Duopoly and Endogenous Single Product Quality Strategies
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Literature Review
3. The Model
- I.
- In equilibrium, the market is fully served. That is, ṯ = a.
- II.
- In equilibrium, the consumer surplus of consumer a from the choice of pairs offered by firm 1 is positive. In particular, 8.
- Note 1
- Note 2
- Note 3
- The main result—part I
- Note 4
- i.
- Economically, firm 1 aims to distinguish itself from firm 2 by reducing its quality in order to relax competition.
- ii.
- The intuition for the latter equation is that to maximize profit per unit, the slope of the indifferent consumer (a) and the slope of the cost function () must be equal in an interior solution9.
Market Competition in Qualities and Prices
- The main result—part II
- i.
- When , then ; in other words, firm 2 will offer top of the line quality10.
- ii.
- When , then firm 2 will offer , where .
- Note 5
4. A Numerical Example
5. Conclusions
Funding
Institutional Review Board Statement
Informed Consent Statement
Data Availability Statement
Acknowledgments
Conflicts of Interest
Appendix A
An Explanation for Example 1
1 | In the monopoly case, we will use the results of Mussa and Rosen (1978) [3] in order to compare them to our results, under the duopolistic case. |
2 | Assumption 1 states that net income is non-negative for all the consumers, since for the case where , there is no consumer t who would choose the pair for every . Therefore, implies that . |
3 | The intuition is that the marginal utility of consumer a, who can buy , cannot be less than the corresponding slope of cost function—. Similarly, the marginal utility of consumer b who buys cannot be below the corresponding slope of the cost function— |
4 | Assumptions 4 and 5 indicate that there will be an intersection of production costs. Intuitively speaking, this intersection leads to a set of qualities where each firm maintains a superior technology over the other. Otherwise, there will be no equilibrium with more than one active firm. |
5 | If , the consumer surplus of b and all other potential consumers of this quality price pair will be negative, which means that none of the consumers will choose this pair. |
6 | By contrast, if we have two quality price pairs and , where and , none of the consumers will choose the pair . |
7 | This includes the possibility of not buying at all. |
8 | This result is contrasts with an equilibrium with a monopoly, in which . The intuition is that in the duopoly case, it is not beneficial for firm 1 to increase its price until due to the “burden” of competition because of the existence of firm 2. See also in the following Example 1. |
9 | This equation also holds in the case of a monopoly when the market is fully served. |
10 | See also Example 1. |
11 | This result contrasts with the monopoly case, where the profit per unit increases with the quality index. |
12 | See also Shaked and Sutton (1982) [4], who assumed that there were no production costs, and accordingly had . |
13 | The rationale why the value of the quality offered by firm 1 is 1.12 is proven in the last subsection of Appendix A. Note that in this example, there are numerical rounding offs. |
14 | See also work by Shitovitz et al. (1989) [24], who derived similar results in the case of a monopoly with a finite number of consumers. |
References
- Scheibehenne, B.; Greifeneder, R.; Todd, P.M. Can there ever be too many options? A meta-analytic review of choice overload. J. Consum. Res. 2010, 37, 409–425. [Google Scholar]
- Shah, A.M.; Wolford, G. Buying behavior as a function of parametric variation of number of choices. Psychol.-Sci.-Camb. 2007, 18, 369. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Mussa, M.; Rosen, S. Monopoly and Product Quality. J. Econ. Theory 1978, 18, 301–317. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Shaked, A.; Sutton, J. Relaxing Price Competition through Product Differentiation. Rev. Econ. Stud. 1982, 49, 3–13. [Google Scholar]
- Shaked, A.; Sutton, J. Natural Oligopolies. Econometrica 1983, 51, 1469–1483. [Google Scholar]
- Fasolo, B.; Carmeci, F.A.; Misuraca, R. The effect of choice complexity on perception of time spent choosing: When choice takes longer but feels shorter. Psychol. Mark. 2009, 26, 213–228. [Google Scholar]
- Timmermans, D. The impact of task complexity on information use in multi-attribute decision making. J. Behav. Decis. 1993, 6, 95–111. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Anderson, C. The Long Tail: Why the Future of Business Is Selling Less of More; Hachette: Edinburgh, UK, 2006. [Google Scholar]
- Gabszewicz, J.J.; Shaked, A.; Sutton, J.; Thisse, J.F. Segmenting the Market: The Monopolist’s Optimal Product Mix. J. Econ. Theory 1986, 39, 273–289. [Google Scholar]
- Noh, Y.H.; Moschini, G. Vertical product differentiation, entry-deterrence strategies, and entry qualities. Rev. Ind. Organ. 2006, 29, 227–252. [Google Scholar]
- Altan, B. Dynamic Durable Goods Monopoly and Market Power. Games 2020, 11, 22. [Google Scholar]
- Motta, M. Endogenous quality choice: Price vs. quantity competition. J. Ind. Econ. 1993, 41, 113–131. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cremer, H.; Thisse, J.F. Commodity taxation in a differentiated oligopoly. Int. Econ. Rev. 1994, 35, 613–633. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Bos, I.; Marini, M.A. Cartel stability under quality differentiation. Econ. Lett. 2019, 174, 70–73. [Google Scholar]
- Bos, I.; Marini, M.A.; Saulle, R.D. Cartel formation with quality differentiation. Math. Soc. Sci. 2020, 106, 36–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Bos, I.; Marini, M.A. Collusion in quality-segmented markets. J. Public Econ. Theory 2022, 24, 293–323. [Google Scholar]
- Morita, H.; Nguyen, X. FDI and quality-enhancing technology spillovers. Int. J. Ind. Organ. 2021, 79, 102787. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Economides, N.S. A Note on Equilibrium in Price-Quality Competition. Greek Econ. Rev. 1985, 7, 179–186. [Google Scholar]
- Champsaur, P.; Rochet, J.C. Multiproduct Duopolists. Econometrica 1989, 57, 533–557. [Google Scholar]
- Cheng, Y.L.; Peng, S.K.; Tabuchi, T. Multiproduct duopoly with vertical differentiation. BE J. Theor. Econ. 2011, 11. [Google Scholar]
- Gayer, A. Endogenous Duopolies. Econ. Lett. 2017, 159, 1–3. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Spence, M. Multi-Product Quantity-Dependent Prices and Profitability Constraints. Rev. Econ. 1980, 47, 821–841. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Phlips, L. The Economics of Price Discrimination; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 1983. [Google Scholar]
- Shitovitz, B.; Spiegel, M.; Weber, S. ‘Top of the Line’ Quality as an Optimal Solution for a Multi-Quality Monopolist. Eur. Econ. Rev. 1989, 33, 1641–1652. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gayer, A. Oligopoly, endogenous monopolist and product quality. BE J. Theor. Econ. 2007, 7. [Google Scholar]
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content. |
© 2023 by the author. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Gayer, A. Duopoly and Endogenous Single Product Quality Strategies. Games 2023, 14, 56. https://doi.org/10.3390/g14040056
Gayer A. Duopoly and Endogenous Single Product Quality Strategies. Games. 2023; 14(4):56. https://doi.org/10.3390/g14040056
Chicago/Turabian StyleGayer, Amit. 2023. "Duopoly and Endogenous Single Product Quality Strategies" Games 14, no. 4: 56. https://doi.org/10.3390/g14040056
APA StyleGayer, A. (2023). Duopoly and Endogenous Single Product Quality Strategies. Games, 14(4), 56. https://doi.org/10.3390/g14040056