Dynamics of Sewage Charge Policies, Environmental Protection Industry and Polluting Enterprises—A Case Study in China
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Mechanism Analysis
3. Methods
- Game participants have completed reciprocal information and acted at the same time. It belongs to the complete information static game.
- Game participants are fully rational. The goal of the government is to realize the maximum overall social welfare. Polluting enterprises and the environmental protection industry pursues the maximum profit. The environmental policies of the government are mainly formulating standards for sewage charges. Variables of polluting enterprises’ decision-making are mainly production Q1 and the amount of pollution emissions u. A variable of environmental protection firm’s decision-making is the production volume of environment protection product Q2.W = L1 + L2 + S1 + S2 + T - L3
- The initial pollution treatment cost of the environmental protection industry as C0. When C0 > tk, and the slope of MC is larger than that of MT, namely αk > 2tk2, then t < min( , ). The result is shown in Figure 2.
- The initial pollution treatment cost of the environmental protection industry as C0. When C0 > tK, and the slope of MC is smaller than that of MT, namely αk > 2tk2, which is < t < . The result is shown in Figure 3.
- When C0 < tK, and the slope of MC is larger than that of MT, namely t < , the result is shown in Figure 4.
- When C0 < tK, and the slope of MC is smaller than that of MT, namely t > max( , ), the result is shown in Figure 5.
4. Empirical Analysis
4.1. Data Collection
Regions | Income of Environmental Protection Industry (billion RMB) | Investment on Environmental Pollution Control (billion RMB) | Number of Organizations Paying Sewage Charges | Revenue of Sewage Charges (million RMB) | Region Classification |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Beijing | 426.3 | 2.31 | 1921 | 35.75 | LDR |
Tianjin | 276.73 | 1.10 | 3984 | 180.42 | LDR |
Hebei | 632.22 | 3.71 | 27973 | 1372.48 | HR |
Shanxi | 266.82 | 2.07 | 10446 | 1662.99 | HR |
Inner Mongolia | 1200 | 2.39 | 6017 | 1029.34 | LUR |
Liaoning | 1000 | 2.07 | 27568 | 1206.30 | HR |
Jilin | 120 | 1.24 | 24187 | 418.77 | LDR |
Heilongjiang | 259.22 | 1.31 | 10984 | 438.83 | LDR |
Shanghai | 961.29 | 1.34 | 5455 | 248.28 | LDR |
Jiangsu | 3410 | 4.66 | 34566 | 2026.12 | HR |
Zhejiang | 2557.5 | 3.34 | 30536 | 1014.73 | LDR |
Anhui | 357.3 | 1.80 | 14404 | 528.56 | LUR |
Fujian | 400 | 1.30 | 20006 | 352.45 | LDR |
Jiangxi | 236.28 | 1.57 | 7521 | 478.07 | LUR |
Shandong | 1278.8 | 4.84 | 17685 | 1506.86 | HR |
Henan | 600 | 1.32 | 16489 | 917.91 | LUR |
Hubei | 600 | 1.47 | 9969 | 375.42 | LDR |
Hunan | 643 | 1.07 | 12433 | 542.61 | LUR |
Guangdong | 1700 | 14.16 | 62578 | 941.38 | LDR |
Guangxi | 95 | 1.64 | 8833 | 466.73 | LUR |
Hainan | 59.87 | 0.24 | 919 | 36.05 | LUR |
Chongqing | 245.69 | 1.76 | 6928 | 377.26 | LUR |
Sichuan | 270 | 0.89 | 7602 | 585.67 | LUR |
Guizhou | 50 | 0.30 | 7595 | 453.04 | LUR |
Yunnan | 72.24 | 1.06 | 7395 | 292.14 | LUR |
Tibet | 5.075 | 0.003 | 4688 | 8.82 | LUR |
Shanxi | 327.7 | 1.79 | 5177 | 478.93 | LDR |
Gansu | 41.21 | 0.64 | 8489 | 213.07 | LUR |
Qinghai | 13.50 | 0.17 | 1241 | 66.24 | LUR |
Ningxia | 16.90 | 0.35 | 2897 | 146.90 | LUR |
Xinjiang | 54.37 | 0.78 | 7089 | 416.88 | LUR |
4.2. Results and Discussion
- (1)
- During the development of sewage charges, the local government should place more focus on the social welfare of the entire society rather than simply aiming for taxation revenue for sake of environmental protection. It is imperative to consider the coping measures of polluting enterprises as a game player, and to achieve the purpose of environment management through developing environmental protection industry as much as possible.
- (2)
- It is proposed that different standards are adopted in different regions in order to maintain its effectiveness. The whole country can be divided into three kinds of regions, i.e., regions with higher sewage charges, regions with lower sewage charges and underdeveloped economy, and regions with lower sewage charges and developed economy. The higher sewage charges regions are Hebei, Shanxi, Liaoning, Jiangsu, and Shandong. Lower sewage charges and undeveloped regions are Inner Mongolia, Anhui, Jiangxi, Henan, Hunan, Guangxi, Hainan, Chongqing, Sichuan, Guizhou, Yunnan, Tibet, Gansu, Qinghai, Ningxia, and Xinjiang. Lower sewage charges and developed regions are Beijing, Tianjin, Jilin, Heilongjiang, Shanghai, Zhejiang, Fujian, Hubei, Guangdong, and Shanxi (see Table 1). In regions with higher sewage charges, it is necessary to reduce the original sewage charge standards. However for Shanxi, a province with rich coal resources in China, its economic development mainly relies on coal mining and processing. The excessive reliance on coal resources has resulted in an unreasonable economic structure and serious environmental degradation. Accordingly, Shanxi has increased the level of sewage charges for several times. For instance, the “Notice on implementation of the action plan for the prevention and control of atmospheric pollution in Shanxi Province” was issued in 2013, which specified that the level of sewage charges will be further increased and the scope will be extended [49]. For regions with lower sewage charges and underdeveloped regions, such as Tibet, Xinjiang and Qinghai, considering the local economy condition, environmental damage caused by the economic development is limited which has yet to affect the quality of life of local residents. Therefore, it is recommended to maintain the current sewage charge standards in a short-term basis. When the local economy conditions develop to a higher level, to the authorities should consider increase sewage charges standard appropriately. For regions with lower sewage charges and developed economy condition (such as Shanghai, Beijing, Tianjin, Guangdong, Jilin), it is proposed to increase sewage charges and strengthen the supervision on the implementation of environment protection policy at the central government level. For instance, as the capital city, Beijing has made a great deal of effort on pollution treatment, as well as improving the air quality. In 2014, the level of sewage charges for SO2, NOx and other pollutants increased by 14 to 15 times of the original level and has become the highest level in the 31 regions [50]. It was reported that the leverage function is strengthened since the implementation of the new collection standards.
- (3)
- At present, China’s environmental issues are not only related to the enforcement of environmental law and supervision of local governments, but also relevant to the relatively lower level of science and technology of the environmental protection industry in China. The environmental management cost is higher associated with comparatively lower technical level of the industry. Illegal discharging of pollutants is not unusual as some polluting enterprises tried to escape from the substantial cost of environmental treatment. Therefore, it is imperative to enhance the technological level of environmental protection industry. Technological innovation can reduce the environmental management cost and improve the profits of the environmental protection industry, as well as sustaining competitiveness against international environmental protection industry.
5. Conclusions
Acknowledgments
Author Contributions
Conflicts of Interest
References
- Yao, J. A multi-objective (energy, economic and environmental performance) life cycle analysis for better building design. Sustainability 2014, 6, 602–614. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yuan, X.L.; Zuo, J.; Ma, C.Y. Social acceptance of solar energy technologies in China—End users’ perspective. Energy Policy. 2011, 39, 1031–1036. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Carlo, C.; Emanuele, M. Energy and climate change in China. Environ. Dev. Econ. 2012, 17, 689–713. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Liu, Y.Q.; Xu, J.P.; Luo, H.W. An integrated approach to modelling the Economy-Society-Ecology system in urbanization process. Sustainability 2014, 6, 1946–1972. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yuan, X.L.; Zuo, J. Transition to low carbon energy policies in China—From Five-Year plan perspective. Energy Policy 2011, 39, 3855–3859. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sun, X.F.; Han, B.P.; Liu, Y.J.; Wei, Y. The impact and strategy for environmental industry of China’s post-WTO. Energy Environ. Prot. 2003, 17, 5–12. [Google Scholar]
- Motta, R.S.D. Analyzing the environmental performance of the Brazilian industrial sector. Ecol. Econ. 2006, 57, 269–281. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhang, Z. Game analysis of environmental protection industry related subject. Shandong Soc. Sci. 2012, 4, 157–159. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
- Keisuke, H. Environmental innovation and policy harmonization in international oligopoly. Environ. Dev. Econ. 2013, 18, 162–183. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Shu, J.Y. Taxation on pollution emission to protect environment. Environ. Prot. 1999, 4, 44–46. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
- Stavins, R.N. Experience with market-based environmental policy instruments. Handb. Environ. Econ. 2003, 1, 355–435. [Google Scholar]
- Yuan, Y.J. Environmental Economics; China Financial Economic Publishing Press: Beijing, China, 2006. [Google Scholar]
- Yang, Y.L. Resoures Economy Development; Science Press: Beijing, China, 2004. [Google Scholar]
- Montginoul, M.; Rinaudo, J.D. Controlling households’ drilling fever in France: An economic modeling approach. Ecol. Econ. 2011, 71, 140–150. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hahn, R.W. Economic prescriptions for environmental problems: How the patient followed the doctor’s orders. J. Econ. Persp. 1989, 3, 95–114. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Pretty, J.; Brett, C.; Gee, D.; Hine, R.; Mason, C.; Morison, J.; Rayment, M.; Dobbs, T. Policy challenges and priorities for internalizing the externalities of modern agriculture. J. Environ. Plan. Manag. 2001, 44, 263–283. [Google Scholar]
- Bressers, H. The impact of effluent charges: A dutch success story. Policy. Stud. Rev. 1995, 7, 43–58. [Google Scholar]
- Bergman, L. General equilibrium effects of environmental policy: A CGE modelling approach. Environ. Resour. Econ. 1991, 1, 43–61. [Google Scholar]
- Lighart, J.E.; Vander, P.F. Environmental policy, tax incidence, the cost of Public Funds. Environ. Resour. Econ. 1999, 13, 187–207. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yan, Z.K.; Yi, B.; Wang, Z.W. Reviews on development of China environmental protection industry in 2004. China Environ. Prot. Ind. 2005, 11, 10–15. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
- Maynard, S. The theory and the evolution of animal conflict. J. Theory Biol. 1974, 1, 209–221. [Google Scholar]
- Klaus, R. Redefining innovation-eco-innovation research and the contribution from ecological economics. Ecol. Econ. 2000, 32, 319–332. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mendoza, A.J.; Clemen, R.T. Outsourcing sustainability: A game-theoretic modeling approach. Environ. Syst. Decis. 2013, 33, 224–236. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sechi, G.M.; Zucca, R.; Zuddas, P. Water costs allocation in complex systems using a cooperative game theory approach. Water. Resour. Manag. 2013, 27, 1781–1796. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Scott, H.B.; Fernandez, L. Game Theory with Economic Applications; Addison Wesley Press: Boston, MA, USA, 1997. [Google Scholar]
- Liu, Y.; Lu, Z.N. Study on the relationship between evolutionary game theory and system analysis. North Econ. 2007, 15, 6–7. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
- Jones, S. Game theoretic framework for risk reduction decisions. Environ. Sci. Tech. 1996, 30, 128–132. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kreps, D.M. Game Theory and Economic Modeling; C Laredo Press: Oxford, UK, 1990. [Google Scholar]
- John, A.; Lista, J.A.; Masonb, C.F. Optimal institutional arrangements for transboundary pollutants in a second-best world: Evidence from a differential game with asymmetric players. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 2001, 42, 277–296. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Segerson, K.; Wu, J. Nonpoint pollution control: Inducing first-best outcomes through the use of threats. J. Environ. Plan. Manag. 2006, 51, 165–184. [Google Scholar]
- Lu, F.Y. Evolutionary game analysis on environmental pollution problem. Syst. Eng. Theory. Pract. 2007, 9, 148–152. [Google Scholar]
- Yang, Z.F.; Zeng, Y.; Cai, Y.P.; Tan, Q. An integrated game-theory based model for trans-boundary water resources management in north China: A case study in the Guanting reservoir basin, Beijing. Int. J. Softw. Eng. Knowl. Eng. 2008, 18, 461–483. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zou, W.J.; Hu, P. The government and the enterprise environmental behavior: Game and game equilibrium improvement. Theor. Mon. 2009, 31, 161–164. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
- Young, H.P. Individual Strategies and Social Structure: The Evolution Theory of System; Shanghai People’s Publishing House: Shanghai, China, 2008. [Google Scholar]
- Irene, M.L.C.; Raymond, R.T.; Dominic, C.Y.F.; Anthony, S.F.C. Game theory approach to the analysis of inter-plant water integration in an eco-industrial park. J. Clean. Prod. 2009, 17, 1611–1619. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Jørgensen, S.; Martín-Herrán, G.; Zaccour, G. Dynamic games in the economics and management of pollution. Environ. Model. Assess. 2010, 15, 433–467. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wang, Y.; Luo, J.; Chen, T.P.; Yin, Z.H. Analysis of dynamic evolution game for enterprise pollution control of strategic alliance. Stat. Decis. 2011, 27, 68–71. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
- Shen, L. A research on Chinese environment protection supervision mechanism: An evolutionary game theory analyses. Manag. Rev. 2011, 23, 46–51. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
- Yuan, Y.J.; Geng, D.H. The transmission mechanism of environmental policies and sustainable development on environment protect industry of China-based on research of government and pollutant corporation and environment protect corporation. China Ind. Econ. 2010, 28, 65–74. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
- Hu, G.; Wang, W.J. Game analysis of investing and financing enterprise behavior in environmental protection industry. J. Xidian. Univ. (Soc. Sci. Ed.) 2007, 17, 70–73. [Google Scholar]
- CCID. China’s Environmental Protection Industry Research Report. Available online: http://wenku.baidu.com/view/04374845b307e87101f69612.html (accessed on 6 November 2013).
- NBS, National Bureau of Statistics. China Environment Statistical Yearbook 2011; China Statistic Press: Beijing, China, 2011. [Google Scholar]
- Li, S.; Chen, Y.L.; Chen, G. Environmental protection industry development and regional environmental quality improvement. J. Zhongnan Univ. Econ. Law 2011, 5, 3–7. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
- NBS, National Bureau of Statistics. China Statistic Yearbook 2011; China Statistic Press: Beijing, China, 2011. [Google Scholar]
- NBS, National Bureau of Statistics. Sewage Charges Levied for Each Region in 2010. Available online: http://www.stats.gov.cn/tjsj/qtsj/hjtjzl/hjtjsj2010/t20111229_402788828.htm (accessed on 10 November 2013).
- Franzen, A.; Vogl, D. Two decades of measuring environmental attitudes: A comparative analysis of 33 countries. Glob. Environ. Chang. 2013, 23, 1001–1008. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Buckley, C.; Carney, P. The potential to reduce the risk of diffuse pollution from agriculture while improving economic performance at farm level. Environ. Sci. Policy 2013, 25, 118–126. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Parodi, S.; Santi, I.; Marani, E.; Casella, C.; Puppo, A.; Vercelli, M.; Stagnaro, E. Risk of non-hodgkin’s lymphoma and residential exposure to air pollution in an industrial area in northern italy: A case-control study. Arch. Environ. Occup. Health 2014, 69, 139–147. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- PGSP, People’s Government of Shanxi Province. Notice on Implementation of the Action Plan for the Prevention and Control of Atmospheric Pollution in Shanxi Province. Available online: http://www.shanxigov.cn/n16/n8319541/n8319612/n8321663/n16932389/n17533814/n17610687/17610834.html (accessed on 15 July 2014).
- Xinhua News. Beijing Significantly Increased Sewage Charges Standard. Available online: http://news.xinhuanet.com/local/2014-05/06/c_1110563808.htm (accessed on 15 July 2014). (In Chinese)
© 2014 by the authors; licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/3.0/).
Share and Cite
Wang, Q.; Yuan, X.; Zuo, J.; Mu, R.; Zhou, L.; Sun, M. Dynamics of Sewage Charge Policies, Environmental Protection Industry and Polluting Enterprises—A Case Study in China. Sustainability 2014, 6, 4858-4876. https://doi.org/10.3390/su6084858
Wang Q, Yuan X, Zuo J, Mu R, Zhou L, Sun M. Dynamics of Sewage Charge Policies, Environmental Protection Industry and Polluting Enterprises—A Case Study in China. Sustainability. 2014; 6(8):4858-4876. https://doi.org/10.3390/su6084858
Chicago/Turabian StyleWang, Qingsong, Xueliang Yuan, Jian Zuo, Ruimin Mu, Lixin Zhou, and Mingxia Sun. 2014. "Dynamics of Sewage Charge Policies, Environmental Protection Industry and Polluting Enterprises—A Case Study in China" Sustainability 6, no. 8: 4858-4876. https://doi.org/10.3390/su6084858
APA StyleWang, Q., Yuan, X., Zuo, J., Mu, R., Zhou, L., & Sun, M. (2014). Dynamics of Sewage Charge Policies, Environmental Protection Industry and Polluting Enterprises—A Case Study in China. Sustainability, 6(8), 4858-4876. https://doi.org/10.3390/su6084858