it can be inferred that: , .
If , then: , . Combining Equations (19)–(21) to form a system of ternary multiple equations, we solve it to obtain .
According to Equations (19)–(21) and (29), the optimal expected profit functions of the players in the contract farming supply chain under mixed contracts are as below:
5.2. The Impact of Option Price and Option Exercise Price on the Coordination of the Contract Farming Supply Chain
Lemma 3 is proposed to analyze the impact of and on the order quantity of the dealer under mixed contracts.
Lemma 3. Under mixed contracts, is positively correlated with and ; and are negatively correlated with and o.
Proof of Lemma 3. According to Equation (20), is approximately equal to , then: . According to Equation (19), we have: . Since is an increasing function, taking the first derivative of and with respect to or , Lemma 3 can be proved. □
Lemma 4 is put forward to compare the optimal order quantities of the dealer among decentralized decision making, centralized decision, and mixed contracts.
Lemma 4. . If , then: .
Lemma 4 shows that, under the mode of flexible supply, when the values of parameters remain unchanged, the order quantity of the dealer with a wholesale price contract is greater than the initial order quantity with mixed contracts and less than the total order quantities with mixed contract. Under certain conditions, the total order quantity of the dealer under centralized decision making would exceed the total quantity with mixed contracts. Although mixed contracts find it difficult to match centralized decision making in terms of total order quantity, they can achieve Pareto improvement in the profits of the supply chain players by reasonably determining the option and option exercise prices. That is, the profits of the distributor and suppliers (including preferred and alternative suppliers) with mixed contracts can exceed those under a wholesale price contract, and would not be less than the overall profits of the supply chain under centralized decision making. Based on Equations (7), (13) and (30), in order to simplify the optimal expected profits of the distributor under different situations, let:
then Lemma 5 is proposed.
Lemma 5. and are the option price and exercise price under mixed contracts. If the combination of and simultaneously satisfies Equations (33) and (34), mixed contracts with a wholesale price and option can achieve Pareto improvement of the profits of the contract farming supply chain. According to Equations (7), (8), (13) and (30)–(32), when Equations (33) and (34) hold, we have: , and .
Lemma 5 indicates that, when the demand of agricultural products is stochastic and the supply of suppliers is flexible, as the option and option exercise prices are reasonably determined by negotiation, mixed contracts will be an ideal choice for the agricultural supply chain, which can benefit both distributor and suppliers. Due to the complexity of the expressions for the optimal expected profits of the members under different situations, the range of option and exercise prices can be obtained to achieving Pareto improvement of the players by numerical calculations. Numerical analysis will be introduced in
Section 6.
6. Numerical Analysis
A distributor in the Guangdong Province of China orders a batch of local chickens (which can be supplied to catering enterprises or restaurants) from suppliers (or farmers) based on demand forecasting before the sales season. The suppliers have sufficient capacity and the breeding time of local chickens is fixed. As the yield of the preferred supplier is uncertain in the process of breeding, their supply of local chickens is flexible. There are two types of contracts, which are a wholesale price contract and mixed contracts available for transactions between the distributor and suppliers. The parameters are assigned as follows (the unit of quantity is ‘piece’, and the unit of price or cost is CNY).
,
,
,
,
,
,
,
,
,
, and
. Based on Propositions 1–3,
Table 1 is as below by MATLAB R2014a calculation.
From
Table 1, it can be seen that, under the mode of flexible supply, as the preferred and alternative suppliers with mixed contracts belonging to the same entity, compared to the wholesale price contract, the profits of both the distributor and supplier under mixed contract increase, and the sum of their profits is higher than that under centralized decision. The above results illustrate that mixed contracts are better than the wholesale price contract under flexible supply from a profit perspective.
Proposition 3 shows that, under flexible supply with mixed contracts, the initial order quantity of the distributor determines not only his option order quantity, but also the production quantity of the suppliers and the profits of all the supply chain members. In order to analyze the difference between mixed contracts and the wholesale price contract, considering that the initial order quantity of the dealer ranges from 8600 to 10,600 (if it is too small, the residual value may be negative, and if it is too large, it may lead to a negative option order quantity), we can obtain the relations between the optimal expected profits of the supply chain members and initial order quantity of the dealer under different contracts, as shown in
Figure 2.
From
Figure 2a, it can be seen that, as the initial order quantity increases, the expected profit of the distributor continues to increase under the wholesale price contract, while it first increases and then decreases under mixed contracts. Although the profit of the distributor with mixed contracts is higher than that with the wholesale price contract, the gap between them becomes smaller and smaller.
Figure 2b shows that, as the initial order quantity of the distributor increases, the expected profits of the suppliers under mixed contracts decreases sharply. However, they are higher than that with the wholesale price contract. Therefore, under mixed contracts, the suppliers can require the distributor to reduce the initial order quantity as much as possible and increase the option order quantity to add their profits.
When the initial order quantity of the dealer ranges from 8600 to 10,600, the impacts of the wholesale price and mixed contracts on profits of the whole supply chain are analyzed as shown in
Figure 2.
Figure 3 shows that, as the initial order quantity of the distributor increases, the overall expected profit of the supply chain continues to decrease under mixed contracts, and increases under centralized decision making and the wholesale price contract. The gap among them becomes smaller and smaller, and ultimately converges to a point. According to
Figure 2 and
Figure 3, when the demand and yield are uncertain under flexible supply, if there are two or more trading opportunities between the supply chain players, within a feasible range, the smaller the initial order quantity of the dealer, the more advantageous it is for all parties. This is because when the demand and outputs are clear, the second or third transaction can reduce the risk of supply and demand mismatch among all parties.
For this example, when
and
, the optimal expected profits of the distributor and suppliers under mixed contracts are higher than those under the wholesale price contract.
Figure 4,
Figure 5 and
Figure 6 are displayed to analyze the changing patterns of profits for each member under the constant changes of
and
. (Note: each figure has a straight line parallel to the horizontal axis, representing the optimal expected profit of a player under the wholesale price contract.)
Figure 4a indicates the relationship between the optimal expected profit of the dealer and its initial order quantity when
and
varies equally between 30 and 60. From
Figure 4a, it can be seen that, as the initial order quantity increases, the profit of the dealer first increases and then decreases when o is between 30 and 40. When o is between 40 and 60, it continues to rise. As the initial order quantity increases, the gaps between the profits of the dealer under the four different option prices become smaller and smaller, and finally they converge to a point. When
, as the initial order quantity takes any value, the expected profit of the distributor is higher than that with the wholesale price contract; when
, the initial order quantity takes some values (i.e.,
), and it is higher than that with the wholesale price contract; when
or
, it is less than that with the wholesale price contract. The smaller the option price, the smaller the initial order quantity that enables the dealer to achieve the optimal expected profit, and the larger the option order quantity, which verifies Lemma 3.
Figure 4b shows the relationship between the optimal expected profit of suppliers and the initial order quantity of the distributor when
and
varies equally between 30 and 60. From
Figure 4b, we know that, for any order quantity, the higher the option price, the greater the profits of the two suppliers, while the profit of the suppliers is the least under the wholesale price contract. As the initial order quantity increases, the profits of suppliers continue to decline and eventually converge to a single point.
Figure 4 indicates that, under mixed contracts, within a reasonable range, the lower the option price, the more advantageous it is for the dealer and two suppliers; when the initial order quantity is moderate, it is most advantageous for the dealer; the smaller the initial order quantity, the more advantageous it is for the suppliers.
Under mixed contracts, taking
and
as an example,
Figure 5 shows analysis of the impacts of the initial order quantity of the dealer on the sum of profits for the supply chain members. It is shown that, no matter what value the initial order quantity takes, the sum of profits for the members is higher than that under the wholesale price contract; within the range [8600, 10,200], it is higher than that under centralized decision making.
Under mixed contracts, let
, and when
changes equally between 150 and 180,
Figure 6, drawn by MATLAB calculation, shows the results. Obviously,
Figure 6a is similar to
Figure 4a. Within feasible ranges, the smaller the option exercise price, the smaller the initial order quantity that enables the dealer to achieve the optimal expected profit. When
, as the initial order quantity is in a certain range, the dealer’s profit is higher than that under the wholesale price contract. The smaller the option exercise price, the more advantageous it is for the dealer. No matter how the option exercise price changes, it ultimately converges to a point where mixed contracts are becoming like the wholesale price contract and the initial order quantity reaches a certain value.
Figure 6b is similar to
Figure 4b, where the higher the option exercise price, the greater the initial order quantity, the more advantageous it is for the suppliers.
7. Conclusions
For a contract farming supply chain consisting of a distributor and two suppliers with random demand and yield, this paper puts forward a new transaction mode with mixed contracts under flexible supply. The mode is as follows. Under a wholesale price contract, when the preferred supplier may only supply part of the initial order quantity required by the distributor, the distributor will sign an option contract with the alternative supplier and the distributor has a second-order opportunity to reduce the mismatch costs between the demand and the inventory of the goods. Based on flexible supply, using the wholesale price contract as a benchmark, this paper compares and analyzes the differences in decision making of order quantities and expected profits of the supply chain players among three trading modes, which are decentralized decision making, centralized decision making, and mixed contracts. The conclusions are as follows by theoretical derivation and numerical analysis.
First, we demonstrated that the expected profit functions of the supply chain members under three trading modes are all concave and obtained the optimal order and production quantities. Then, we proved that the order quantity of the dealer is the largest under centralized decision making, followed by mixed contracts, and the smallest under wholesale price contract; compared to the wholesale price contract, the production quantity of the supplier under centralized decision making is closer to the order quantity of the distributor.
Second, under mixed contracts, within a feasible range, the smaller the option price (or option exercise price), the smaller the initial order quantity for the dealer to achieve optimal profits, and the larger the expected profits; as the initial order quantity increases, the gap between profits of the distributor under three trading modes continues to narrow, and ultimately tends towards the same point.
Third, under certain conditions, compared to the wholesale price contract, mixed contracts are more advantageous for the distributor, suppliers, and the overall supply chain, and the smaller the option price (or option exercise price), the more advantageous they are.
Suggestions are proposed for the transaction and development of the contract farming supply chain under random demand and yield.
Firstly, both dealers and suppliers should fully use historical data, and apply a combination of qualitative and quantitative methods to forecast the trend of the agricultural product industry. As decisions about the order and production quantities of upstream and downstream enterprises are interrelated, they should establish a coordination department to strengthen mutual cooperation and communication.
Secondly, under a wholesale price contract, compared to fixed supply, the mode of flexible supply has the advantages of reducing mismatch costs for the players. Under flexible supply and certain conditions, compared to a wholesale price contract, mixed contracts are more helpful to them.
Thirdly, as a leader of the agricultural supply chain, the distributor should take the following measures to better implement mixed contracts. First, the distributor should fully investigate the price and quality of the agricultural products, and reputation and character of the suppliers. Second, the distributor should explicitly define the process, content, and time of signing the contracts and carry out the contracts to adapt to changes in supply and demand. Third, under flexible supply, the distributor can establish real-time supervision mechanisms to avoid the preferred supplier intentionally concealing the actual outputs, and the distributor can require the alternative supplier to timely fulfil the options. Fourth, information sharing and interest coordination mechanisms should be established to promote long-term and stable cooperation between the players, and the option and option exercise prices should be reasonably determined.
Fourthly, the agricultural product production is related to supply side structural reform and rural revitalization. As quasi-operational resources, agricultural products have both public welfare and commercial characteristics. To promote the sustainable development of the agricultural product industry, on the one hand, enterprises need to participate in market competition based on market rules, minimize production risks, improve quality and circulation efficiency, and strengthen the matching of supply and demand of agricultural products. On the other hand, it is necessary for the government to enforce planning, guidance, supervision, and management of the agricultural product industry, strengthen quality and safety supervision of agricultural products, promote the consumption of green and organic agricultural products, and provide financial subsidies, tax exemptions, and other support to the suppliers.
There are some limitations in this paper. For example, it did not consider price decisions among supply chain members and did not compare mixed contracts with other coordinated contracts. The following questions are worth further investigation based on the above research. First, under the mode of flexible supply, the maximum supply quantity of the supplier can exceed the initial order volume of the distributor. Second, for an agricultural supply chain composed of two distributors and two suppliers, there is price competition among distributors and quality competition among suppliers. Third, if the supply chain members improve the quality and yield rate of products through investment, there is a correlation between demands, quality, and investment costs of the product. Regarding the above problems, we can establish models to obtain optimal decisions and analyze the differences in expected profits under various transaction modes.