Unraveling Platform Strategies: A Review from an Organizational Ambidexterity Perspective
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Theoretical Background
2.1. OA Theory
2.2. OA Perspectives for Platform Strategies
3. Methods
4. Findings
4.1. Pricing
4.2. Openness
4.3. Integration
4.4. Differentiation
4.5. Envelopment
5. Future Research
5.1. Managing Several Platform Strategies
5.2. Interactions between Supply-Side Agents and Platform Owners
5.3. Roles of Demand-Side Agents and Implications for Platform Strategies
6. Conclusions
Acknowledgments
Author Contributions
Conflicts of Interest
Appendix A. Diversity of Platform Ecosystem Research
Type of platform | Function | Theory and Perspective | Methodology | Ref. |
---|---|---|---|---|
E-commerce | Facilitate same-side interaction | Two-sided markets | Analytics, simulations, case study | [43] |
Facilitate information exchange | Transaction cost theory | Case study | [53] | |
Facilitate matching | Two-sided markets | Statistical test | [90] | |
Allow operational and strategic benefits | Technology adoption | Logit model | [120] | |
Facilitate information aggregation | Information systems; Two-sided markets | Game model | [99] | |
Facilitate collaboration | Information systems | Game model | [121] | |
Facilitate information exchange | Information systems; Agency theory; Interpersonal communication | Lab experiment | [122] | |
Allow operational and strategic benefits | Institutional theory; Structuration theory of technology assimilation | Structural equation model | [123] | |
Online community | Enable incomplete designs that lead to continuous evolution | Organizational perspective | Case study | [124] |
Facilitate user innovation | Social theory | Case study | [125] | |
Facilitate same-side interaction | Business model; Socioeconomic approach | Case study | [126] | |
Facilitate information aggregation | Marketing approach of new-product diffusion; Sociology perspective of social network analysis | Hazard-rate model | [127] | |
Facilitate information exchange | Attribution theory | Lab experiment | [128] | |
Enable firms to strengthen their innovation process | Information approach; Social psychology; Behavioral economics | Statistical test | [129] | |
Motivate knowledge co-creation | Knowledge based view; Organizational perspective | Statistical test | [130] | |
Facilitate information exchange | Opinion-leader theory; Cognitive dissonance; Organizational psychology | Structural equation model | [131] | |
Create business opportunities for other firms | Austrian economics theory of entrepreneurial discovery; Creative collective theory; | Case study | [132] | |
Facilitate information aggregation | Interactionist theory of place attachment | Lab experiment and structural equation model | [133] | |
Trigger effective entrepreneurial thinking and action | Decision making | Interviews | [134] | |
Facilitate user innovation | Social network | Theoretical framework | [135] | |
Facilitate matching | Marketing perspectives | Theoretical framework | [136] | |
Payment cards | Exploit network effects | Two-sided markets | Game model | [137] |
Create specific roles with particular characteristics, like platform providers and platform sponsor | Two-sided markets | Game model | [54] | |
Facilitate same-side interaction | Two-sided markets; Transaction costs | Statistical test | [52] | |
Software | Exploit complementarities | Resource based view; Complementarity approach | Statistical test | [138] |
Provide profitability and utility to developers and users | Network effects; Systems perspective | Game model | [51] | |
Motivate value co-creation and signaling | Resource based view; Institutional theory; Intellectual property rights | Statistical test | [109] | |
Facilitate recombination and reuse | Two-sided markets | Statistical test | [98] | |
Facilitate same-side interaction | Organizational perspective; Two-sided markets | Logit model | [139] | |
Facilitate recombination and reuse | Two-sided markets; Platform architecture approach | Statistical test | [44] | |
Video console | Attract valuable participants | Network theory | Logit model | [140] |
Facilitate matching | Two-sided markets; Contracts | Statistical test | [141] | |
Create new mechanisms of entry and defense for entrants and incumbents | Expectation-driven view; Network effects; Dynamic competition; Technology adoption | Structural econometric model | [2] |
References
- Kenney, M.; Pon, B. Structuring the smartphone industry: Is the mobile internet OS platform the key? J. Ind. Compet. Trade 2011, 11, 239–261. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhu, F.; Iansiti, M. Entry into platform-based markets. Strat. Manag. J. 2012, 33, 88–106. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- West, J. How open is open enough? Melding proprietary and open source platform strategies. Res. Policy 2003, 32, 1259–1285. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ou, C.X.; Pavlou, P.A.; Davison, R.M. Swift Guanxi in online marketplaces: The role of computer-mediated communication technologies. Manag. Inf. Syst. Q. 2014, 38, 209–230. [Google Scholar]
- Rai, A.; Tang, X. Leveraging IT capabilities and competitive process capabilities for the management of interorganizational relationship portfolios. Inf. Syst. Res. 2010, 21, 516–542. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yoo, Y.; Boland, R.J.; Lyytinen, K.; Majchrzak, A. Organizing for innovation in the digitized world. Org. Sci. 2012, 23, 1398–1408. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Tiwana, A. Platform Ecosystems: Aligning Architecture, Governance, and Strategy; Morgan Kaufmann: Burlington, MA, USA, 2013. [Google Scholar]
- Gawer, A. Bridging differing perspectives on technological platforms: Toward an integrative framework. Res. Policy 2014, 43, 1239–1249. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- McIntyre, D.P.; Srinivasan, A. Networks, platforms, and strategy: Emerging views and next steps. Strat. Manag. J. 2017, 38, 141–160. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Thomas, L.D.W.; Autio, E.; Gann, D.M. Architectural leverage: Putting platforms in context. Acad. Manag. Perspect. 2014, 28, 198–219. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hagiu, A. Strategic decisions for multisided platforms. MIT Sloan Manag. Rev. 2014, 55, 92–93. [Google Scholar]
- Van Alstyne, M.; Parker, G.; Choudary, S.P. Pipelines, platforms, and the new rules of strategy. Harvard Bus. Rev. 2016, 94, 54–62. [Google Scholar]
- Van Alstyne, M.; Parker, G.; Choudary, S.P. 6 Reasons Platforms Fail. Available online: https://hbr.org/2016/03/6-reasons-platforms-fail (accessed on 26 April 2016).
- Farrell, J.; Saloner, G. Standardization, compatibility, and innovation. RAND J. Econ. 1985, 16, 70–83. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gupta, A.K.; Smith, K.G.; Shalley, C.E. The interplay between exploration and exploitation. Acad. Manag. J. 2006, 49, 693–706. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- March, J.G. Exploration and exploitation in organizational learning. Org. Sci. 1991, 2, 71–87. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Lavie, D.; Stettner, U.; Tushman, M.L. Exploration and exploitation within and across organizations. Acad. Manag. Ann. 2010, 4, 109–155. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Eisenmann, T.; Parker, G.; van Alstyne, M. Strategies for two-sided markets. Harvard Bus. Rev. 2006, 84, 92–101. [Google Scholar]
- Rochet, J.C.; Tirole, J. Platform competition in two-sided markets. J. Eur. Econ. Assoc. 2003, 1, 990–1029. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gawer, A.; Cusumano, M.A. How companies become platform leaders. MIT Sloan Manag. Rev. 2008, 49, 28–35. [Google Scholar]
- Baldwin, C.; Woodard, C.J. The architecture of platforms: A unified view. In Platforms, Markets and Innovation; Gawer, A., Ed.; Edward Elgar Publishing: Cheltenham, UK; Northampton, MA, USA, 2009; pp. 19–44. [Google Scholar]
- Parker, G.; van Alstyne, M. Platform Strategy. In The Palgrave Encyclopedia of Strategic Management; Augier, M., Teece, D.J., Eds.; Palgrave Macmillan: London, UK, 2016; pp. 1–9. [Google Scholar]
- Parker, G.; van Alstyne, M.; Jiang, X. Platform ecosystems: How developers invert the firm. Manag. Inf. Syst. Q. 2017, 41, 255–266. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Parker, G.; van Alstyne, M.; Choudary, S.P. Platform Revolution: How Networked Markets Are Transforming the Economy and How to Make Them Work for You, 1st ed.; W. W. Norton & Company: New York, NY, USA, 2016. [Google Scholar]
- Levinthal, D.A.; March, J.G. The myopia of learning. Strat. Manag. J. 1993, 14, 95–112. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Andriopoulos, C.; Lewis, M.W. Exploitation-exploration tensions and organizational ambidexterity: Managing paradoxes of innovation. Org. Sci. 2009, 20, 696–717. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- He, Z.L.; Wong, P.K. Exploration vs. exploitation: An empirical test of the ambidexterity hypothesis. Org. Sci. 2004, 15, 481–494. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kristal, M.M.; Huang, X.; Roth, A.V. The effect of an ambidextrous supply chain strategy on combinative competitive capabilities and business performance. J. Oper. Manag. 2010, 28, 415–429. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Smith, W.K.; Tushman, M.L. Managing strategic contradictions: A top management model for managing innovation streams. Org. Sci. 2005, 16, 522–536. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Maletič, M.; Maletič, D.; Dahlgaard, J.J.; Dahlgaard-Park, S.M.; Gomišček, B. Sustainability exploration and sustainability exploitation: From a literature review towards a conceptual framework. J. Clean. Prod. 2014, 79, 182–194. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Simsek, Z. Organizational ambidexterity: Towards a multilevel understanding. J. Manag. Stud. 2009, 46, 597–624. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Chen, Y.S.; Chang, C.H.; Lin, Y.H. The determinants of green radical and incremental innovation performance: Green shared vision, green absorptive capacity, and green organizational ambidexterity. Sustainability 2014, 6, 7787–7806. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Simsek, Z.; Heavey, C.; Veiga, J.F.; Souder, D. A typology for aligning organizational ambidexterity’s conceptualizations, antecedents, and outcomes. J. Manag. Stud. 2009, 46, 864–894. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gibson, C.B.; Birkinshaw, J. The antecedents, consequences, and mediating role of organizational ambidexterity. Acad. Manag. J. 2004, 47, 209–226. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Raisch, S.; Birkinshaw, J.; Probst, G.; Tushman, M.L. Organizational ambidexterity: Balancing exploitation and exploration for sustained performance. Org. Sci. 2009, 20, 685–695. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Winterhalter, S.; Zeschky, M.B.; Gassmann, O. Managing dual business models in emerging markets: An ambidexterity perspective: Managing dual business models in emerging markets. R&D Manag. 2016, 46, 464–479. [Google Scholar]
- Lavie, D. The competitive advantage of interconnected firms: An extension of the resource-based view. Acad. Manag. Rev. 2006, 31, 638–658. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gupta, S.; Mela, C.F. What is a free customer worth? Harvard Bus. Rev. 2008, 86, 102–109. [Google Scholar]
- Rochet, J.C.; Tirole, J. Two-sided markets: A progress report. RAND J. Econ. 2006, 37, 645–667. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Roson, R. Two-sided markets: A tentative survey. Rev. Netw. Econ. 2005, 4, 142–160. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Webster, J.; Watson, R.T. Analyzing the past to prepare for the future: Writing a literature review. Manag. Inf. Syst. Q. 2002, 26, xiii–xxiii. [Google Scholar]
- Parker, G.; Van Alstyne, M. Two-sided network effects: A theory of information product design. Manag. Sci. 2005, 51, 1494–1504. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Eisenmann, T.; Parker, G.; van Alstyne, M. Platform envelopment. Strat. Manag. J. 2011, 32, 1270–1285. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Boudreau, K.J. Let a thousand flowers bloom? An early look at large numbers of software APP developers and patterns of innovation. Org. Sci. 2012, 23, 1409–1427. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Casey, T.R.; Töyli, J. Dynamics of two-sided platform success and failure: An analysis of public wireless local area access. Technovation 2012, 32, 703–716. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Eckhardt, J.T. Welcome contributor or no price competitor? The competitive interaction of free and priced technologies: The Competitive Interaction of Free and Priced Technologies. Strat. Manag. J. 2016, 37, 742–762. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Parker, G.; Van Alstyne, M. Information complements, substitutes, and strategic product design. In Proceedings of the Twenty First International Conference on Information Systems, Brisbane, Queensland, Australia, 10–13 December 2000; Association for Information Systems: Atlanta, GA, USA; pp. 13–15. [Google Scholar]
- Anderson, E.G.; Parker, G.; Tan, B. Platform performance investment in the presence of network externalities. Inf. Syst. Res. 2014, 25, 152–172. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Boudreau, K.J.; Jeppesen, L.B. Unpaid crowd complementors: The platform network effect mirage. Strat. Manag. J. 2015, 36, 1761–1777. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Armstrong, M.; Wright, J. Two-sided markets, competitive bottlenecks and exclusive contracts. Econ. Theory 2007, 32, 353–380. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Economides, N.; Katsamakas, E. Two-sided competition of proprietary vs. open source technology platforms and the implications for the software industry. Manag. Sci. 2006, 52, 1057–1071. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zinman, J. Debit or credit? J. Bank. Financ. 2009, 33, 358–366. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Felfernig, A.; Friedrich, G.; Jannach, D.; Zanker, M. An integrated environment for the development of knowledge-based recommender applications. Int. J. Electron. Commer. 2006, 11, 11–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wright, J. The determinants of optimal interchange fees in payment systems. J. Ind. Econ. 2004, 52, 1–26. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Armstrong, M. Competition in two-sided markets. RAND J. Econ. 2006, 37, 668–691. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hagiu, A. Pricing and commitment by two-sided platforms. RAND J. Econ. 2006, 37, 720–737. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Valverde, S.C.; Chakravorti, S.; Fernández, F.R. The role of interchange fees in two-sided markets: An empirical investigation on payment cards. Rev. Econ. Stat. 2016, 98, 367–381. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Evans, D.S.; Schmalensee, R. Failure to launch: Critical mass in platform businesses. Rev. Netw. Econ. 2010, 9. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Fang, E.; Li, X.; Huang, M.; Palmatier, R.W. Direct and indirect effects of buyers and sellers on search advertising revenues in business-to-business electronic platforms. J. Mark. Res. 2015, 52, 407–422. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Liu, H. Dynamics of pricing in the video game console market: skimming or penetration? J. Mark. Res. 2010, 47, 428–443. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Eisenmann, T.; Parker, G.; Van Alstyne, M. Opening platforms: How, when and why? In Platforms, Markets and Innovation; Gawer, A., Ed.; Edward Elgar Publishing: Cheltenham, UK; Northampton, MA, USA, 2009; pp. 131–162. [Google Scholar]
- Schilling, M.A. Protecting or diffusing a technology platform. In Platforms, Markets and Innovation; Gawer, A., Ed.; Edward Elgar Publishing: Northampton, MA, USA; Northampton, MA, USA, 2009; pp. 192–218. [Google Scholar]
- Rysman, M. The economics of two-sided markets. J. Econ. Perspect. 2009, 23, 125–143. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Farrell, J.; Monroe, H.K.; Saloner, G. The vertical organization of industry: Systems competition versus component competition. J. Econ. Manag. Strat. 1998, 7, 143–182. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Farrell, J.; Saloner, G. Installed base and compatibility: Innovation, product preannouncements, and predation. Am. Econ. Rev. 1986, 76, 940–955. [Google Scholar]
- Chen, K.M.; Liu, R.J. Interface strategies in modular product innovation. Technovation 2005, 25, 771–782. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Boudreau, K.J. Open platform strategies and innovation: Granting access versus devolving control. Manag. Sci. 2010, 56, 1849–1872. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Rysman, M.; Simcoe, T. Patents and the performance of voluntary standard-setting organizations. Manag. Sci. 2008, 54, 1920–1934. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gawer, A.; Henderson, R. Platform owner entry and innovation in complementary markets: Evidence from Intel. J. Econ. Manag. Strat. 2007, 16, 1–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Lee, R.S. Vertical integration and exclusivity in platform and two-sided markets. Am. Econ. Rev. 2013, 103, 2960–3000. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hagiu, A.; Wright, J. Marketplace or reseller? Manag. Sci. 2014, 61, 184–203. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hagiu, A.; Wright, J. Multi-sided platforms. Int. J. Ind. Org. 2015, 43, 162–174. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dewan, S.; Ganley, D.; Kraemer, K.L. Complementarities in the diffusion of personal computers and the internet: Implications for the global digital divide. Inf. Syst. Res. 2010, 21, 925–940. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Fuentelsaz, L.; Garrido, E.; Maicas, J.P. Incumbents, technological change and institutions: How the value of complementary resources varies across markets. Strat. Manag. J. 2015, 36, 1778–1801. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Lee, C.H.; Venkatraman, N.; Tanriverdi, H.; Iyer, B. Complementarity-based hypercompetition in the software industry: Theory and empirical test, 1990–2002. Strat. Manag. J. 2010, 31, 1431–1456. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Nambisan, S. Complementary product integration by high-technology new ventures: The role of initial technology strategy. Manag. Sci. 2002, 48, 382–398. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hagiu, A.; Spulber, D. First-party content and coordination in two-sided markets. Manag. Sci. 2013, 59, 933–949. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Smedlund, A. Value cocreation in service platform business models. Serv. Sci. 2012, 4, 79–88. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Clements, M.T.; Ohashi, H. Indirect network effects and the product cycle: Video games in the U.S., 1994–2002. J. Ind. Econ. 2005, 53, 515–542. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Johns, J. Video games production networks: Value capture, power relations and embeddedness. J. Econ. Geogr. 2006, 6, 151–180. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Marchand, A.; Hennig-Thurau, T. Value creation in the video game industry: Industry economics, consumer benefits, and research opportunities. J. Interact. Mark. 2013, 27, 141–157. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Farrell, J.; Katz, M.L. Innovation, rent extraction, and integration in systems markets. J. Ind. Econ. 2000, 48, 413–432. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhu, F.; Liu, Q. Competing with Complementors: An Empirical Look at Amazon.com; Social Science Research Network: Rochester, NY, USA, 2015. [Google Scholar]
- Keen, P.; Williams, R. Value architectures for digital business: Beyond the business model. Manag. Inf. Syst. Q. 2013, 37, 642–647. [Google Scholar]
- Brousseau, E.; Penard, T. The economics of digital business models: A framework for analyzing the economics of platforms. Rev. Netw. Econ. 2007, 6, 81–114. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gretz, R.T. Hardware quality vs. network size in the home video game industry. J. Econ. Behav. Org. 2010, 76, 168–183. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hagiu, A. Two-sided platforms: Product variety and pricing structures. J. Econ. Manag. Strat. 2009, 18, 1011–1043. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kind, H.J.; Schjelderup, G.; Stähler, F. Newspaper differentiation and investments in journalism: The role of tax policy. Economica 2013, 80, 131–148. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gal-Or, E.; Geylani, T.; Yildirim, T.P. The impact of advertising on media bias. J. Mark. Res. 2012, 49, 92–99. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hendel, I.; Nevo, A.; Ortalo-Magné, F. The relative performance of real estate marketing platforms: MLS versus FSBOMadison.com. Am. Econ. Rev. 2009, 99, 1878–1898. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sridhar, S.; Mantrala, M.K.; Naik, P.A.; Thorson, E. Dynamic marketing budgeting for platform firms: Theory, evidence, and application. J. Mark. Res. 2011, 48, 929–943. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Jha, S.K.; Pinsonneault, A.; Dubé, L. The evolution of an ICT platform-enabled ecosystem for poverty alleviation: The case of eKutir. Manag. Inf. Syst. Q. 2016, 40, 431–445. [Google Scholar]
- Pepall, L.M.; Richards, D.J. Reach for the stars: A strategic bidding game. Economica 2001, 68, 489–504. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yoo, E.; Rand, W.; Eftekhar, M.; Rabinovich, E. Evaluating information diffusion speed and its determinants in social media networks during humanitarian crises. J. Oper. Manag. 2016, 45, 123–133. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cennamo, C.; Santalo, J. Platform competition: Strategic trade-offs in platform markets. Strat. Manag. J. 2013, 34, 1331–1350. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kapoor, R.; Furr, N.R. Complementarities and competition: Unpacking the drivers of entrants’ technology choices in the solar photovoltaic industry: Complementarities and Competition. Strat. Manag. J. 2015, 36, 416–436. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- De Sordi, J.O.; Nelson, R.E.; Meireles, M.; da Silveira, M.A. Development of digital products and services: Proposal of a framework to analyze versioning actions. Eur. Manag. J. 2016, 34, 564–578. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gallaugher, J.M.; Wang, Y.M. Understanding network effects in software markets: Evidence from web server pricing. Manag. Inf. Syst. Q. 2002, 26, 303–327. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bhargava, H.K.; Choudhary, V. Economics of an information intermediary with aggregation benefits. Inf. Syst. Res. 2004, 15, 22–36. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Suárez, F.F.; Kirtley, J. Innovation strategy—Dethroning an established platform. MIT Sloan Manag. Rev. 2012, 53, 35–43. [Google Scholar]
- Choudary, S.P. Piggybacking Mechanics: WhatsApp, Instagram and Network Effect Marketing: Platform Thinking. Available online: http://platformed.info/whatsapp-instagram-marketing/ (accessed on 29 May 2014).
- Bharadwaj, A.; El Sawy, O.A.; Pavlou, P.A.; Venkatraman, N. Digital business strategy: Toward a next generation of insights. Manag. Inf. Syst. Q. 2013, 37, 471–482. [Google Scholar]
- Sun, M.; Tse, E. The Resource-Based View of competitive advantage in two-sided markets. J. Manag. Stud. 2009, 46, 45–64. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Peitz, M.; Valletti, T.M. Content and advertising in the media: pay-tv versus free-to-air. Int. J. Ind. Org. 2008, 26, 949–965. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ennen, E.; Richter, A. The whole is more than the sum of its parts—Or is it? A review of the empirical literature on complementarities in organizations. J. Manag. 2010, 36, 207–233. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cenamor, J.; Usero, B.; Fernández, Z. The role of complementary products on platform adoption: Evidence from the video console market. Technovation 2013, 33, 405–416. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Li, S.; Liu, Y.; Bandyopadhyay, S. Network effects in online two-sided market platforms: A research note. Decis. Support Syst. 2010, 49, 245–249. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Fréry, F.; Lecocq, X.; Warnier, V. Competing with ordinary resources. MIT Sloan Manag. Rev. 2015, 56, 69–77. [Google Scholar]
- Ceccagnoli, M.; Forman, C.; Huang, P.; Wu, D.J. Cocreation of value in a platform ecosystem: The case of enterprise software. Manag. Inf. Syst. Q. 2012, 36, 263–290. [Google Scholar]
- Zhu, F.; Liu, Q. When Platforms Attack. Harvard Bus. Rev. 2015, 93, 30–31. [Google Scholar]
- Feijoo, C.; Gómez-Barroso, J.L.; Aguado, J.M.; Ramos, S. Mobile gaming: Industry challenges and policy implications. Telecommun. Policy 2012, 36, 212–221. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Li, Y.R. The technological roadmap of Cisco’s business ecosystem. Technovation 2009, 29, 379–386. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Tiwana, A.; Konsynski, B.; Bush, A.A. Platform evolution: Coevolution of platform architecture, governance, and environmental dynamics. Inf. Syst. Res. 2010, 21, 675–687. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bapna, R.; Goes, P.; Gupta, A.; Jin, Y. User heterogeneity and its impact on electronic auction market design: An empirical exploration. Manag. Inf. Syst. Q. 2004, 28, 21–43. [Google Scholar]
- Franke, N.; Von Hippel, E. Satisfying heterogeneous user needs via innovation toolkits: The case of Apache security software. Open Sour. Softw. Dev. 2003, 32, 1199–1215. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Weyl, E.G. A price theory of multi-sided platforms. Am. Econ. Rev. 2010, 100, 1642–1672. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- García-Crespo, Á.; Colomo-Palacios, R.; Gómez-Berbís, J.M.; Ruiz-Mezcua, B. SEMO: A framework for customer social networks analysis based on semantics. J. Inf. Technol. 2010, 25, 178–188. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Li, F.; Pieńkowski, D.; van Moorsel, A.; Smith, C. A holistic framework for trust in online transactions. Int. J. Manag. Rev. 2012, 14, 85–103. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Oestreicher-Singer, G.; Zalmanson, L. Content or community? A digital business strategy for content providers in the social age. Manag. Inf. Syst. Q. 2013, 37, 591–616. [Google Scholar]
- Hong, W.; Zhu, K. Migrating to internet-based e-commerce: factors affecting e-commerce adoption and migration at the firm level. Inf. Manag. 2006, 43, 204–221. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhu, K. Information transparency of Business-to-Business electronic markets: A game-theoretic analysis. Manag. Sci. 2004, 50, 670–685. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wang, W.; Benbasat, I. Recommendation agents for electronic commerce: Effects of explanation facilities on trusting beliefs. J. Manag. Inf. Syst. 2007, 23, 217–246. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Chatterjee, D.; Grewal, R.; Sambamurthy, V. Shaping up for e-commerce: institutional enablers of the organizational assimilation of web technologies. Manag. Inf. Syst. Q. 2002, 26, 65–89. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Garud, R.; Jain, S.; Tuertscher, P. Incomplete by design and designing for incompleteness. Org. Stud. 2008, 29, 351–371. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Lai, L.S.L.; Turban, E. Groups formation and operations in the web 2.0 environment and social networks. Group Decis. Negot. 2008, 17, 387–402. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Lechner, U.; Hummel, J. Business models and system architectures of virtual communities: From a sociological phenomenon to peer-to-peer architectures. Int. J. Electron. Commer. 2002, 6, 41–54. [Google Scholar]
- Katona, Z.; Zubcsek, P. P.; Sarvary, M. Network effects and personal influences: The diffusion of an online social network. J. Market. Res. 2011, 48, 425–443. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Lee, M.; Youn, S. Electronic word of mouth (eWOM): How eWOM platforms influence consumer product judgement. Int. J. Advert. 2009, 28, 473–499. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Jeppesen, L.B.; Frederiksen, L. Why do users contribute to firm-hosted user communities? The case of computer-controlled music instruments. Org. Sci. 2006, 17, 45–63. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ransbotham, S.; Kane, G.C. Membership turnover and collaboration success in online communities: Explaining rises and falls from Grace in Wikipedia. Manag. Inf. Syst. Q. 2011, 35, 613–627. [Google Scholar]
- Hennig-Thurau, T.; Walsh, G. Electronic word-of-mouth: Motives for and consequences of reading customer articulations on the internet. Int. J. Electron. Commer. 2003, 8, 51–74. [Google Scholar]
- Chandra, Y.; Leenders, M.A.A.M. User innovation and entrepreneurship in the virtual world: A study of Second Life residents. Technovation 2012, 32, 464–476. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Goel, L.; Johnson, N.A.; Junglas, I.; Ives, B. From space to place: predicting users’ intentions to return to virtual worlds. Manag. Inf. Syst. Q. 2011, 35, 749–772. [Google Scholar]
- Fischer, E.; Reuber, A.R. Social interaction via new social media: (How) can interactions on Twitter affect effectual thinking and behavior? J. Bus. Ventur. 2011, 26, 1–18. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kietzmann, J.H.; Hermkens, K.; McCarthy, I.P.; Silvestre, B.S. Social media? Get serious! Understanding the functional building blocks of social media. Bus. Horiz. 2011, 54, 241–251. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mangold, W.G.; Faulds, D.J. Social media: The new hybrid element of the promotion mix. Bus. Horiz. 2009, 52, 357–365. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Rochet, J.C.; Tirole, J. Cooperation among competitors: Some economics of payment card associations. RAND J. Econ. 2002, 33, 549–570. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Tanriverdi, H.; Lee, C.H. Within-industry diversification and firm performance in the presence of network externalities: Evidence from the software industry. Acad. Manag. J. 2008, 51, 381–397. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cottrell, T.; Nault, B.R. Product variety and firm survival in the microcomputer software industry. Strat. Manag. J. 2004, 25, 1005–1025. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Venkatraman, N.; Lee, C.H. Preferential linkage and network evolution: A conceptual model and empirical test in the US video game sector. Acad. Manag. J. 2004, 47, 876–892. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Landsman, V.; Stremersch, S. Multihoming in two-sided markets: An empirical inquiry in the video game console industry. J. Market. 2011, 75, 39–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
© 2017 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Wan, X.; Cenamor, J.; Parker, G.; Van Alstyne, M. Unraveling Platform Strategies: A Review from an Organizational Ambidexterity Perspective. Sustainability 2017, 9, 734. https://doi.org/10.3390/su9050734
Wan X, Cenamor J, Parker G, Van Alstyne M. Unraveling Platform Strategies: A Review from an Organizational Ambidexterity Perspective. Sustainability. 2017; 9(5):734. https://doi.org/10.3390/su9050734
Chicago/Turabian StyleWan, Xing, Javier Cenamor, Geoffrey Parker, and Marshall Van Alstyne. 2017. "Unraveling Platform Strategies: A Review from an Organizational Ambidexterity Perspective" Sustainability 9, no. 5: 734. https://doi.org/10.3390/su9050734
APA StyleWan, X., Cenamor, J., Parker, G., & Van Alstyne, M. (2017). Unraveling Platform Strategies: A Review from an Organizational Ambidexterity Perspective. Sustainability, 9(5), 734. https://doi.org/10.3390/su9050734