3.1.1. At the Village Level
Livelihoods in Shaxi are predominantly based on agriculture and the extraction of forest resources, such as medicinal plants, edible mushrooms, or timber from unlicensed small-scale logging. Off-farm employment and seasonal migrant labor are additional important income sources. The surveyed villages showed marked differences in structural and socio-demographic characteristics (
Table 1) and in the livelihood activities pursued to earn an income (
Table 2). While for some livelihood activities no clear distinction between the villages could be found (
i.e., overall agricultural income per capita, income from local off-farm or migrant labor, or employment in public service), for others a clear mountain/valley divide was found. For instance, while the per capita income from forest resources is statistically significantly higher in the mountain villages (Mountains: 1332 ± 1208 CNY; Valley: 120 ± 228 CNY; independent samples
t-Test,
p < 0.001), off-farm income per capita is significantly higher in valley villages (Mountains: 604 ± 1025 CNY; Valley: 2241 ± 3035 CNY; independent samples
t-Test,
p = 0.006). In addition to the expected mountain/valley divide, however, several livelihood activities were found to be highly specific to single villages (timber in Xishan; tobacco in Silian; and in Huacongshan specific collective migrant labor to factories in Southern China).
Table 1 shows a low accessibility of the mountain villages in contrast to the surveyed villages in the valley bottom. Land holdings per capita are significantly larger in the mountains, whereas arable land in the valley bottom is limited but allows for two harvests per year. The average household cash income in all villages is statistically not significantly different. While the annual income of households in the valley bottom did not increase substantially (from an average of 18,750 ± 14,955 CNY [adjusted for inflation: 21,500 ± 17,155 CNY] in 2005 to 21,765 ± 14,615 CNY in 2009), the average income of households in the mountains increased from 5850 ± 4980 CNY (adjusted for inflation: 6710 ± 5710 CNY) in 2005 to 13,155 CNY ± 7005 CNY in 2009. When calculated per capita, the differences between mountain and valley residents’ income disappear altogether in the period between 2005 and 2009 (2005: valley: 3255 ± 2270 CNY [adjusted for inflation: 3730 ± 2605 CNY]; mountains: 1185 ± 820 CNY [adjusted for inflation: 1360 ± 940]; 2009: valley: 4125 ± 2900 CNY; mountains: 3615 ± 2215 CNY). The relative importance of the different income sources for both regions did not change significantly between 2005 and 2009.
The level of income equality
within the villages is likewise different
between the villages (
Figure 2) and does not show a clear mountain/valley divide. Xishan (mountains) and Silian (valley) have a more equal distribution of household income than the other villages.
In Shaxi, NTFPs are an open access resource, not only accessible for mountain households but also for the valley population. All stakeholders are aware of periods of intensive harvesting, especially of medicinal plants, but no clear rules to regulate collection activities have so far been established. However, in recent years around 10 mu/capita of government forest land has been allocated to individual households, but so far to those in valley villages only. The goal of a long-term tenure system for forest land, similar to the system for agricultural land, is to motivate forest users to manage their lots in a sustainable way and create an additional and secure income source, instead of relying on open access to government land. However, hardly any household knows what is allowed to do on this forest land or even where exactly its plot is located. Another system, which is proposed and partially applied in adjacent areas, is the auction of whole mountains to wealthy individual contractors, who allow local villagers to collect NTFPs on their land on payment of a fee. Both systems restrict the mountain population’s legal rights to use forest resources. Mountain farmers repeatedly mentioned that they are waiting for the program to include their land, so that they can afford to convert large areas of surplus fields back to forest or fruit tree plantations.
Tourism in Shaxi is focused on the central town of Sideng and the temples and grottoes in the nature reserve of nearby Shibaoshan. In the surveyed villages, tourism is not a relevant source of direct income. However, it generates indirect revenue for the more peripheral villages through increased demand for unskilled labor in construction, timber, and NTFP harvesting, as well as agricultural production. The importance of these income sources varies considerably between the villages (
Table 2). While NTFPs represent an important income source for the households in both mountain villages, unlicensed and thus illegal small-scale logging of timber for the flourishing construction sector in Shaxi is restricted to Xishan only, due to its remoteness and thus weaker integration into the local societal and legal system. Huacongshan, by comparison, benefits from an increased demand for agricultural products (
Table 1). Interviews with both government officials and farmers in Xishan indicated that if pressure on livelihood options, particularly logging, in the mountains increases, migration to new localities is likely to happen. This outcome is sought by neither of the parties, and some flexibility in the enforcement of the logging policy is thus intended.
Table 1.
Overview of structural and socio-demographic variables among four villages in Shaxi Valley, SW China.
Table 1.
Overview of structural and socio-demographic variables among four villages in Shaxi Valley, SW China.
Variables | Mountains | Valley | ANOVA/Kruskal–Wallis |
---|
Xishan | Huacongshan | Changle | Silian |
---|
Accessibility 1 | very low | low | very high | very high | n/a |
Elevation 2 (m.a.s.l.) | 2987 ± 85 | 2908 ± 82 | 2125 ± 6 | 2124 ± 7 | n/a |
Total No. of households | 33 | 92 | 199 | 311 | n/a |
Average household size (# of people) | 3.9 ± 1.0 a | 3.7 ± 1.1 a | 5.4 ± 1.2 b | 5.5 ± 1.2 b | F = 10.293, p < 0.001 |
Landholding per capita (mu) | 2.21 ± 0.87 a | 10.35 ± 6.67 b | 1.25 ± 0.37 c | 1.32 ± 0.69 c | F = 26.963, p < 0.001 |
Education 3,4 (y) | 2.97 ± 2.98 a | 3.76 ± 3.99 a | 8.77 ± 5.00 b | 8.69 ± 3.50 b | F = 23.863, p < 0.001 |
Education men 3 (y) | 4.50 ± 2.94 a | 5.61 ± 4.34 a | 10.18 ± 3.67 b | 9.24 ± 2.73 b | F = 13.676, p < 0.001 |
Education women 3 (y) | 1.33 ± 2.06 a | 1.69 ± 2.24 a | 7.11 ± 5.86 b | 8.21 ± 4.04 b | F = 14.345, p < 0.001 |
Table 2.
Variables showing economic differences and commonalities between two Bai villages in the valley and two Yi villages in the mountains of Shaxi Valley, SW China.
Table 2.
Variables showing economic differences and commonalities between two Bai villages in the valley and two Yi villages in the mountains of Shaxi Valley, SW China.
Variables | Mountains | Valley | ANOVA/Kruskal–Wallis |
---|
Xishan | Huacongshan | Changle | Silian |
---|
Subsistence income 1 per capita (CNY) | 417 ± 352 a | 1530 ± 2023 b | 805 ± 556 a,b | 854 ± 499 a,b | F = 2.588, p = 0.062 |
Total cash income per capita (CNY) | 2977 ± 1057 a | 4349 ± 2820 a | 4317 ± 3803 a | 3925 ± 1552 a | F = 0.929, p = 0.433 |
% of subsistence income in total income per capita 2 | 12.2 ± 7.6 | 23.3 ± 22.4 | 23.2 ± 21.1 | 20.2 ± 15.9 | χ2 = 1.844, df = 3, p = 0.605 |
Overall agricultural income per capita (CNY) | 1121 ± 681 a | 2332 ± 1296 a | 1462 ± 878 a | 2089 ± 1797 a | F = 2.711, p = 0.054 |
% of total cash income 3 | 38.5 ± 19.5 | 57.2 ± 15.8 | 46.1 ± 23.1 | 55.9 ± 38.0 | χ2 = 4.555, df = 3, p = 0.21 |
—Tobacco income per capita (CNY) | 0 a | 0 a | 157 ± 447 b | 911 ± 1117 c | F = 7.239, p < 0.001 |
% of total cash income | 0 | 0 | 4.7 ± 15.2 | 23.2 ± 27.9 | χ2 = 14.671, df = 3, p = 0.002 |
Overall forest resources income per capita (CNY) | 1549 ± 887 a | 1116 ± 1467 a | 165 ± 232 b | 73 ± 221 b | F = 11.272, p < 0.001 |
% of total cash income | 52.1 ± 25.1 | 23.6 ± 13.9 | 8.3 ± 15.1 | 1.4 ± 3.9 | χ2 = 37.539, df = 3, p < 0.001 |
—NTFP income per capita (CNY) | 734 ± 475 a,b | 1116 ± 1467 a | 165 ± 232 b | 73 ± 221 b | F = 6.349, p = 0.001 |
% of total cash income | 24.0 ± 14.2 | 23.6 ± 13.9 | 8.3 ± 15.1 | 1.4 ± 3.9 | χ2 = 30.971, df = 3, p < 0.001 |
—Logging income per capita (CNY) | 815 ± 500 a | 0 b | 0 b | 0 b | F = 41.120, p < 0.001 |
% of total cash income | 28.1 ± 15.5 | 0 | 0 | 0 | χ2 = 51.514, df = 3, p < 0.001 |
Overall off-farm income per capita (CNY) | 307 ± 676 a | 901 ± 1186 a,b | 2690 ± 3927 b | 1764 ± 1651 a,b | F = 2.843, p = 0.046 |
% of total cash income | 9.4 ± 23.2 | 19.2 ± 20.4 | 45.6 ± 29.8 | 42.6 ± 37.5 | χ2 = 15.061, df = 3, p = 0.002 |
—Local off-farm income per capita | 0 a | 58 ± 208 a | 1123 ± 2675 a | 343 ± 680 a | F = 1.877, p = 0.144 |
% of total cash income | 0 | 1.7 ± 6.2 | 15.1 ± 24.0 | 7.6 ± 16.3 | χ2 = 7.806, df = 3, p = 0.05 |
—Public service income per capita (CNY) | 122 ± 441 a | 282 ± 921 a | 820 ± 1710 a | 555 ± 1508 a | F = 0.830, p = 0.483 |
% of total cash income | 5.4 ± 19.5 | 7.1 ± 20.5 | 12.2 ± 23.0 | 11.1 ± 30.1 | χ2 = 3.100, df = 3, p = 0.376 |
—Migrant working income per capita (CNY) | 185 ± 666 a | 562 ± 982 a | 747 ± 1220 a | 866 ± 1090 a | F = 1.173, p = 0.328 |
% of total cash income | 4.0 ± 14.3 | 10.4 ± 13.5 | 18.3 ± 22.5 | 23.9 ± 30.8 | χ2 = 6.293, df = 3, p = 0.098 |
Gini coefficient | 0.178 | 0.303 | 0.384 | 0.218 | n/a |
Average Herfindahl diversity index | 0.42 | 0.55 | 0.52 | 0.33 | n/a |
Figure 2.
Comparison of income inequality (Lorenz curve and Gini coefficient) for the four villages surveyed. A higher Gini coefficient expresses higher income inequality within a village.
Figure 2.
Comparison of income inequality (Lorenz curve and Gini coefficient) for the four villages surveyed. A higher Gini coefficient expresses higher income inequality within a village.
3.1.2. At the Household Level
Agriculture is practiced by a vast majority of households in Shaxi, both in the mountains and the valley for subsistence and cash income (
Figure 3). In addition to agriculture, livelihood diversification is a key strategy. In the mountains, 96% of all households participate in the collection of NTFPs, compared to 41% in the valley. When looking at the cash income from the sale of different NTFPs, the importance of edible mushrooms is evident, as 79.2% ± 21.5% of the NTFP income of the households in the mountains and 73.2% ± 40.5% in the valley derives from the marketing of mushrooms. Medicinal plants contribute 11.5% ± 15.1% to the NTFP-income of the households in the mountains and 10.0% ± 25.2% in the valley. The remaining NTFPs, such as wild orchids, small game, and wild food plants contribute 9.3% ± 18.3% of NTFP-derived income for households in the mountains and 16.8% ± 36.5% in the valley.
Figure 3.
Share of households in the mountains and the valley participating in different livelihood activities.
Figure 3.
Share of households in the mountains and the valley participating in different livelihood activities.
Table 3 shows socio-demographic variables for three income groups for both mountain and valley households. While most of the variables, in particular education and household income diversification (Herfindahl diversity index), do not show significant differences between income groups of the same region, a remarkable exception is the increase of landholding per capita from low-income to high-income households in the mountains.
Table 4 examines economic variables for the three income groups of both regions. While in the valley wealth is not associated with agricultural and subsistence income, agricultural activities in the mountains positively correspond with wealth. In the valley it is predominantly the off-farm income that determines the wealth of a household.
Applying stepwise multiple linear regressions for the different livelihood activities, we clarify the patterns found in
Table 2. While some of the livelihood activities are influenced by structural and socio-demographic variables such as education or the number of elderly persons living in the household, other activities are explained by the household location in the mountains or the valley, respectively, or its affiliation to a certain village (
Table 5).
3.1.3. At the Individual Level
Off-farm income in Shaxi means well-paid and usually permanent jobs for higher educated people mainly from the valley’s lowland (daily income: 50–70 CNY plus in kind benefits), as well as temporary jobs with a lower salary for unskilled laborers (30–50 CNY per day). As a consequence of these employment opportunities, the threshold of an expected daily income for laborers is set at about 40–50 CNY per day. People who do not have the opportunities to engage in these remunerative occupations, namely elderly people and women, rely on low-income jobs, predominantly the collection of NTFPs. The daily income is about 15 CNY for medicinal plants and 22 CNY for mushrooms (median of all indications), and sometimes even much lower.
The collection of NTFPs is equally distributed between the sexes (
Table 6). The average age of NTFP collectors is significantly higher for collectors from the valley as compared to collectors from the mountains, both for mushrooms (independent samples
t-Test,
p = 0.015; age
valley = 45.3 ± 9.3; age
mountains = 33.8 ± 14.0;
n = 45) and medicinal plants (independent samples
t-Test,
p = 0.028; age
valley = 47.8 ± 12.9; age
mountains = 33.1 ± 13.4;
n = 24).
In contrast to the collection of NTFPs, off-farm work is clearly an occupation of young males with no significant difference between the age of off-farm laborers between the valley and the mountains (average age = 31 ± 7.8; min = 17; max = 43; n = 25), while NTFP collection is performed by all age classes (average age = 36.7 ± 14.0; min = 10; max = 70; n = 69).
Table 3.
Socio-demographic variables between three income groups (total income) in each the valley and the mountains of Shaxi Valley, SW China.
Table 3.
Socio-demographic variables between three income groups (total income) in each the valley and the mountains of Shaxi Valley, SW China.
Variables | Mountains | Valley | |
---|
Low-Income Group | Medium-Income Group | High-Income Group | Low-Income Group | Medium-Income Group | High-Income Group | ANOVA/Kruskal–Wallis |
---|
Average household size (# people) | 3.7 ± 1.0 a | 4.0 ± 0.8 a | 3.7 ± 1.3 a | 5.6 ± 1.6 b | 5.4 ± 0.7 b | 5.0 ± 0.8 a,b | F = 6.457, p < 0.001 |
Landholding per capita (mu) | 2.8 ± 1.7 a | 5.8 ± 4.5 a,b | 10.2 ± 8.3 b | 1.2 ± 0.5 a | 1.2 ± 0.5 a | 1.6 ± 0.5 a | F = 8.869, p < 0.001 |
Average household education (y) | 2.6 ± 1.7 a | 4.6 ± 1.9 a,b | 3.0 ± 1.9 a | 7.6 ± 2.3 b,c | 8.1 ± 3.1 c | 10.1 ± 2.4 c | F = 16.856, p < 0.001 |
Highest education in household (y) | 5.2 ± 3.4 a | 6.7 ± 2.3 a | 5.6 ± 5.1 a | 10.6 ± 4.1 a,b | 10.8 ± 4.3 a,b | 13.1 ± 3.6 b | F = 6.666, p < 0.001 |
Average Herfindahl diversity index | 0.46 ± 0.15 a | 0.51 ± 0.15 a | 0.49 ± 0.21 a | 0.35 ± 0.22 a | 0.43 ± 0.17 a | 0.50 ± 0.17 a | F = 1.112, p = 0.365 |
Table 4.
Economic variables between three income groups (total income) in each the valley and the mountains of Shaxi Valley, SW China.
Table 4.
Economic variables between three income groups (total income) in each the valley and the mountains of Shaxi Valley, SW China.
Variables | Mountains | Valley | |
---|
Low-Income group | Medium-Income group | High-Income Group | Low-Income Group | Medium-Income Group | High-Income Group | ANOVA/Kruskal–Wallis |
---|
Subsistence income 1 per capita (CNY) | 331 ± 189 a | 638 ± 654 a,b | 1914 ± 2313 a,b | 972 ± 517 a,b | 796 ± 450 a,b | 719 ± 603 a,b | F = 2.584, p = 0.036 |
Total cash income per capita (CNY) | 2367 ± 633 a | 3041 ± 934 a,b | 5512 ± 2765 b,c | 1904 ± 949 a | 3734 ± 689 a,b,c | 6742 ± 3518 c | F = 9.551, p < 0.001 |
Total income2 per capita (CNY) | 2698 ± 283 a | 3679 ± 499 a | 7427 ± 3723 b | 2876 ± 743 a | 4530 ± 573 a,c | 7461 ± 3203 b,c | F = 10.909, p < 0.001 |
% of subsistence income in total income | 12.7 ± 8.2 | 18.1 ± 18.3 | 22.4 ± 22.9 | 36.0 ± 22.8 | 17.7 ± 10.6 | 11.5 ± 10.4 | χ2 = 10.136, df = 5, p = 0.071 |
Overall agricultural income per capita (CNY) | 1124 ± 441 a | 1332 ± 607 a | 2680 ± 1518 a | 1286 ± 980 a | 1614 ± 1093 a | 2396 ± 1879 a | F = 2.650, p = 0.033 |
% of total cash income | 47.4 ± 15.9 | 46.0 ± 21.6 | 50.0 ± 23.5 | 66.9 ± 29.4 | 44.6 ± 29.6 | 41.0 ± 30.6 | χ2 = 4.940, df = 5, p = 0.423 |
—Tobacco income per capita (CNY) | 0 a | 0 a | 0 a | 307 ± 728 b | 700 ± 993 b | 561 ± 1,029 b | F = 1.995, p = 0.094 |
% of total cash income3 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 10.8 ± 23.9 | 20.6 ± 29.0 | 9.7 ± 17.9 | χ2 = 9.790, df = 5, p = 0.081 |
Overall forest resources income per capita (CNY) | 1001 ± 601 a,b,c | 1263 ± 598 b,c | 1725 ± 1893 c | 101 ± 164 a | 73 ±164 a | 187 ± 323 a,b | F = 7.093, p < 0.001 |
% of total cash income | 41.5 ± 21.1 | 42.8 ± 22.9 | 29.8 ± 29.7 | 9.1 ± 17.9 | 2.6 ± 6.5 | 3.2 ± 5.8 | χ2 = 34.421, df = 5, p < 0.001 |
—NTFP income per capita (CNY) | 465 ± 302 a,b | 938 ± 349 a,b | 1373 ± 1738 b | 101 ± 164 a | 73 ±164 a | 187 ± 323 a | F = 5.119, p = 0.001 |
% of total cash income | 19.3 ± 11.1 | 31.5 ± 11.0 | 21.4 ± 16.7 | 9.1 ± 17.9 | 2.6 ± 6.5 | 3.2 ± 5.8 | χ2 = 31.707, df = 5, p < 0.001 |
—Logging income per capita (CNY) | 536 ± 430 a | 325 ± 440 a | 352 ± 729 a | 0 b | 0 b | 0 b | F = 3.957, p = 0.004 |
% of total cash income | 22.2 ± 18.6 | 11.3 ± 15.8 | 8.4 ± 18.0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | χ2 = 23.875, df = 5, p < 0.001 |
Overall off-farm income per capita (CNY) | 242 ± 522 a | 446 ± 834 a | 1107 ±1394 a | 517 ± 671 a | 2047 ± 1390 a,b | 4159 ± 4442 b | F = 5.053, p = 0.001 |
% of total cash income | 11.2 ± 23.2 | 11.2 ± 18.5 | 20.2 ± 24.7 | 24.0 ± 28.9 | 52.8 ± 32.0 | 55.8 ± 31.7 | χ2 = 18.828, df = 5, p = 0.002 |
— Local off-farm income per capita | 0 a | 0 a | 83 ± 250 a | 0 a | 538 ± 839 a | 1695 ± 3207 a | F = 2.305, p = 0.057 |
% of total cash income | 0 | 0 | 2.5 ± 7.4 | 0 | 13.8 ± 21.2 | 20.6 ± 25.9 | χ2 = 18.117, df = 5, p = 0.003 |
—Public service income per capita (CNY) | 214 ± 528 a | 0 a | 370 ± 1,111 a | 172 ± 513 a | 445 ± 1,445 a | 1457 ± 2189 a | F = 1.796, p = 0.130 |
% of total cash income | 10.0 ± 23.5 | 0 | 8.1 ± 24.2 | 7.0 ± 20.9 | 9.0 ± 28.9 | 19.1 ± 29.2 | χ2 = 4.376, df = 5, p = 0.497 |
—Migrant working income per capita (CNY) | 28 ± 83 a | 446 ± 834 a | 654 ± 1,167 a | 344 ± 548 a | 1063 ± 1084 a | 1006 ± 1533 a | F = 1.572, p = 0.184 |
% of total cash income | 1.1 ± 3.3 | 11.2 ± 18.5 | 9.6 ± 15.5 | 17.0 ± 24.8 | 30.0 ± 31.1 | 16.1 ± 23.4 | χ2 = 7.799, df = 5, p = 0.168 |
Table 5.
Stepwise multiple linear regression for the different income sources as dependent variables.
Table 5.
Stepwise multiple linear regression for the different income sources as dependent variables.
Income Source | Explanatory Variable | B (T) | Summary of Model |
---|
Total income 1 per capita (CNY) | Intercept | (2.392) * | R = 0.515; Adjusted R2 = 0.238 |
Total agricultural land/capita | 0.490 (3.962) *** | |
Household mean education level | 0.388 (3.136) ** | |
Total cash income per capita (CNY) | Intercept | (3.742) *** | R = 0.288; Adjusted R2 = 0.066 |
Household mean education level | 0.288 (2.233) * | |
Subsistence income 2 per capita (CNY) | Intercept | (4.184) *** | R = 0.685; Adjusted R2 = 0.450 |
Total agricultural land/capita | 0.790 (6.876) *** | |
Mountain (dummy) | −0.332 (−2.891) ** | |
% of subsistence income in total income | No statistically significant explanatory variable | | n/a |
Overall agricultural income per capita (CNY) | Intercept | (4.996) *** | R = 0.394; Adjusted R2 = 0.126 |
Total agricultural land/capita | 0.377 (2.969) ** | |
Silian (dummy) | 0.263 (2.071) * | |
% of total cash income | Intercept | (9.308) *** | R = 0.430; Adjusted R2 = 0.156 |
Household maximum education level | −0.419 (−3.172) ** | |
Xishan (dummy) | −0.380 (−2.875) ** | |
—Tobacco income per capita (CNY) | Intercept | (0.686) | R = 0.488; Adjusted R2 = 0.224 |
Silian (dummy) | 0.488 (4.145) *** | |
% of total cash income3 | Intercept | (0.784) | R = 0.465; Adjusted R2 = 0.202 |
Silian (dummy) | 0.465 (3.900) *** | |
Overall forest resources income per capita (CNY) | Intercept | (2.893) ** | R = 0.660; Adjusted R2 = 0.415 |
Mountains (dummy) | 0.391 (3.085) ** | |
Household size | −0.349 (−2.756) ** | |
% of total cash income | Intercept | (5.116) *** | R = 0.800; Adjusted R2 = 0.620 |
Xishan (dummy) | 0.524 (5.499) *** | |
Household size | −0.238 (−2.566) * | |
Household mean education level | −0.237 (−2.363) * | |
—NTFP income per capita (CNY) | Intercept | (3.967) *** | R = 0.552; Adjusted R2 = 0.279 |
Household size | −0.409 (−3.331) ** | |
Huacongshan (dummy) | 0.247 (2.014) * | |
% of total cash income | Intercept | (6.729) *** | R = 0.636; Adjusted R2 = 0.382 |
Household mean education level | −0.486 (−4.141) *** | |
Household size | −0.248 (−2.111) * | |
—Logging income per capita (CNY) | Intercept | (0.000) | R = 0.830; Adjusted R2 = 0.684 |
Xishan (dummy) | 0.830 (11.051) *** | |
% of total cash income | Intercept | (0.000) | R = 0.856; Adjusted R2 = 0.728 |
Xishan (dummy) | 0.856 (12.282) *** | |
Overall off-farm income per capita (CNY) | Intercept | (−1.457) | R = 0.609; Adjusted R2 = 0.348 |
Household mean education level | 0.426 (3.585) *** | |
Old persons in household | 0.292 (2.459) * | |
% of total cash income | Intercept | (−0.857) | R = 0.669; Adjusted R2 = 0.427 |
Household maximum education level | 0.534 (4.934) *** | |
Old persons in household | 0.254 (2.349) * | |
—Local off-farm income per capita | Intercept | (−1.733) | R = 0.493; Adjusted R2 = 0.215 |
Old persons in household | 0.295 (2.266) * | |
Household mean education level | 0.290 (2.222) * | |
% of total cash income | Intercept | (−1.307) | R = 0.423; Adjusted R2 = 0.164 |
Household mean education level | 0.423 (3.465) *** | |
—Public service income per capita (CNY) | Intercept | (−3.791) *** | R = 0.684; Adjusted R2 = 0.438 |
Household maximum education level | 0.567 (4.486) *** | |
Old persons in households | 0.445 (4.015) *** | |
Dummy mountains | 0.326 (2.530) * | |
% of total cash income | Intercept | (−3.163) ** | R = 0.613; Adjusted R2 = 0.341 |
Old persons in household | 0.412 (3.437) *** | |
Household maximum education level | 0.515 (3.756) *** | |
Dummy mountain | 0.357 (2.556) * | |
—Migrant working income per capita (CNY) | No statistically significant explanatory variable | | n/a |
% of total cash income | Intercept | (−5.672) *** | R = 0.408; Adjusted R2 = 0.136 |
Dummy mountain | −0.432 (−3.187) ** | |
Old persons in household | −0.274 (−2.022) * | |
Table 6.
Gender distribution of mushroom and medicinal plant collection as well as off-farm employment.
Table 6.
Gender distribution of mushroom and medicinal plant collection as well as off-farm employment.
Location | Sex of Collectors | Mushrooms | Medicinal Plants | Off-Farm |
---|
Valley | Male | 45% | 50% | 89% |
Female | 55% | 50% | 11% |
Mountains | Male | 44% | 44% | 100% |
Female | 56% | 56% | 0% |