1. Introduction
As an important part of the Chinese economy, private enterprises play a leading role in gross domestic product (GDP) creation and social employment [
1]. Therefore, the environment for the development of private enterprises should be optimized. At the same time, the property rights of private enterprises and the rights and interests of entrepreneurs should be protected in accordance with the law, and the development and growth of the private economy should be promoted. During this critical period of China’s economic transformation, private enterprises play an irreplaceable role in promoting economic growth, promoting technological innovation, and expanding employment. In particular, private enterprises, as the backbone of China’s private sector, are crucial for achieving inclusive and sustainable economic development. Strengthening the financing environment for private enterprises is thus vital for advancing social equity, regional balance, and long-term economic resilience—core themes of sustainable development. However, the development of private enterprises still faces many challenges, especially financing difficulties, which are particularly prominent among micro-, small-, and medium-sized enterprises.
On the one hand, bank credit conditions remain the main obstacle to private enterprise financing. Although Chinese governments have introduced a series of policies in recent years to promote the inclusive development of the banking industry, to reduce their own risk, some banks are still not active enough in supporting the financing of private enterprises, and the financing conditions are relatively stringent, which makes it difficult for private enterprises to obtain sufficient financing support. On the other hand, private enterprises often face a shortage of funds when participating in government projects, especially when the level of local government debt is high. Government projects to promote economic development often require large amounts of funding support. However, whether these funds can be received and paid to private enterprises on time has become a key issue affecting the normal operation and development of enterprises. Payment arrears not only affect the cash flow of an enterprise but may also damage its credit, which has a chain effect on enterprise development. These challenges undermine not only firm-level viability but also broader goals of sustainable financial inclusion and regional economic balance.
Local governments’ payment arrears to private enterprises are essentially an external manifestation of the local government debt problem. The root of this problem lies in the imbalance between the fiscal revenues and expenditures of local governments and the continuous increase in the debt burden. Under China’s current fiscal system, local governments assume the responsibility for many expenditures on infrastructure construction and public service supply, but their fiscal revenues often cannot meet these rigid needs. To compensate for the funding gap, local governments borrow through various means, such as bank loans, bond issuance, and financing platforms, which results in a constantly expanding scale of debt. When fiscal resources are limited, local governments often postpone or default on payments to private enterprises in order to guarantee priorities, such as wage payments and people’s livelihood expenditures. This behavior is essentially a hidden debt default, which reflects the soft budget constraints of local governments under debt pressure. In addition, local governments’ overreliance on the investment-driven economic growth model and their motivation based on the performance appraisal mechanism further exacerbate the accumulation of debt risks. Therefore, the payment arrears by local governments to private enterprises represent not only a symptom of financial difficulties but also deep-seated debt problems. Addressing these structural issues is essential for building fiscal systems that support responsible public investment and private sector vitality—critical components of a sustainable governance framework. In this paper, we aim to explore how the optimization of the local government debt structure affects the investment and financing environment of private enterprises through the transmission mechanism and thereby provide policy guidance for promoting the development of private enterprises.
For a long time, the Chinese Central government has given great importance to the issue of local governments’ debts to private enterprises. From 2010 to 2016, in order to address the risks of local government debt, the Chinese government established a policy framework linking “supervisory standardization, institutional reconstruction, debt replacement, and innovation financing”. That is, in 2010, the expansion of implicit debt was curbed by liquidation of the financing platforms, and in 2014, debt limit management and bond issuance mechanisms were used to reshape the logic of debt borrowing, and the PPP mode was launched to guide the participation of social capital in infrastructure construction. In 2015, large-scale debt replacement was launched to replace the existing high-interest debt with low-cost bonds so as to optimize the maturity structure and relieve the pressure on short-term payments. This policy combination not only strengthens debt transparency through institutional constraints but also promotes debt restructuring and financing transformation by means of market-oriented instruments. However, in implementation, this policy still faces regulatory challenges, such as implicit debt transfer and pseudo-PPP arbitrage, which reflect the dynamic game between fiscal discipline and demands for growth. To address the issue of delayed payments by local governments to private enterprises, China’s State Council launched a special supervision in 2016. The campaign focused on seven provinces—Beijing, Liaoning, Anhui, Shandong, Henan, Hubei, and Qinghai—selected for their acute fiscal pressures (e.g., Liaoning, Qinghai), the prevalence of payment arrears to private firms (e.g., Shandong, Henan), and their representative regional characteristics. These regions span economically diverse areas, including developed eastern municipalities (e.g., Beijing), industrialized central provinces (e.g., Hubei), and underdeveloped western regions (e.g., Qinghai). In 2016, the State Council of China issued the “Notice of the General Office of the State Council on Further Improving the Work on Private Investment”, which required the Ministry of Finance and relevant departments to urge local governments to liquidate the arrears of payments and address the arrears of project payments, material procurement payments, and nonrefundable deposits in accordance with the law. Moreover, responsibility implementation and accountability mechanisms were strengthened to promote communication between governments and enterprises. For centralized rectification, the central government dispatched a special supervision team to seven provinces (cities), including Beijing, Liaoning, Anhui, Shandong, Henan, Hubei, and Qinghai, to carry out key supervision and conduct investigations and summary reports in various ways, which had a strong warning effect. Driven by this supervision, the government’s efforts to repay arrears significantly increased. For example, by the end of 2016, the accounts receivable by small and medium-sized enterprises in Anhui Province reached 277.21 billion yuan, a year-over-year increase of 13.2%, and the total profits reached 144.45 billion yuan, a year-over-year increase of 1.0%, which showed a stable level of profitability. By the end of 2016, Shandong Province had accumulated repaid project payments of approximately 90.9 billion yuan, accounting for 90.4% of all project payment arrears, and the total profit of small and medium-sized enterprises was 572.05 billion yuan, a year-over-year increase of 0.4%, ranking at the average level among the seven provinces (cities).
Despite prior research on the financing challenges faced by private enterprises—explored through the lenses of credit discrimination by banks [
2] and broader macroeconomic constraints [
3]—an important gap remains. Existing studies have seldom examined the role of local governments’ “payment credibility”—specifically, their practice of delaying payments to firms—as a quasi-fiscal behavior that may systematically affect firms’ access to financing constraint sand the mechanisms through which such effects arise.
Most research on government debt has concentrated on its macroeconomic implications, such as crowding-out effects or structural optimization through debt swaps [
4], often overlooking the direct impact of governments’ payment conduct as a market participant on firms’ financial conditions. In this context, delayed payments by local governments are not merely symptoms of fiscal stress but constitute a form of informal financing that consumes firms’ working capital, deteriorates cash flow, and potentially propagates credit risk across the supply chain [
5]. How does this government-induced credit constraint differ in its transmission and intensity from traditional bank credit rationing? Can targeted interventions—such as special supervision aimed at improving public-sector payment behavior—serve as effective policy instruments for alleviating financing constraints in the private sector? These questions have yet to be adequately addressed in the literature.
To fill this gap, this study draws on data from privately owned, non-financial A-share listed firms in China from 2007 to 2022 to examine how optimization of the government debt structure influences private enterprises’ financing constraints. A difference-in-differences (DID) framework is employed, with cash flow sensitivity serving as a proxy for financing constraints. Robustness checks—including parallel trend tests, placebo tests, and alternative variable specifications—confirm the validity of our findings. To probe the mechanisms of impact, we further apply a triple-differences (DDD) approach to investigate heterogeneous effects across firms and explore the channels through which special supervision may ease financing constraints, distinguishing between endogenous (internal cash flow) and exogenous (commercial credit) financing. We also examine how factors such as market orientation and technological intensity condition the policy’s effectiveness.
This study offers three contributions. First, in terms of research perspective, it shifts the focus from the macro-level scale of government debt to the micro-level payment behavior of local governments, conceptualizing payment default as a structural distortion in debt credibility. This provides a new analytical dimension linking public governance with firm-level financing. Second, in research design, the study leverages a highly specific and special supervision—designed to rectify government default—as a quasi-natural experiment, yielding cleaner causal identification compared to broader institutional reforms typically examined in DID research. Third, in mechanism analysis, we articulate how the policy eases financing constraints through two micro-level channels: improving internal liquidity (working capital turnover) and restoring external credit access (commercial credit), thereby enriching the theoretical understanding of policy transmission.
Based on the above, we propose three core hypotheses to be empirically tested: (H1) special supervision mitigates financing constraints for private enterprises by restructuring local government debt; (H2) the policy effect is heterogeneous, being stronger for firms more closely tied to government contracts or with weaker financing capacity; and (H3) the policy operates via two key channels—enhancing internal financing efficiency and improving access to external credit through the restoration of government credibility. By rigorously testing these hypotheses, this study aims to provide comprehensive evidence on the complex interplay between public governance and private-sector financing.
6. Conclusions
6.1. Main Research Conclusions
In this study, through theoretical analysis and based on data from A-share listed enterprises, a quasi-natural experiment is conducted to explore the impact of the optimization of the government debt structure via the liquidation of government arrears under the special supervision of private enterprises’ financing constraints. The findings are as follows:
First, optimization of the government debt structure significantly relieves the financing constraints of private enterprises. The special supervision of the liquidation of government debts can reduce the debts owed by local governments, optimize the government debt structure, release more working capital for enterprises, and enable enterprises to respond more flexibly to their capital needs. This can effectively improve private enterprises’ liquidity and cash flow and reduce their financing pressures. This mechanism is particularly relevant for private enterprises, which are disproportionately affected by payment delays and financing bottlenecks. Enhancing liquidity through government debt optimization not only strengthens the short-term financial stability of private enterprises but also promotes their long-term sustainable development, contributing to broader economic resilience and inclusive growth. A study by Li et al. (2023) [
10] showed that the special supervision of the State Council to liquidate government arrears significantly increases the long-term investment of private enterprises in the areas under supervision. Although Li et al. (2023) [
10] do not directly discuss the issue of private enterprise financing constraints, their conclusions show from another angle that the liquidation of government arrears eases the financing constraints of private enterprises in the supervision areas. This result is consistent with our conclusions, except that we study optimization of the government debt structures through the special supervision of the liquidation of government arrears as the channel through which private enterprises’ financing constraints are alleviated in supervision areas.
Second, the effects of optimization of the government debt structure vary significantly among different types of enterprises. This finding underscores the need to tailor sustainability-focused policy interventions to enterprise heterogeneity, particularly prioritizing support for private enterprises in critical sectors such as infrastructure and environmental services. These sectors not only experience heightened financing vulnerability but also have high potential to contribute to environmental and social sustainability outcomes. Other studies explore the heterogeneous impacts of optimization of the government debt structure mostly from the perspectives of the nature of enterprises and provincial locations [
8,
29], whereas we focus on different types of private enterprises. For industries that rely on local government support, such as the infrastructure and environmental protection industries, optimization of the government debt structure has a particularly significant effect. Enterprises in the infrastructure and environmental protection industries usually face high financing costs and difficulty in capital turnover. The liquidation of government debts can significantly improve capital turnover and credit status and reduce financing difficulties for these enterprises. On the other hand, for enterprises with fairly stable operations and strong financing ability, the effect of optimization of the government debt structure is relatively small, which indicates that the policy effect is mainly concentrated on the enterprises with great financing difficulties.
Third, optimization of the government debt structure further eases financing constraints by improving enterprises’ capital turnover and trade credit. By restoring trade credit and financial trust, especially for smaller private enterprises, these changes can catalyze broader improvements in financing ecosystems—thus aligning financial system reform with the core goals of sustainable economic development. Studies have proposed that government debt relieves enterprise financing constraints through financial intermediaries or through the reduction in new loans in platform financing [
4,
29]. We emphasize that, under optimization of the government debt structure, private enterprises’ credit status is significantly improved. The increase in trade credit makes it easier for enterprises to obtain external financing and thus effectively reduces financing constraints. This mechanism not only improves the funding liquidity of enterprises but also strengthens their competitiveness in the financing market, which supports the sustainable development of private enterprises.
6.2. Policy Recommendations
We offer various policy implications for better promoting the high-quality development of private enterprises in the background of the deepening structural reform to address local government debts. First, the reform of decentralization, regulation, and services should be further promoted, and the special supervision mechanism should be improved. From a sustainability perspective, these reforms not only serve fiscal governance goals but also play a key role in creating a transparent, equitable financial environment that fosters the survival and growth of private enterprises—actors essential for employment generation, green innovation, and inclusive economic transformation. Although the central government has introduced several policies to support private enterprises, due to the financial pressures of local governments and other factors, payment arrears still exist. The special supervision measure provides an effective means for local government debt liquidation, which can improve the financing environment of private enterprises and ease financing constraints. Therefore, the policy implementation should be promoted in support of the financing ability of private enterprises.
Second, governments’ legal responsibility for the arrears should be clarified, and supervision should be strengthened. Embedding these responsibilities within a legally enforceable and transparent framework supports the institutional underpinnings of a sustainable economy—especially one where private enterprises can operate with greater financial certainty and lower systemic risk exposure. The persistence of government arrears is partly due to the lack of effective, legally binding, and supervisory measures. To prevent the long-term existence of government payment arrears to private enterprises, legislation must be passed to clarify the government’s debt repayment responsibility, standardize debt settlement procedures, and reduce the negative impact of the government’s payment arrears. Moreover, the supervision of local government debt behavior should be strengthened to ensure that private enterprises can receive funding support under a fair and just environment.
Third, while the government debt structure continues to be optimized, a long-term mechanism to effectively solve the local government debt problem should be developed. Developing a resilient, future-oriented debt management system will provide a more reliable foundation for private enterprises to access stable financial resources, thereby empowering them to contribute meaningfully to sustainable recovery and economic transformation, particularly in the post-pandemic era. Although debt liquidation went smoothly when the debt-free policy was implemented in 2016, against the background of slowing economic growth, the local government debt problem has become more complex. Future policies should be designed to improve debt transparency, establish a sound debt management framework, and provide more stable financial support and financing channels for private enterprises to ensure that private enterprises can continue to play a key role in promoting sustained economic recovery and development amid economic challenges. The above policy measures can effectively relieve private enterprises’ financing constraints, enhance their financing ability, and provide powerful support for their long-term development.
In conclusion, these policy measures can effectively relieve private enterprises’ financing constraints, enhance their financing ability, and provide powerful support for their long-term development—especially for private enterprises, which are central to achieving the UN Sustainable Development Goals through job creation, innovation, and regional development.
6.3. Generalizability of the Findings
While the conclusions of this study are deeply rooted in the distinctive institutional context of China, the underlying logic possesses a degree of generalizability under specific conditions. The central insight is that, when the government plays an active role in the market, improvements in its payment credibility and fiscal discipline can alleviate private sector financing constraints—both through direct liquidity support and via enhanced creditworthiness.
This mechanism may be relevant to other economic contexts, particularly in the following scenarios: First, in emerging markets where the government is heavily involved in economic activity, the findings of this study may offer valuable insights. In such economies, the state often functions not only as a purchaser but also as a key determinant of the overall business environment. Where issues such as delayed government payments or weak fiscal discipline are prevalent, reforms aimed at enhancing government payment reliability could serve—much as in China—as a potent policy tool to ease firms’ financing constraints.
Second, the results may also apply in markets characterized by structural credit discrimination. In economies where small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) or certain firm types (e.g., start-ups) face persistent barriers to accessing traditional finance, stable and timely payments from public sector entities can serve both as a critical cash flow lifeline and as a form of implicit credit endorsement. Ensuring the predictability of government payments may thus represent an unconventional yet effective policy lever to support firms under financial stress.
6.4. Limitations of the Study
Despite offering both theoretical insights and empirical evidence, this study is not without limitations—chief among them, concerns regarding sample representativeness.
To ensure data reliability and comparability, the analysis focuses on firms listed on China’s A-share market. These companies tend to be relatively large, with more formal governance structures and access to diversified financing channels, giving them far greater bargaining power than the typical private enterprise. As a result, the sample does not fully capture the broader landscape of China’s private sector, particularly the micro, small, and medium-sized enterprises (MSMEs) and firms operating in the informal economy—segments often most acutely affected by credit constraints.
The exclusion of these more financially vulnerable groups may lead the empirical results to underestimate the average effect of government arrears clearance on the overall financing environment for private enterprises. The significant positive impact observed among listed firms may thus represent only the “tip of the iceberg” in terms of the policy’s broader benefits. This constitutes the study’s most critical limitation and underscores the urgent need for future research drawing on more representative datasets—such as large-scale MSME surveys or administrative data from public agencies—to provide a more comprehensive assessment.
6.5. Further Research
This study provides new empirical evidence on the relationship between optimization of the government debt structures and private sector financing, yet it also underscores the considerable scope for further investigation. Future research could fruitfully explore the following directions:
First, long-term policy dynamics and sustainability. While this study primarily examines the short- to medium-term impacts following special supervision, the long-run effects remain unclear—particularly whether local governments, under renewed fiscal pressures, might revert to delaying payments. Future studies could employ extended time-series data and methodologies such as event history analysis or difference-in-differences designs with longer windows to assess the durability of policy impacts and identify the determinants of their persistence.
Second, spillover effects on unlisted firms and the informal sector. Due to data limitations, the current analysis focuses on publicly listed firms. However, financing constraints are often more acute among unlisted small and micro enterprises and within the informal economy. It remains an open question whether expedited payments to large firms by governments generate positive spillovers—via supply chain effects or improved regional financial conditions—to these more vulnerable entities. Future research could leverage survey data from small firms in selected regions or alternative data sources (e.g., electricity usage, tax records) to examine the multi-layered transmission mechanisms of such policies.
Third, cross-country comparative analysis under varying institutional contexts. As discussed, the findings of this study are closely tied to China’s institutional context. A valuable avenue for future inquiry would be cross-national comparisons that assess whether and how the effects of government payment behavior on corporate financing constraints vary across countries with differing fiscal discipline, legal frameworks, and financial market structures. Such comparative work could contribute to more generalizable theoretical insights and inform policy design in diverse institutional settings.
Finally, micro-level firm responses and strategic behaviors. Firms are not passive actors in the face of government payment delays. How do they respond—by diversifying their client base to reduce dependence on public contracts or by strengthening political connections to improve their bargaining position? Moreover, how do such behaviors evolve in response to enforcement actions like special supervision? Micro-level studies, using case interviews, surveys, or text analysis, could illuminate firms’ adaptive strategies within the state–business interface, offering a rich complement to the macro-level patterns observed here.