1. Introduction
In many countries, public debt plays a significant role in financing development by providing the necessary funds for investment in infrastructure, education, healthcare, social welfare programs, and other development projects. Particularly in developing economies, where the development needs are high but the fiscal systems are severely strained and resources are scarce, public debt serves as a crucial source of financing for initiatives aimed at promoting economic growth, reducing poverty, and improving the living standards of citizens, as recent studies suggest [
1,
2]. Nevertheless, the relationship between debt and development is one between friends and foes; debt mismanagement, excessive borrowing, and debt accumulation may pose substantial risks to macroeconomic stability and hinder future development efforts [
3,
4].
In Cameroon, as in many other developing economies, public debt was used as a tool for mobilizing additional resources and supporting growth. Up to the beginning of the 1980s, Cameroon practiced a prudent debt policy, and the increase in external debt, although continuous, led to only moderate debt levels compared to similar countries. Nevertheless, starting in the mid-1980s, the situation changed. Cameroon faced serious cash deficits and devalued the CFA franc to stimulate exports and restore budget balance, while the bulk of its debt was denominated in foreign currency. However, the expected positive effects were not observed, and external debt increased steadily and more than tripled over the following decade. In 1996, the Bretton Woods institutions launched the Heavily Indebted Poor Countries (HIPC) initiative to alleviate the debt burden of developing countries. Cameroon joined this initiative and reached the completion point in 2005, benefiting from a reduction in its debt. In 2020, the country was granted a moratorium on its debt because of the COVID-19 pandemic. The G20’s debt-suspension initiative allowed Cameroon to postpone the payment of
$108 million in external debt in 2020 [
5]. Such initiatives as HIPC and IMF interventions are tools used to help developing countries cope with their economic difficulties and reduce their debt. At present, although public debt is well below the 70% of GDP threshold set as a convergence criterion by CEMAC (Central African Economic and Monetary Community) member states, Cameroon is facing a high risk of debt distress. This underscores the high importance of prudent debt management and the appropriate choice of future sources of funding to avoid unfavorable debt developments while also allowing the government to reach a wide range of economic and social goals.
The economy of a developing country like Cameroon is therefore faced with a complex dilemma when it comes to financing economic initiatives and supporting development. One of the core questions is whether the government should rely on foreign or domestic debt to finance its projects. This decision is not simply a matter of weighing the pros and cons but also requires an in-depth analysis of the economic and social externalities associated with each option.
Theory suggests that both external and domestic debt may have advantages and disadvantages. External debt allows for rapid access to substantial financial resources, enabling the financing of large-scale infrastructure and development projects [
6,
7]. It also makes it possible to benefit from the foreign knowledge and expertise needed to implement these projects effectively [
8]. However, external debt can also lead to economic dependence on foreign creditors, with potential implications for national sovereignty and economic policy [
9]. Alternatively, domestic debt offers a higher degree of independence and economic control, as the government can mobilize financial resources internally, mainly by issuing bonds [
10]. This allows it to diversify its sources of finance and make more autonomous development decisions [
11,
12]. However, excessive reliance on domestic debt can also lead to an accumulation of unsustainable debt, inflation, and higher interest rates, which in turn can undermine economic stability and investor confidence [
13,
14].
In recent years, the effects of overall public or external debt in developing economies have been extensively investigated, with most of the studies focusing on the debt-growth nexus in one individual country or a group of countries. While some researchers looked at the direct effects of debt on economic growth or identified a debt threshold [
15,
16,
17,
18,
19,
20], others focused on the factors moderating debt’s impact on growth, like the liquidity of the economy [
21], the stability of macroeconomic policies [
22], or the quality of institutions [
18]. With regard to domestic public debt, a few studies focused on crowding-out effects and investigated its impact on private investment [
23] or corporate debt [
24]. All these studies have contributed to our understanding of public debt issues and clearly emphasized the importance of domestic and external debt in financing development. Nevertheless, without disregarding the contribution of growth-focused studies, we appreciate that they offer an incomplete picture of the complex network of effects linking government debt financing to development.
Against this background, our study aims to comparatively assess, through externalities, the impacts of external and domestic government debt as methods of financing development in Cameroon. While reaching economic goals is of high importance to developing countries, we advocate for a wider approach that integrates economic and social considerations when choosing the appropriate source of funding. Therefore, we combine macroeconomic and microeconomic approaches to simulate the long-term effects of an increase in Cameroon’s foreign and domestic debt on various economic and social indicators such as production, prices, household welfare, income inequality, and poverty.
This study stands out in several respects. First, it offers an integrative and comparative approach to the impact of external and domestic public debt on Cameroon’s development. Unlike previous research that focuses primarily on the effects of debt on economic growth, our work takes a broader perspective by examining the economic and social impacts associated with each type of debt. Second, we consider economic and social externalities in the analysis, which are essential to assessing the indirect effects of financing choices on an economy. In particular, external debt can contribute to an increase in imports of goods and services, which may have a negative impact on the balance of trade [
25]. Moreover, domestic debt can affect the availability of bank loans for the private sector, which may hamper investment and economic growth in the long run [
26]. Third, by using a dynamic computable general equilibrium (CGE) model coupled with a microsimulation analysis, we are able to capture the complex interactions between different sectors of the economy and estimate the long-term sectoral and social impacts of financing choices. This innovative methodology not only assesses the direct effects of debt on economic growth but also emphasizes the indirect consequences on income distribution, poverty, and inequality.
By focusing on the specific case of Cameroon, this study provides empirical support for concrete policy recommendations that are tailored to local realities. Therefore, our research could be useful to public authorities in Cameroon for designing debt strategies that maximize the positive effects of government interventions. In addition, our study opens perspectives that are applicable to other developing countries. Cameroon’s situation in terms of public debt, whether foreign or domestic, is relevant not only for the country itself but also for the international community. As a developing country with a diversified economy and abundant natural resources, Cameroon represents a relevant case study for understanding debt dynamics and its impact on economic development, and the lessons learned from the Cameroonian experience can be applied to other developing countries facing similar economic conditions and development financing challenges. By exploring the externalities associated with public debt, this study contributes to a broader debate on sustainable development financing strategies, offering valuable insights for international financial institutions, and policymakers and researchers in all developing countries.
The structure of this paper is as follows: we begin by briefly presenting some facts about Cameroon’s external and domestic debt dynamics in
Section 2; in
Section 3, we review the existing literature to explore the potential effects of different indebtedness options; in
Section 4, we describe the methodological approach;
Section 5 presents the results and discusses their implications; and finally, in
Section 6, we conclude by summarizing the main results and identifying policy implications and recommendations for the choice of financing for Cameroon’s development.
2. Overview of Cameroon’s Foreign and Domestic Debt Trends
In this section, we briefly explore the evolution of Cameroon’s debt. The data in
Figure 1 give us valuable insights into external and domestic debt fluctuations over the period 2000–2021, in both nominal and relative terms. When distinguishing between domestic and foreign debt, we consider the criterion of creditors’ residence; therefore, domestic debt refers to the government borrowing from domestic creditors, while external debt refers to borrowing from foreign creditors.
The total stock of external debt increased from
$10.6 billion in 2000 to
$15.4 billion in 2021 (
Figure 1a). Nevertheless, this general trend hides changing dynamics over the years. External debt decreased up to 2005, given the government’s efforts to reduce the debt burden and improve the country’s economic situation. A sharp decrease was further registered in 2006, followed by a slight decline between 2006 and 2011 because of the commitments undertaken and support granted by international creditors under the enhanced HIPC. Nevertheless, from 2011 to 2021, external debt grew significantly because of increased external borrowing to finance infrastructure projects or cover budget deficits.
The overall rise in the country’s external debt over the years resulted mostly from additional government liabilities. External public and publicly guaranteed debt closely followed the trend of total external debt, rising from
$8.8 billion in 2000 to
$12.4 billion in 2021. Nevertheless, the external debt/GDP ratio dropped from 99.9% in 2000 to 34.2% in 2021, with most of the decrease being registered up to 2011, when external debt recorded a minimum of 6.9% of GDP. Over the same period (2000–2021), external public and publicly guaranteed debt decreased from 82.8% to 27.5% of GDP (
Figure 1b). Moreover, following the same trend, the debt-to-exports ratio fell from 402.1% in 2000 to 206.9% in 2021, at about half its value in 2000 (
Figure 1c).
The analysis of overall public debt data also reveals some important trends over the years (
Figure 1d). Cameroon’s general government debt/GDP ratio decreased from 75.9% in 2000 to a minimum of 11.2% of GDP in 2008 and then increased continuously to 46.8% in 2021 because of the decline in oil revenues, the security crisis, the COVID-19 pandemic, and investment needs in infrastructure. Central government debt represents the bulk of this debt, accounting for about 90% of the total amount (
Figure 1e). In addition, over the period 2015–2021, domestic debt represented no more than 30% of central government debt (
Figure 1f), which emphasizes that foreign creditors are the main providers of funds to the Cameroonian government, which preferred to finance its projects by borrowing externally. Nevertheless, despite the quite similar patterns that domestic and external debt exhibited in recent years, both increasing because of the high financing requirements of the government or the late payments to external creditors, the contribution of domestic creditors slightly improved after 2018. The ratio of domestic debt to overall central government debt rose from 23.7% in 2018 to 28.1% in 2021, which highlights an increased interest in using domestic markets as an alternative to external creditors.
Overall, this brief analysis shows the significant efforts of the government to strike a balance between external and domestic borrowing while focusing on prudent debt management to ensure long-term economic stability. Moreover, it points to an increasing role of domestic creditors as financial resource providers for the government, which substantiates the need for an in-depth comparative analysis of domestic and external debt’s effects.
3. Theoretical Background and Empirical Literature
Financing development through public debt is a major concern for governments and economists in developing countries. In time, several economic theories have been put forward to understand the economic and political aspects of public debt, each making equally important contributions. In addition, many empirical studies explored economic and political factors such as trade balances, exchange rates, interest rates, economic size, and institutional factors to understand how developing countries manage their public debt.
Grounding their arguments on Keynes’ most influential work [
27], Keynesian economists emphasize the positive role of public debt in supporting fiscal policy interventions to stabilize the economy and promote full employment. In times of recession, when aggregate demand falls short of aggregate supply, increased government spending or tax cuts financed through government borrowing may spur economic activity and resume economic growth. Nevertheless, the crowding-out theory (that Keynes himself brought forward but subsequent monetarist economists refined) argues that such positive effects may not occur or be smaller than expected, as an increase in public debt can lead to an increase in interest rates, which further reduces private investment and slows down economic growth.
Developed by Krugman [
28], the debt cycle theory further suggests that developing countries can enter a vicious cycle of indebtedness, in which they borrow to repay their existing debt, leading to a continuous increase in debt. Stiglitz’s creditor response theory [
29] argues that the conditions and policies imposed by international creditors can have a significant impact on the level of public debt. According to this theory, creditors can influence the economic policies of developing countries according to their interests.
Reinhart and Rogoff’s theory of the costs of debt reduction [
30] highlights the negative effects of decreasing public debt. According to this theory, efforts to cut down on debt can lead to high social costs, such as reduced social spending, which can harm the population.
Finally, the theory of debt solutions proposes various strategies for dealing with the problem of public debt, such as debt renegotiation, restructuring, and debt forgiveness. This theory emphasizes the need to find viable political and economic solutions to the debt crisis. The key authors of this theory include several economists and researchers specializing in the field of development economics, notably those mentioned above.
These theories have given rise to a vast empirical literature on the effects of public debt. Whether external or domestic, public debt is a major concern for many developing countries, as it can have a significant impact on economic growth, macroeconomic stability, and social welfare. However, the impact of public debt on development is ambiguous and depends on several factors, such as the level, composition, maturity, cost, and sustainability of the debt, in addition to the institutional, political, and economic context of the country. The empirical literature on this topic is rich and diverse, but also sometimes contradictory and incomplete. In this review, we briefly present the main findings and limitations of existing studies, grouping them along three axes: the impact of public debt on growth, the impact of external debt on growth, and the impact of domestic debt on growth.
Public debt is a topic that generates much debate in the economic literature, particularly concerning its impact on economic growth. Several empirical studies have tried to measure this effect using different methods and data. We can distinguish two main approaches: one that considers the relationship between public debt and economic growth to be linear and negative, and the other that states the relationship is nonlinear and depends on the level of public debt and further identifies the threshold at which the relationship between public debt and economic growth/development reverses.
The linear approach assumes that public debt has a negative effect on economic growth, regardless of its level. This hypothesis is based on the theory of crowding out, according to which an increase in public debt leads to an increase in interest rates, which further reduces private investment and aggregate demand. It also draws on the theory of odious debt, which states that public debt can be considered illegitimate if it is not used to finance productive expenditures or if it is contracted by corrupt or authoritarian regimes. Studies using this approach include Refs. [
16,
31]. Based on panel data from developed and emerging economies, these find an inverse and linear relationship between public debt and economic growth. In other words, the more public debt increases, the more economic growth decreases. More recently, similar findings have been confirmed for a group of 45 sub-Saharan African countries by Sumba et al. [
32], who also presented evidence of a negative effect of public debt on macroeconomic stability and inflation. For a smaller group of just 11 sub-Saharan African economies, Obiero and Topuz [
33] investigated the causal relationships between public debt, economic growth, and income inequality and found that these vary according to the specific characteristics of the countries.
The nonlinear approach is based on the assumption that the relationship between public debt and economic growth is not constant but varies with the level of public debt. This hypothesis is based on the critical threshold theory, according to which public debt has no significant effect on economic growth as long as it remains below a certain threshold but becomes detrimental beyond this threshold. It is also based on the theory of the inverted U-curve, which states that public debt can have a positive effect on economic growth at moderate levels by financing productive public spending, but it becomes negative at higher levels by creating fiscal distortions and uncertainty. Among the studies using this approach, Ref. [
34] examined data from 44 countries over two centuries and found that there was no apparent relationship between public debt and economic growth up to a threshold of 90% of GDP. Beyond this threshold, economic growth slows down significantly. Checherita-Westphal and Rother [
35] examined a sample of Eurozone countries over the period 1970–2009. Their results showed that when public debt exceeds 90% of GDP, it weakens economic growth. Below this threshold, however, the relationship between debt and growth is insignificant. A study by Caner et al. [
15] confirmed these results, based on data from 101 developed and developing countries between 1980 and 2008. They also found a nonlinear relationship between public debt and economic growth. Similarly, the study by Cecchetti et al. [
36] on a sample of 18 OECD countries between 1980 and 2010 identified a threshold of 85% of GDP that should not be exceeded to avoid the negative impact of public debt on economic growth. Da Veiga et al. [
37] found evidence in a group of 52 African countries that there is an inverted-U relationship between public debt and economic growth, while high public debt levels are also associated with more inflation. Finally, Presbitero [
38] examined the impact of public debt on growth in developing countries, focusing on the expansionary response of governments to the global crisis. His results showed that public debt has a negative impact on growth at the threshold of 90% of GDP, beyond which the effects are no longer significant. This non-linear effect is explained by country-specific factors, with excessive debt being a constraint on growth only in countries with sound macroeconomic policies and stable institutions. Other studies confirm that there is high cross-country heterogeneity in the public debt–economic growth nexus, with the relationship depending on various factors, among which are the income level [
39,
40] or type of economic system [
41].
Regarding the impact of external debt on growth, foreign debt is often seen as a means of financing development, which allows countries to import capital goods, undertake public investment, finance budget deficits, and support domestic demand. However, external debt can also have negative effects on growth by creating distortions in the allocation of resources, reducing the availability of credit, increasing vulnerability to external shocks, inducing opportunistic or strategic behavior by debtors and creditors, and restricting fiscal space and economic policy’s room for maneuver. Several empirical studies have attempted to measure the impact of external debt on growth using various econometric techniques such as threshold models, error correction models, instrumental variable models, impact models, fixed or random effects models, or dynamic panel data models. These studies have generally found that there is a nonlinear relationship between external debt and growth, i.e., above a certain threshold, external debt becomes detrimental to growth. However, the level of this threshold varies across studies, ranging from 20% to 90% of GDP, depending on the indicators, periods, samples, and specifications used. For example, Pattillo et al. [
42] estimated that the threshold is between 35% and 40% of GDP for low-income countries and between 15% and 20% of GDP for middle-income countries. Reinhart and Rogoff [
30] proposed a higher threshold of 60% of GDP, above which the average growth rate falls by more than one percentage point. In the study of Lau et al. [
20], the threshold varies for different groups of Asian developing countries, between below 30% of GDP and 60%–90% of GDP. Moreover, the growth effects are not limited to one country, but significant spillovers may occur, especially at the regional level. Examining the impact of geographic proximity and spatial spillovers on public debt and economic growth dynamics in East Africa over the period 1992–2019, Otieno [
43] found evidence that foreign public debt has a negative impact on economic growth, which is consistent with the debt overhang theory and the crowding-out hypothesis. In addition, along with many other macroeconomic variables, foreign debt is found to have significant spatial spillover effects on regional economic growth. A separate strand of research has highlighted the importance of the quality of institutions, fiscal policy, degree of openness, exchange rate, and type of creditors as moderating or amplifying factors in the impact of external debt on economic growth. For example, Dey and Tareque [
22] found that external debt has a positive effect on growth when macroeconomic policies are stable but a negative effect when policies are unstable. Ehigiamusoe and Lean [
44] found that macroeconomic stability and institutional quality foster financial development, which in turn enhances the positive effect of external debt on growth. Moshin et al. [
18] emphasized that better institutions can help alleviate the negative effects of external debt on economic growth.
As several studies indicate, the foreign currency denomination of external debt is particularly important for shaping its economic and developmental effects. Grounding their demonstration on a two-country New Keynesian DSGE model with nominal rigidities and financial frictions, Hory et al. [
45] demonstrated that foreign currency debt can influence domestic financial conditions. They showed that the increase in the burden of foreign currency-denominated debt issued to finance public spending deteriorates the balance sheets of domestic firms by increasing their external financing premium and crowding out private investment, ultimately offsetting the positive effect of the government spending shock. Furthermore, Lu et al. [
46] found that the composition of foreign exchange reserves may be altered, with higher proportions of dollar-denominated external debt leading central banks to hold more U.S. dollars. Coulibaly et al. [
47] also provided evidence on the buffering effects of international reserves in Africa, which is crucial for understanding debt management mechanisms. Finally, Apeti et al. [
48] discussed the role of fiscal rules in limiting foreign currency debt and exposure to the problem of “original sin” in developing countries.
Domestic debt, i.e., public debt held by the residents of a country, is often perceived as less risky and more flexible than external debt because it is not dependent on international market conditions, does not involve a transfer of resources abroad, does not create currency mismatch problems, and can be renegotiated or restructured more easily. However, domestic debt can also have negative effects on growth by crowding out the private sector, increasing financing costs, reducing the effectiveness of monetary policy, creating inflationary expectations, and introducing fiscal distortions. Empirical studies on the impact of domestic debt on growth are fewer and less consistent than those on external debt, due to the difficulty of obtaining reliable and comparable data on domestic debt and the complexity of isolating its effect from other factors. Some studies have found a negative effect of domestic debt on growth using threshold models, error correction models, or panel data models. For example, Abbas and Christensen [
49] estimated that the threshold is between 35% and 40% of GDP for emerging economies and between 70% and 80% of GDP for advanced economies. Kumar and Woo [
31] found a lower threshold of 30% of GDP for the OECD countries. Other studies evidenced a positive or insignificant effect of domestic debt on growth using instrumental variable models, fixed or random effects models, or dynamic panel data models. For example, Panizza [
50] found that domestic debt has no significant effect on growth but reduces the likelihood of external debt crises. Presbitero [
51] emphasized that domestic debt has a positive effect on growth, but this effect is weaker than that of external debt. Ehigiamusoe and Samsurijan [
52] noted that the effect of domestic debt on growth depends on the quality of institutions, fiscal policy, and the degree of financial development.
The banking sector may be an important player in providing domestic resources to governments and supporting economic growth, especially in developing countries. According to Presbitero [
38], local banks can contribute to financial stability by diversifying their portfolios with public debt securities, thereby reducing their exposure to the risks associated with private lending. This interaction between the banking sector and public debt can also stimulate the economy by increasing liquidity and facilitating access to credit for firms and households. More recently, Tran et al. [
53] showed that banks may act as lenders to governments, thus allowing them to raise funds to finance development projects. According to these authors, well-capitalized banks are more likely to increase loan growth, especially for real estate, commercial and industrial loans, and loans to individuals. However, this positive effect of capital on loan growth is not uniform, as medium and large banks do not show this positive effect during crises. All these studies highlight the importance of bank participation in the public debt market and the soundness of macroeconomic policies to maximize the benefits of domestic debt financing.
Although the effects of public debt are extensively investigated in the literature, this study differs from the previously identified works in several ways. First, while the bulk of the literature focuses on the effects of external or domestic debt on one dimension of development, namely economic growth, we use an externalities approach to provide a comparative view of the impact of external and domestic debt on multiple facets of development. Externalities are the positive or negative consequences of an action or decision on agents who are not directly involved. For example, external debt can have negative externalities for development by reducing investor confidence, increasing the risk of crises, or limiting the room for maneuvering economic policy. Domestic debt can also have positive externalities for development by stimulating savings, promoting financial sector growth, or enhancing the credibility of public authorities. Second, a dynamic CGE model and microsimulation analysis are used to assess the impact of external and internal debt on development. A CGE model is a tool that can be used to simulate the impact of a change in policy, technology, or other external factors on a country’s economy. It is based on real economic data and assumptions about the behavior of agents. A dynamic CGE model accounts for changes in the economy over time, considering accumulation, transition, and growth effects [
54]. A microsimulation analysis simulates the activities of each individual within a population, taking into account their characteristics and preferences [
54]. Finally, the paper focuses on the case of Cameroon, a developing country that faces significant challenges in financing development and whose public debt, both external and domestic, has increased markedly in recent years. Nevertheless, the findings and recommendations of this study could be extended to other developing countries facing similar economic and financial conditions.
In conclusion, this study makes an original and relevant contribution to the literature on the impact of external and internal debt on development, using an innovative methodology and focusing on the case of Cameroon.
5. Results and Interpretations
In this section, we present the results obtained following the implementation of a scenario of a 20% increase in external and domestic public debt. Successive simulations are carried out at five-year intervals and reported for the years 2025, 2030, 2035, and 2040. We start by presenting the results at the macroeconomic level (
Section 5.1) and then move on to the results at the microeconomic level (
Section 5.2). For a description of the variables retained for interpretation, see
Table A2 in the
Appendix A.
5.1. Results of the Macrosimulation Model
From the results of the dynamic CGE model, we can observe the impact of the increase in Cameroon’s external and domestic public debt on certain indicators like total production, household consumption, purchase prices, etc., over a time frame ranging from 2025 to 2040.
In terms of production and without accounting for externalities, when external debt is used as an alternative for financing, total production will increase only in the AGR sector; nevertheless, a slight decline in the growth rate can be noticed over the subsequent simulation periods, from 1.90% in 2025 to 1.65% in 2040 (see
Table 1). In the industrial (IND), services (SER), and public administration (SAD) sectors, total output would decline over the years. When domestic debt is used as a method for financing, total output will increase in almost all sectors over the years. The highest increase can be noticed in the IND sector, where output would rise by 1.83% in 2025 and 3.3% in 2040 (see
Table 1). The SAD sector, on the other hand, is expected to experience a slight decline in output over the years.
When externalities are considered and external debt is used as a means for financing, the negative effects are amplified, and total output will fall significantly in all sectors over the period 2025–2040. In the IND sector, for example, the decrease in output goes from 7.42% in 2025 to 9.46% in 2040 (see
Table 1). On the other hand, with domestic debt as a method for financing, the positive effects are stronger, and total output will increase significantly in all sectors over the years. The increase in output is more pronounced in the industrial and service sectors and only modest, by comparison, in the public administration sector.
Looking at these impacts, we see that the use of domestic debt as a method of financing leads to an increase in total output in most sectors, both with and without externalities. This indicates that domestic debt has a positive impact on development in Cameroon. On the other hand, the use of external debt leads to a decrease in total output in most sectors, with even more important negative effects when accounting for externalities.
When used for productive purposes, debt financing may play a key role in supporting economic growth, especially at a moderate debt level, and this effect appears to be dominant in the case of Cameroon’s domestic debt. In addition, domestic debt may promote economic and financial stability and distribute the interest income to domestic creditors, which further supports consumption, investment, and production. As for the external debt, the positive effects seem to be exceeded by the negative impact of specific factors such as national currency depreciation and the diverting of productive resources to serve an increasing debt, capital flight, and economic instability, increased external dependency, and high vulnerability to external shocks. These channels play an important role in the case of countries with a history of high external debt, like Cameroon.
Furthermore, without taking externalities into account, we can see that the increase in external and domestic debt would lead to a fall in household consumption in many sectors over the years (see
Table 2). This fall is more pronounced in the industrial sector for external debt, with household consumption falling by 0.68% up to 2025 and 0.49% up to 2040. For domestic debt, the falls are less significant than for external debt over the long run; only household consumption in industry continuously fell by 0.64% in the last period of simulation (up to 2040).
Taking externalities into account, the impact on household consumption would remain negative for external debt across all sectors. In fact, the reductions are more marked in the case of external debt, particularly in the industrial and service sectors. For example, in 2040, household consumption would fall by 4.26% in industry and 5.04% in services. On the other hand, the increase in domestic debt would have a positive impact on household consumption, leading to an increase in all sectors over the years. The most important increase would be in the services sector, where household consumption grows by 10.84% up to 2040 (see
Table 2).
One may notice that the changes in household consumption generally follow the changes in output for both external and domestic debt, which reflects the strong connection between production and consumption in an economy. In addition, domestic debt directly affects household consumption through increased private savings to buy government bonds. This could explain why the impact of domestic debt on household consumption is negative in some instances that do not account for externalities.
Overall, we may conclude that an increase in domestic debt has a more favorable impact on household consumption than an increase in external debt. This could help to improve household living standards and purchasing power and, thus, support Cameroon’s economic development.
With regard to prices and without taking externalities into account, we find that the increase in external debt would lead to an increase in the purchase price of the composite product in all sectors (agriculture—AGR, industry—IND, services—SER, and public administration—SAD) over the years. However, the increase would be more important in certain sectors, such as agriculture (AGR) and services (SER). Comparatively, the increase in domestic debt would lead to a decrease in the purchase price of the composite product in almost all sectors (AGR, IND, and SER) over the years. This decline is more significant in sectors such as industry (IND) and agriculture (AGR) and becomes stronger over time. For example, the purchase price of the composite product in the agricultural sector would fall by 3.23 times more in 2040 compared to 2025 (−0.68 in 2040 compared to only −0.21 in 2025) (see
Table 3). The exception is the public administration sector (SAD), where the purchase price of the composite product would rise from 2025 onwards.
When taking externalities into account, we can see that the impact on the purchase price of the composite product is more important for both financing methods and generally becomes stronger over time. In the case of external debt, increases are higher, particularly in the agricultural (AGR) and industrial (IND) sectors (see
Table 3). In the case of domestic debt, the decrease in the purchase price of the composite product is more pronounced and is present in all sectors, public administration included.
Overall, considering these results, the increase in external debt has a more unfavorable impact on the purchase price of the composite product. This implies higher costs for businesses and consumers, which could be detrimental to Cameroon’s economic development. Some possible explanations are that external borrowing and foreign debt accumulation may result in the depreciation of the national currency and higher prices of imported goods, or lead to high budget deficits and inflationary pressures to service this debt. On the other hand, domestic borrowing may just reallocate existing resources and not exert the same negative effects on prices. As the total production and supply of goods and services increase (as emphasized by the data in
Table 1), prices may even decrease over time.
To further develop the analysis of macroeconomic effects, we present the impacts of domestic and external debt on a few one-dimensional variables, such as gross domestic product (GDP), consumer price index (CPI), total household income (TSH), and overall well-being. We capture well-being (welfare) by the equivalent variation, which allows us to measure the impact of a change on the welfare of an individual or a society. Décaluwé et al. [
71] use equivalent variation to assess the impact of economic policies, reforms, or changes in living conditions. From the results obtained, we can see that in the first case (without taking externalities into account), the increase in external debt would lead to an increase in GDP, although this growth would gradually slow down over the years (see
Table 4). The change in total household income and the consumer price index, although positive over our time framework, would also fall over time (see
Table 4). On the other hand, by increasing domestic debt, we would see a gradual growth in GDP and total household income and a gradual decrease in the consumer price index. Nevertheless, the increase in domestic debt would also result in an initial decline in welfare, followed by a gradual improvement over time, up to 2040 (see
Table 4).
By introducing externalities, the results differ. This time, the increase in external debt would lead to a significant reduction in GDP, total household income, and overall well-being. In addition, the consumer price index rises steadily (see
Table 4). For domestic debt with externalities, there would be a significant increase in GDP, total household income, and welfare, although the impact on the latter would decrease over time. Moreover, the consumer price index would fall steadily.
Overall, it is interesting to note that, in all sectors, when taking externalities into account, the increase in external debt has negative effects, while the increase in domestic debt has positive effects. Based on our findings, it seems that the most appropriate method of financing development in Cameroon would be domestic debt. Indeed, domestic debt allows for continuous growth in GDP and household income while maintaining stable consumer prices and ultimately improving the well-being of the Cameroonian people.
5.2. Results of the Microsimulation Model
The microsimulation results presented in this section are mainly based on the use of the Foster–Greer–Thorbecke index to measure poverty and the GINI index to assess inequality. Given the dynamic nature of the model and for the sake of simplicity, we have chosen to present the results for the poverty rate (incidence of poverty) and inequality at the national level, as well as for the area of residence and gender of the household head. Results specific to the depth and severity of poverty and the different regions are appended (see
Table A3,
Table A4,
Table A5,
Table A6,
Table A7 and
Table A8 in
Appendix A).
Our results show that without externalities, the increase in external debt would lead to a reduction in poverty in Cameroon (see
Table 5). Reductions in the incidence of poverty would be registered at the national level and in urban and rural areas, for both men and women. However, the extent of this reduction varies between areas and population groups. For example, the reduction is greater in rural areas, while it is slightly less pronounced in urban areas. In fact, poverty will fall by 25.42% at the national level in 2025 and by 20.96% in 2040. In urban areas, the reduction is 17.61% in 2025 and 15.14% in 2040, while in rural areas, it is 34.24% in 2025 and 27.53% in 2040 (see
Table 5). Nevertheless, the increase in domestic debt would lead to an increase in poverty levels at the national level, as well as within urban and rural areas, for both men and women, but this would diminish over time. Again, the extent of this increase would vary by area and population group, although to a smaller extent.
When externalities are accounted for, the results change drastically. In the case of external debt, we would see an increase in poverty at the national level as well as in urban and rural areas, for both men and women, after each year of simulation (see
Table 5). This shows that the externalities generated by this method of development financing have a negative impact on poverty. As for domestic debt, the externalities generated would help to reduce poverty at the national level and in urban and rural areas for both men and women, and the reduction would be persistent over time. Moreover, the reduction in the incidence of poverty is more pronounced in rural areas than in urban ones.
Our results indicate that domestic debt is a more appropriate method of financing development in Cameroon. Taking externalities into account, domestic debt would reduce poverty, while external debt would increase it. Nevertheless, the impact on inequality also needs to be accounted for to obtain a more complete picture of the effects.
When looking at the results that do not take externalities into account, we may notice that external debt leads to a gradual reduction in inequality over time at the national level and in urban and rural areas for both men and women (see
Table 6). However, these reductions remain modest, with values ranging from 0.03 to 0.09. In the case of domestic debt, there would instead be a gradual increase in inequality across all categories over time. The values range from 0.02 to 0.23, indicating a more marked increase in inequality compared with external debt.
Nevertheless, the results differ completely when accounting for externalities. In the case of external debt, we can observe a complete reversal of previous trends. Inequality would increase progressively over time, which means that an increase in external debt would lead to an increase in inequality, with values ranging from 0.06 to 0.83. In the case of domestic debt, the results also differ substantially from those obtained without externalities. Inequalities in this case would be progressively reduced, and the values would oscillate around 0.13 (see
Table 6).
Our results therefore indicate, once again, that domestic debt is more appropriate as a method of financing development in Cameroon. Taking externalities into account, domestic debt would reduce inequality, while external debt would increase it.
5.3. Robustness of the Results
Sensitivity analysis in the CGE model can be subject to strong criticism due to the difficulty of choosing the right parameters to analyze [
72,
73], simplifying assumptions, data limitations, normative assumptions, and issues of interpretation of results due to a lack of data [
74]. To demonstrate the robustness of the basic results, sensitivity analysis in the CGE model can consist of testing the structure of the elasticities of substitution between goods within a 50% interval [
72].
In our study, we followed the method of Hosoe et al. [
75] to analyze the sensitivity of our results to modifying the values of the CES and/or CET elasticities. In accordance with this method, we chose to multiply the values of the CES parameters by 1.5. In this way, we were able to assess the impact of this variation on the results of the various scenarios considered. We found that despite this 50% increase in the values of the CES parameters, the results did not change significantly.
Table 7 reports the results of macrosimulations capturing the impacts on one-dimensional variables, but other results can be provided upon request. The variations observed in the various indicators shown in
Table 7 suggest that our results are robust to these changes.