Asymmetric Reimbursement and Contingent Fees in Environmental Conflicts: Observable vs. Unobservable Contracts
Abstract
:1. Introduction
1.1. Background Information
1.2. Related Literature
2. Results
2.1. Framework of Analysis
=1/2 for x1 + x2 = 0,
=p1b − x1.
=p2(1 + ab) − ab − x2.
2.2. The Unobservable-Contract Game
- (i)
- if 0 < a < [−(3 + 2w) + [(1 + 2w)2 + 16w)]1/2]/2,
- (a)
- The delegation contract is b* = 1/[(1 − a)(1 + 2wδ)],
- (b)
- Delegate 1 and player 2 expendx1* = wδ/[(1 − a)(1 + wδ)2(1 + 2wδ)] and x2* = w/[(1 − a)(1 + wδ)2(1 + 2wδ)].
- (c)
- The probability of winning for player 1 is p1* = wδ/(1 + wδ).
- (d)
- The expected payoff for delegate 1 isπ1* = (wv)2/[(1 − a)(1 + wδ)2(1 + 2wδ)].
- (e)
- The expected payoffs for players areG1* = 2(wδ)2/[(1 + wδ)(1 + 2wδ)] andG2* = [(1 + wδ)[1 − a + (2 − 3a)wδ] − w]/[(1 − a)(1 + wδ)2(1 + 2wδ)].
- (ii)
- if [−(3 + 2w) + [(1 + 2w)2 + 16w)]1/2]/2 ≤ a < 1,
- (a)
- The delegation contract is b* = 1/2,
- (b)
- Delegate 1 and player 2 expendx1* = (2 + a)w/[2(2 + a + w)2] and x2* = (2 + a)2w/[2(2 + a + w)2].
- (c)
- The probability of winning for player 1 is p1* = w/(2 + a + w).
- (d)
- The expected payoff for delegate 1 isπ1* = w2/[2(2 + a + w)2].
- (e)
- The expected payoffs for players areG1* = (1 + a)w/[2(2 + a + w)] andG2* = [8 + [12 − (2 + w)2]a + 2(1 − w)a2]/[2(2 + a + w)2].
2.3. The Observable-Contract Game
- (i)
- if a < [−(3 + w) + [(1 + w)(9 + w)]1/2]/2,
- (a)
- The delegation contract is b** = θ/(1 − aθ),
- (b)
- Delegate 1 and player 2 expendx1** = θ2w/[(1 − aθ)(1 + wθ)2] and x2** = θw/[(1 − aθ)(1 + wθ)2].
- (c)
- The probability of winning for player 1 is p1** = wθ/(1 + wθ).
- (d)
- The expected payoff for delegate 1 isπ1** = w2θ3/[(1 − aθ)(1 + wθ)2].
- (e)
- The expected payoffs for players areG1** = (1 − θ)wθ/[(1 − aθ)(1 + wθ)] andG2** = [1 − aθ(1 + wθ)2]/[(1 − aθ)(1 + wθ)2].
- (ii)
- if [−(3 + w) + [(1 + w)(9 + w)]1/2]/2 ≤ a < 1,
- (a)
- The delegation contract is b** = 1/2,
- (b)
- Delegate 1 and player 2 expendx1** = (2 + a)w/[2(2 + a + w)2] and x2** = (2 + a)2w/[2(2 + a + w)2].
- (c)
- The probability of winning for player 1 is p1** = w/(2 + a + w).
- (d)
- The expected payoff for delegate 1 isπ1** = w2/[2(2 + a + w)2].
- (e)
- The expected payoffs for players areG1** = (1 + a)w/[2(2 + a + w)] andG2** = [8 + [12 − (2 + w)2]a + 2(1 − w)a2]/[2(2 + a + w)2].
3. Discussion
4. Conclusions
Author Contributions
Funding
Data Availability Statement
Acknowledgments
Conflicts of Interest
1 | In the United States, only the remuneration paid by the citizens to the attorney is subject to asymmetric reimbursement, excluding office costs such as postage and fact-finding costs of various documents. Ref. [1] describes it as follows. “Reimbursement could include repaying the cost for discovery, investigation, court costs, and support staffs, but generally is only awarded for attorney’s fees”. |
2 | This paper is narrowly focused on a specific application of contract theory, environmental contests, instead of being broader in nature by creating a unified theory of contracts. |
3 | There are various reasons why plaintiffs hire lawyers under contingent fee [9,13,14,15,16]. In most civil cases, defendants are corporations, such as insurance companies, while plaintiffs are individuals. Accordingly, plaintiffs with less litigation experience have a greater incentive to prevent moral hazard of their attorneys than defendants and are more prone to be confronted with liquidity constraints than defendants. This is also why it is relatively easy for the plaintiffs to bring into line the contingent fee formula at an assured percentage of the compensation for damage, unlike the defendants [14]. On the other hand, it is common for the defendants to have in-house legal resources to invest in civil disputes, unlike the plaintiffs. |
4 | In the United States, the maximum feasible percentage the client can give the attorney is often dictated by legal restrictions on the contingent fee (which prohibit fees exceeding 50 percent). |
5 | As [4] mentioned, player 2 has more information about the case than player 1. Thus, Ref. [4] assumes that w is less than 1. This study assumes that the asymmetry of information is resolved by player 1 hiring delegate 1. Accordingly, this study considers w as player 2’s degree of fault. Thus, w can be greater than 1. |
6 | See [8] for a detailed description of how the delegation contests can be solved with unobservable contracts. |
7 | The second-order condition is satisfied with ∂2G2/∂x22 = (∂2p2/∂x22) (1 + ab) < 0. |
8 | Note that x1 + x2 = bw(ab + 1)[1 + (a + 1)b]/[1 + (a + w)2b]. Further, ∂(x1 + x2)/∂b = [1 + 2a(a + 1)(a + w)2b3 + (2a3 + 4(w + 1)a2 + (2w2 + 2w + 3)a + w2)b2 + 2(2a + 1)b]w/[1 + (a + w)2b]2 > 0 for 0 < θ < 1/(2 + a), which implies that the total efforts are increasing in b. Considering ∂(x1 + x2)/∂b and b* > b** for 0 < θ < 1/(2 + a), this study obtains that if for 0 < θ < 1/(2 + a), then x1* + x2* > x1** + x2**. |
9 | Furthermore, the equilibrium contingent fees in the two games increase in a, which makes the equilibrium total effort levels increase: ∂b*/∂a > 0, ∂b**/∂a > 0, ∂(x1* + x2*)/∂a > 0, and ∂(x1** + x2**)/∂a > 0 for 0 < θ < 1/(2 + a). This study uses Maple, a computer program, for comparative static analysis. |
References
- Baik, K.H.; Shogren, J.F. Environmental Conflicts with Reimbursement of Citizen Suits. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 1994, 27, 1–20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Park, S.-H.; Shogren, J.F. Public-Private Environmental Conflicts. In Risk and Uncertainty in Environmental and Natural Resource Economics; Wessler, J., Weikard, H.-P., Weaver, R.D., Eds.; Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, UK, 2004; pp. 161–192. [Google Scholar]
- Cherry, T.L.; Cotton, S.J. Environmental Conflicts with Reimbursement: Experimental Evidence. Econ. Bull. 2012, 32, 3224–3232. [Google Scholar]
- Chassé, R.M. Strategic Behavior in Environmental Contests with Asymmetric Ability and Reimbursement. Int. Rev. Law Econ. 2019, 58, 115–126. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Park, S.-H.; Settle, C. Internalizing Environmental Damages and Endogenous Reimbursement in Environmental Conflicts: A Game-theoretic Analysis. Int. Rev. Econ. 2022, 69, 547–569. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Park, S.-H. Asymmetric Reimbursement System in an Environmental Conflict. Appl. Econ. Lett. 2010, 17, 1197–1199. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Lim, B.L.; Shogren, J.F. Unilateral Delegation and Reimbursement System in an Environmental Conflict. Appl. Econ. Lett. 2004, 11, 489–493. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Baik, K.H.; Kim, I.-G. Contingent Fees versus Legal Expense Insurance. Int. Rev. Law Econ. 2007, 27, 351–361. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Park, S.-H.; Lee, S. Legal Contests with Unilateral Delegation. Asian J. Law Econ. 2020, 11, 20190031. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Baumann, F.; Friehe, T. Contingent Fees Meet the British Rule: An Exploratory Study. Public Choice 2012, 150, 499–510. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Baumann, F.; Friehe, T. A Note on the Timing of Investments in Litigation Contests. Eur. J. Law Econ. 2013, 35, 313–326. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Park, S.-H. Contingent Fees and Endogenous Timing in Litigation Contests. Eur. J. Law Econ. 2022, 54, 453–473. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Miller, G.P. Some Agency Problems in Settlement. J. Leg. Stud. 1987, 16, 189–215. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dana, J.D.; Spier, E.K. Expertise and Contingent Fees: The Role of Asymmetric Information in Attorney Compensation. J. Law Econ. Organ. 1993, 9, 349–367. [Google Scholar]
- Bebchuck, L.A.; Guzman, A.T. How Would You Like to Pay for That? The Strategic Effects of Fee Arrangement on Settlement Terms. Harv. Negot. Law Rev. 1996, 1, 53–63. [Google Scholar]
- Liston-Heyes, C. Setting the Stakes in Environmental Contests. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 2001, 41, 1–12. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Matros, A.; Armanios, D. Tullock’s contest with reimbursements. Public Choice 2009, 141, 49–63. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Carbonara, E.; Parisi, F.; von Wangenheim, G. Rent-Seeking and Litigation: The Hidden Virtues of Limited Fee Shifting. Rev. Law Econ. 2015, 11, 113–148. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Katz, M. Game-Playing Agents: Unobservable Contracts as Precommitments. Rand J. Econ. 1991, 22, 307–328. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Koçkesn, L.; Ok, E. Strategic Delegation by Unobservable Incentive Contracts. Rev. Econ. Stud. 2004, 71, 397–424. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Ursprung, H.W. Public Goods, Rent Dissipation, and Candidate Competition. Econ. Politics 1990, 2, 115–132. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Nitzan, S. Collective Rent Dissipation. Econ. J. 1991, 101, 1522–1534. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hurley, T.M. Rent Dissipation and Efficiency in a Contest with Asymmetric Valuations. Public Choice 1998, 94, 289–298. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dickson, A.; MacKenzie, I.A.; Sekeris, P.G. Rent Dissipation in Simple Tullock Contests. Games 2022, 13, 83. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Li, G.; Guan, X.; Mukhopadhyay, S.K. The impact of decision timing on the suppliers’ interactions: Simultaneous moves versus sequential moves. J. Oper. Res. Soc. 2016, 67, 248–258. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bag, P.K.; Roy, S. On Sequential and Simultaneous Contributions Under Incomplete Information. Int. J. Game Theory 2011, 40, 119–145. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Varian, H. Sequential Contributions to Public Goods. J. Public Econ. 1994, 53, 165–186. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gachter, S.; Nosenzo, D.; Renner, E.; Sefton, M. Sequential versus Simultaneous Contributions to Public Goods: Experimental Evidence. J. Public Econ. 2010, 94, 515–522. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Amir, R.; Chalioti, E.; Halmenschlager, R. University-Firm Competition in Basic Research: Simultaneous versus Sequential Moves. J. Public Econ. Theory 2021, 23, 1199–1219. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kubler, D.; Muller, W. Simultaneous and Sequential Price Competition in Heterogenous Duopoly Markets. Int. J. Ind. Organ. 2002, 20, 1437–1460. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Kovenock, D.; Morath, F.; Münster, J. Information Sharing in Contests. J. Econ. Manag. Strategy 2015, 24, 570–596. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content. |
© 2023 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Park, S.-H.; Settle, C.E. Asymmetric Reimbursement and Contingent Fees in Environmental Conflicts: Observable vs. Unobservable Contracts. Games 2023, 14, 55. https://doi.org/10.3390/g14040055
Park S-H, Settle CE. Asymmetric Reimbursement and Contingent Fees in Environmental Conflicts: Observable vs. Unobservable Contracts. Games. 2023; 14(4):55. https://doi.org/10.3390/g14040055
Chicago/Turabian StylePark, Sung-Hoon, and Chad E. Settle. 2023. "Asymmetric Reimbursement and Contingent Fees in Environmental Conflicts: Observable vs. Unobservable Contracts" Games 14, no. 4: 55. https://doi.org/10.3390/g14040055
APA StylePark, S. -H., & Settle, C. E. (2023). Asymmetric Reimbursement and Contingent Fees in Environmental Conflicts: Observable vs. Unobservable Contracts. Games, 14(4), 55. https://doi.org/10.3390/g14040055