Next Article in Journal
Quality and Influences of Natural and Anthropogenic Factors on Drinking Water in Rural Areas of Southern Chile
Previous Article in Journal
How Top-Down Water Regulation Affects the Financial Performance of Enterprises: The River Chief System in China as an Example
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Transboundary Water Allocation under Water Scarcity Based on an Asymmetric Power Index Approach with Bankruptcy Theory

by
Jianan Qin
1,2,3,*,
Xiang Fu
3,*,
Xia Wu
1,2,
Jing Wang
1,2,
Jie Huang
1,2,
Xuxun Chen
1,2,
Junwu Liu
1,2 and
Jiantao Zhang
1,2
1
Hubei Water Resources Research Institute, Wuhan 430070, China
2
Hubei Provincial Water Saving Research Center, Wuhan 430070, China
3
State Key Laboratory of Water Resources Engineering and Management, Wuhan University, Wuhan 430072, China
*
Authors to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Water 2024, 16(19), 2828; https://doi.org/10.3390/w16192828
Submission received: 2 September 2024 / Revised: 25 September 2024 / Accepted: 2 October 2024 / Published: 6 October 2024
(This article belongs to the Section Water Resources Management, Policy and Governance)

Abstract

:
Cooperative and self-enforceable water allocation is a key instrument to manage geopolitical conflict induced by water scarcity, which necessitates the cooperative willingness of the agents and considers their heterogeneity in geography, climate, hydrology, environment and social economy. Based on a multi-indicator system that contains asymmetric information on water volume contribution, current water consumption, water economic efficiency and efforts for eco-environmental protection, this study proposed a water allocation framework by combining the asymmetric power index approach with bankruptcy theory for solving the transboundary water allocation problem under scarcity. The proposed method was applied to the Yellow River Basin in northern China, which is mainly shared by nine provincial districts and frequently suffers from severe water shortages, and its results were compared with six alternative methods. The results highlight the necessity of quantifying agents’ willingness to cooperate under the condition of asymmetric negotiation power when making decisions on transboundary water allocations. The proposed method allows for transboundary water allocations through simultaneous consideration of the agent’s willingness to cooperate and asymmetric negotiation power, as well as disagreement allocation points, which ensure the stability, fairness and self-enforceability of allocation results. Therefore, it can offer practical and valuable decision-making insights for transboundary water management under water scarcity.

1. Introduction

Water resources are fundamental and strategic natural resources that support high-quality socio-economic development and maintain eco-environmental health [1,2]. Nowadays, intense anthropocentric activities and climatic changes have collectively exerted heavy pressure on the freshwater resources system, inducing serious water deficits and deteriorated aquatic ecosystems in the world. According to the United Nations, by 2025, around 1.80 billion people will face severe water scarcity [3] and two-thirds of the global population will live without sufficient clean water [4]. Therefore, it is desired to propose effective tools for dealing with water scarcity to achieve the global water security agenda (SDG 6) [5].
Freshwater resources, especially in transboundary river systems, usually have the attributes of quasi-public goods, that is, non-excludability and competitiveness. It not only emphasizes that the involved agents enjoy equal rights to extract and use this public resource but also means that any of their unilateral actions may pose negative externalities on others and/or the whole system [6]. In the absence of a prudent co-management regime, water allocation conflict seems inevitable, especially when the transboundary river system encounters severe drought. The situation presumably further worsens as the number of stakeholders with competitive or even conflicting water use objectives increases. Water right allocation is commonly recognized as the main instrument to deal with a water shortage and its associated conflicts [7] in the transboundary river context. Nevertheless, it is complicated and intractable to accomplish this task successfully since it often involves multiple institutionally independent decision-making agents [8] with disparate social, economic and political statuses and needs [9].
Nowadays, numerous conflict resolution methods derived from various interdisciplinary theories and technologies have been used to facilitate water allocation under water scarcity. Mathematical programming-based methods, such as linear programming [10], non-linear programming [11], dynamic programming [12], quadratic programming [8], multi-objective programming [13], etc., focus on finding the Pareto-optimal solution by maximizing or minimizing the pre-specified primary objective. Nevertheless, it is usually difficult to describe the complex water resources system with objective functions; meanwhile, “the curse of dimensionality” actually may result in a system without an optimal solution [14]. In addition, achieving Pareto-optimal solutions may not be feasible in a real transboundary water management setting as it allocates water resources only from the social planner’s view without considering the individual rationality [6], strategic interactions [15] and asymmetric external power [9] of local decision-makers.
Game theory-based methods, including non-cooperative game and cooperative game, can provide appropriate frameworks for analyzing water allocation conflicts by capturing the interactions between agents and reproducing the allocation scenarios under different strategies. The non-cooperative game-based methods, such as the graph theory model, Rubinstein bargaining model, fallback bargaining model, Stackelberg leader–follower game model, etc., generally focus on investigating the strategic behaviors among agents and evaluating the feasibility of discrete solutions with qualitative information [16], as well as allowing valuable strategic insights for conflict resolution in transboundary water allocation [17,18,19,20,21,22]. Nevertheless, the widespread application of these methods is limited by their qualitative discrete results [16] and high dependence on agents’ risk preference and foresight levels [1,6] as well as available information quality [21]. The cooperative game-based methods, such as the Shapely Value, Nash–Harsanyi solution, Nucleolus, etc., resolve water conflicts and ensure efficient water utilization by establishing benefit compensations between agents through simultaneous consideration of individual rationality, group rationality and Pareto efficiency [1,6,15,23,24,25,26]. However, conceptualizing the transboundary water allocation problem as a cooperative, transferable utility game usually is complicated and challenging due to it highly depending on transparent and reliable utility information from all agents [16]. In addition, when the transboundary rivers encounter water shortages, the zero-sum game mentality may drive agents to compete for limited water resources instead of computing coalition gains and pursuing some kind of benefit compensation.
In recent years, the bankruptcy theory-based methods, such as Proportional, Constrained Equal Awards, Constrained Equal Losses, Adjusted Proportional, Talmud, Piniles, etc., have been applied to resolve water allocation conflicts [7,14,16,27,28,29]. Based on common sense [8,29], these methods ration the water resources among the agents directly with respect to their water claims, irrespective of their utility information functions and incremental benefits of cooperation [16], and thus they are relatively simple and can be easily used by agents and policy makers to address water sharing problems [14]. As described earlier, however, sharing transboundary water resources under scarcity often involves synthesizing far more influencing factors than general enterprise bankruptcy problems. These methods are not sufficient to address this problem as they assume that all agents have homogeneous water contribution, current water consumption, water economic efficiency and efforts for eco-environmental protection.
Equity normally is recognized as the cardinal principle for water resources planning and management, and related research is gradually emerging [30,31,32,33]. At present, no agreement regarding the general definition of this criterion has been reached yet in the field of public resource management. In economics, equity often coincides with the concept of distributive justice [34], emphasizing the implementation of egalitarian distribution to ensure all the participants’ expectations are satisfied [35]. Apparently, it is unscientific and irrational to allocate public resources based on egalitarianism [36]. On one hand, it is quite possible that resource shares allocated to some agents by this method exceed their claims, which violates the claim-boundedness principle [6]. On the other hand, agents in the transboundary resources system often present significant differences in terms of geography, socio-economy and environment, which indicates that the assumed symmetry between them seems unrealistic in water allocation problems [7].
The decision outcome of the “prisoner’s dilemma game” proves that, in the absence of effective agreements, rational decision-makers often tend to choose stable solutions rather than the most efficient solution at the system level [9]. Consequently, the cooperative willingness of the agents and capturing their strategic interactions are the key instruments to settle water geopolitical conflict. The Shapley–Shubik power index method [37] can quantitatively simulate agents’ willingness to cooperate, providing a good mathematical framework for identifying stable solutions for the allocation of shared resources. Since Loehman et al. [38] used this index method to select stable solutions for wastewater treatment cost allocation, it has been widely applied and gained a good reputation in water resources management [1,16,24,39,40,41]. However, this method still has the following limitations for successful transboundary water management. For one thing, it is mainly applied in the cooperative game theory literature to identify the most stable solutions from the discrete domain [9], while only a few researchers [9,40,41] employ it to develop continuous solutions for water allocations. For another, agents’ power asymmetries [42,43] (also referred to as external power [6,9] and bargaining power [1,14]) and their disagreement utility points, which ensure fairness and self-enforceability [6,15], respectively, are not simultaneously considered and included when using this index method to seek continuous water allocation solutions.
To this end, based on a multi-indicator system that contains asymmetric information on water volume contribution, current water consumption, water economic efficiency and efforts for eco-environmental protection, this study proposes a water allocation framework by combining the asymmetric power index approach with bankruptcy theory for resolving the transboundary water allocation problem under water scarcity. Subsequently, it is applied to the Yellow River Basin, which is mainly shared by nine provincial districts and frequently faces water shortages, to demonstrate the effectiveness of the framework by comparing it with six alternative methods.

2. Methods

In this study, a hybrid water allocation framework is proposed by combining the asymmetric power index approach with bankruptcy theory to tackle the transboundary water allocation problem under scarcity. Figure 1 briefly presents the methodological flowchart of the proposed water allocation framework. It includes the following detailed steps:

2.1. Step 1: Collect Basic Data and Information on Transboundary Water Allocation System

Basic data and information on transboundary water allocation include the decision-making agents involved and their climatic, geographical, hydrological, ecological, socio-economical and water consumption data and analyzing the mismatch of water availability and claim based on the available water quantity and water demand.

2.2. Step 2: Aggregate Multiple Characteristic Factors That Affect the Decision-Making Agent’s External Power into Their Negotiation Weight Coefficients

Firstly, a multiple-indicator system that is used to describe the external negotiation power of decision-making agents, from the criteria such as water contribution, respecting the current situation, economic efficiency and eco-environmental sustainability, is constructed. The proportion of annual average runoff to the total runoff of the entire watershed is used to quantify the water volume contributions to the entire system, and the agents who contribute more should bear a smaller water deficit [29]. The current water consumption cannot only reflect the existing ability of decision-making agents to develop and utilize freshwater resources [7] but also can express the respect for the status quo principle in the water allocation process. The economic output per cubic meter of water consumption is used to describe the water economic benefits for the agent, and obviously agents with a larger marginal benefit of water usage deserve higher water allocations [14] from the reasonable perspective. Reserved water for inner-river eco-environment and sewage discharged are used as the representative indicators to quantify the efforts made by the agent towards the entire aquatic ecological environment. Over-exploitation of water resources for socio-economic development may squeeze the inner-river eco-environment water requirements. Eventually, agents who reserve more water for the river course should be given more water. Too much sewage discharged into the river course can result in the deterioration of water quality and aquatic ecosystems, and consequently it should be regarded as a negative indicator when allocating transboundary water resources with the aim of punishing the agents who cause great damage to water quality. The representative indicators that are used to quantify four criteria are shown in Table 1.
Secondly, it formulates the quantification problem of agents’ external negotiation power in a transboundary water allocation system as a multi-criteria decision-making problem, where agents are regarded as the evaluated solutions, and thus an initial indicator matrix for calculating their negotiation weight coefficients can be constructed as follows:
C = c i j n × m = c 11 c 12 c 1 m c 21 c 22 c 2 m c n 1 c n 2 c n m i N , j M
where c i j is the performance value of the alternative i with respect to the indicator j ; N = 1 , 2 , , n is the alternative set, referring to the agents involved in a transboundary water allocation system; M = 1 , 2 , , m is the evaluation indicator set; n is the number of alternatives (herein, agents); and m is the number of indicators.
Thirdly, the efficiency coefficient method is employed to standardize the initial indicator data to achieve their unified dimension and attribute:
r i j = r i j b = ε + c i j b c min j b c max j b c min j b × ε , j b I B r i j c = ε + c max j c c i j c c max j c c min j c × ε , j c I C
c max j b = max i N c i j b , j b I B c min j b = min i N c i j b , j b I B
c max j c = max i N c i j c , j c I C c min j c = min i N c i j c , j c I C
where r i j is the standardized value of indicator j under alternative i ; r i j b and r i j c , respectively, are the standardized values of the benefit indicator j b (present positive effects on indicator weights) and the cost indicator j c (present negative effects on indicator weights) under the alternative i ; I B and I C are the benefit and cost indicator sets, respectively, and I B I C = M ; c max j b ( c max j c ) and c min j b ( c min j c ), respectively, are the satisfactory value and impermissible value of the indicator j b ( j c ); ε and ε are the translation parameter and zoom parameter, respectively, herein ε = 10 5 ; and ε = 1 ε . In this way, the attributes of the original indicator will be unified, and their values will be mapped within the range of 0–1.
Fourthly, the CRITIC method [44] is used to produce indicator weights by simultaneously considering the contrast intensity of each indicator and conflict between them [45]:
w j = I A j j = 1 m I A j
I A j = S D j × j = 1 m 1 C C j j
C C j j = i = 1 n r i j r j ¯ × r i j r j ¯ i = 1 n r i j r j ¯ 2 × i = 1 n r i j r j ¯ 2
S D j = 1 n i = 1 n r i j r j ¯ 2
r j ¯ = 1 n i = 1 n r i j
where w j is the indicator weight of the indicator j produced by the CRITIC method; I A j is the information amount contained by the indicator j ; C C j j is the correlation coefficient between the indicator j and the indicator j , which is used to measure the conflict between two indicators [44]; S D j is the standard deviation of the indicator j across all the alternatives, which is applied to quantify the contrast intensity of the indicator [45]; and r j ¯ is the average value of the indicator j across all the alternatives.
Finally, the negotiation weight coefficients of decision-making agents can be calculated as:
ω i = w j × r i j j = 1 m w j × r i j
where ω i is the negotiation weight coefficient of the agent i representing its asymmetric external power [9] or bargaining power [1], and the larger the weight coefficient, the higher power and capability of an agent to affect the final negotiation outcomes [6].

2.3. Step 3: Calculate the Disagreement Utility Value of the Decision-Making Agents

First, the bankruptcy game core [46] is used to determine the minimum water allocations for decision-making agents in the transboundary river system:
x i min = max 0 , A W i N i w c i
Given that:
i = 1 n x i min A W
where x i min is the minimum water allocation of the agent i produced by the bankruptcy game core; A W is the available water quantity of the transboundary water allocation system; and w c i is the water claim of the agent i , herein, i N i .
Afterwards, the linear interval function [47] is employed to describe the utility function value of the agents [15]:
u i x i = x i x i min w c i x i min
where u i x i is the utility function value of the agent i ; x i is the water allocation of the agent i (decision variable); and w c i is the water claim of the agent i . The disagreement utility point of the agent i ( u i 0 x i min ) can be obtained when x i equals x i min .

2.4. Step 4: Propose the Water Allocation Framework Using the Asymmetric Power Index Approach

The Shapley–Shubik power index [37], defined as the ratio of an agent’s loss due to its departure from the grand coalition to the sum of all other agents’ losses after they leave the coalition [38], proved to be an appropriate method for simulating agents’ willingness to cooperate and identifying the most stable solution in the cooperative game-based water management literature [1,24,39,40,41]. However, this method still fails to find fair and self-enforceable continuous solutions for transboundary water allocation due to agents’ asymmetric negotiation power and their disagreement utility points not being simultaneously considered and included. Therefore, a hybrid water allocation framework is proposed using the asymmetric power index approach based on the quantitative results of agent’s negotiation weight coefficient and their disagreement utility points:
Ω = min ϕ A P I
ϕ A P I = σ A P I A P I ¯
A P I i = u i x i u i 0 x i min / ω i i = 1 n u i x i u i 0 x i min / ω i
subject to:
u i x i u i 0 x i min
x i x i min
x i w c i
i = 1 n x i = A W
i = 1 n A P I i = 1
i = 1 n ω i = 1
x i min , x i , w c i 0
u i 0 x i min , u i x i , ω i , A P I i 1
u i 0 x i min , u i x i , ω i , A P I i 0
where Ω is the objective function of the water allocation framework, which aims to evenly distribute the willingness of agents to cooperate on the basis of considering their asymmetric external negotiation power; ϕ A P I is the coefficient of variation of agent’s asymmetric power index (the smaller the value, the more stable the obtained solution, and vice versa [39]); σ A P I and A P I ¯ , respectively, are the standard deviation and average value of agent’s asymmetric power index; and A P I i is the asymmetric power index of the agent i (the larger the value, the stronger the willingness of the agent to cooperate [9]). The other abbreviations are mentioned above.
From the mathematical expression above, the following properties of the proposed water allocation framework can be summarized: The discrepancy in agent’s willingness to cooperate can be minimized using Equation (14), which can ensure the stability of water allocation solutions [9]. Agent’s willingness to cooperate is quantified in Equation (16) based on simultaneous consideration of agent’s asymmetric negotiation power and the distance between their utility values and disagreement utility points, which ensures fairness and self-enforceability in a bounded space [6,15]. Equations (17) and (18) give the individual rationality, which represents the minimum threshold value of the agent’s water allocation and must be reflected before the cooperation of the agents [48]. Equation (19) presents the claim boundedness, which helps prevent resource overuse that may cause the tragedy of the commons [6,48]. Equation (20) denotes the Pareto efficiency, which requires that the sum of available water resources must be precisely allocated between all the agents [48].

3. Study Area and Data

3.1. Study Area

The Yellow River, the chief river in North China and the fifth longest river in the world, originates from the Bayankala Mountain in Qinghai Province, flows through nine provinces (regions) of Qinghai, Sichuan, Gansu, Ningxia, Inner Mongolia, Shaanxi, Shanxi, Henan and Shandong, and finally merges into the Bohai Sea in Dongying City, Shandong Province (Figure 2). It has a total length of about 5464 km and drains an area of 795,000 km2 [49], accounting for approximately 8.3% of Mainland China’s total area [50]. The Yellow River Basin (YRB) is characterized by an arid and semi-arid continental monsoon climate with a mean annual precipitation of 495 mm and a general decreasing trend from the southeast to the northwest [51]. Although the basin only accounts for about 2% of China’s surface water resources, it feeds approximately 9% of the nation’s population, about 13% of its agricultural land and around 8% of its industrial land [49]. Even some areas outside the basin, such as Hebei Province and Tianjin city, also draw water from this river. Thus, it serves an irreplaceable role in the social and economic growth of Northern China, and its ecological conservation and high-quality development has been elevated to a great national strategy related to rejuvenating the country [52].
The YRB is mainly characterized by abundant sand, uneven spatial and temporal distribution of water resources, and a fragile ecological environment. The stream-flow was cut off at the lower reach of the river every year from 1972 to 1998 because of over-withdrawals, which resulted in serious socio-economic and environmental issues in the downstream areas [53]. During the recent decades, the contradiction between water supply and demand has been increasingly prominent, drought disasters have been frequent [54] and how to allocate the river’s limited water resources have been key issues of water management in the basin. The “Yellow River Water Supply Allocation Plan” (known as the “87” Water Allocation Plan) was promulgated and implemented by the State Council in 1987, which specified the water use permits for each province. The plan reserved 21 billion m3 of the average natural runoff of 58 billion m3 in the YRB from 1919 to 1975 for the inner-river eco-environment and assigned the remaining 37 billion m3 to nine riparian provinces and Hebei Province and Tianjin City outside the basin (Table 2). Based on the “87” Water Allocation Plan, the “Yellow River Basin Comprehensive Plan (2012–2030)” (referred to as the Yellow River Basin Plan) was approved by the State Council in 2013. The plan predicted an average natural runoff of 51.98 billion m3 in 2020 and adjusted the water use permit of the Hebei Province and Tianjin City to 0.628 billion m3 based on considering the effectiveness of the East and Middle Route of the South to North Water Diversion Project, and the reduced water use permits were divided between nine riparian provinces according to the proportion of the “87” Water Allocation Plan (Table 2). The two plans above provide a basis for water allocation in the YRB.
The Yellow River Water Resources Commission is a watershed management agency dispatched by the Ministry of Water Resources of the People’s Republic of China to exercise water administrative management responsibilities in the YRB. Ensuring the rational development and utilization of water resources in the basin is one of its key responsibilities, and it has currently proposed the “87” Water Allocation Plan and the Yellow River Basin Plan to respond to the contradiction between water supply and demand. Nevertheless, conflict over water resource exploitation in this basin remains prominent with the continuous development of the economic society and the increasing demand for eco-environment protection. The YRB passes through nine provinces with disparate geography, climate, hydrology, ecological environment, social economy and water needs, and consequently a completely administrative directive management approach that does not consider the heterogeneity of agents’ multidimensional characteristic factors and their willingness to cooperate may not be capable of managing the increasingly knotty water allocation conflicts in this basin. Therefore, it is necessary to investigate new theories and methods from the perspective of local decision-making agents to adapt to the constantly changing mismatch between water supply and demand. In summary, the water resource allocation features in the YRB perfectly correspond with the water allocation framework proposed in this study and can serve as a good case study to demonstrate its effectiveness. Conversely, the newly proposed allocation framework can offer decision-making insights for YRB water management under water scarcity.

3.2. Data Collection and Analysis

The raw data used in this study are extracted from the Yellow River Water Resources Bulletin, relevant provincial (city) statistical yearbooks, the “Yellow River Basin Comprehensive Plan (2012–2030)” and the China Urban Construction Statistical Yearbook. The water demand of each province in the YRB is defined by their average water consumption from 2013 to 2020 (Figure 3). The total available water quantity of the YRB is adopted from the “87” Water Allocation Plan and the Yellow River Basin Plan (Table 2). Other raw data of the representative indicators (Table 1) that are used to quantify the external negotiation power of nine agents in the YRB are extracted from the relevant provincial (city) statistical yearbooks and the China Urban Construction Statistical Yearbook (Table 3).
After deducting the inner-river eco-environment water demand and the water demand outside the basin (a small amount of water supply for Hebei Province and Tianjin city), the total available water quantity in the YRB under the “87” Water Allocation Plan and the Yellow River Basin Plan, respectively, is 35.00 billion m3 and 32.66 billion m3, while the total water demand is 41.91 billion m3 (generated by the annual average water consumption of the basin from 2013 to 2020). Overall, the water resources in the basin are mainly concentrated in the upstream provinces, while the provinces with higher water demand induced by intense social economic activities are located in the middle and lower reaches. Hence, the spatial distribution of water resources in the YRB does not match its social economic development pattern. Due to the transboundary, water resources have the attributes of quasi-public goods [6]; the mismatch between water availability and demand may cause water conflicts in the YRB. Therefore, finding an allocation mechanism to resolve water allocation conflicts is both a crucial and challenging issue faced by basin authorities.

4. Results and Discussion

Basic data and information on water allocation in the YRB were collected and reported in Section 3. Based on the data from Table 3, the CRITIC method [44] is used to produce indicator weights, and subsequently the negotiation weight coefficients of nine agents in the YRB representing their asymmetric external negotiation power can be calculated using Equation (8). Furthermore, equal weight, which recognizes the equal status of each agent in water use so that the negotiation weight coefficients of all agents are equal [1], is also considered as a comparison in this study. Figure 4 presents the negotiation weight coefficients of nine agents in the YRB determined by the CRITIC method and equal weight method.
Among nine provinces in the YRB, Ningxia is given the lowest weight coefficient of 0.068 due to having the worst performance in the three criteria of water contribution, water economic efficiency and eco-environmental sustainability. With its relatively higher current water consumption and water economic efficiency, Shandong obtains the largest negotiation weight coefficient of 0.150. The negotiation weight coefficients of other provinces are between those of the two provinces mentioned above. It should be emphasized that the negotiation weight coefficients of the provinces in the YRB are multi-factor aggregated values, which are jointly determined by multiple criteria such as water contribution, respecting the current situation, economic efficiency and eco-environmental sustainability.
Based on the available water quantity from the “87” Water Allocation Plan and the Yellow River Basin Plan (Table 2) and the water demand of nine agents in the YRB (Figure 3), the bankruptcy game core [46] is used to determine their minimum water allocations, and the results are presented in Table 4. Under the “87” Water Allocation Plan, Inner Mongolia and Shandong obtain the minimum initial water allocation of 1.149 billion m3 and 2.379 billion m3, respectively, which are defined on the basis of ensuring that other agents are fully satisfied and therefore can be considered as conceded to them by all the others [16]. The minimum initial water allocations to the other agents are zero because there is no surplus water for them after all the others have been fully compensated in terms of their claims [55]. Under the Yellow River Basin Plan, the minimum initial water amount allocated to Shandong by the bankruptcy game core is 0.038 billion m3, whereas the other agents do not receive an initial water allocation. The different results under the two available water quantity scenarios indicate that the bankruptcy game core is highly sensitive to the water shortage degree in the watershed when producing the minimum water allocations.
Based on the minimum water allocation results, the disagreement utility values of the agents are determined using Equation (11), which are the lower bound or starting points for their participation in bargaining [23], and, to some extent, determine the sustainability of the developed solutions or signed agreements [6]. Subsequently, the asymmetric power index approach considering the agents’ minimum water allocation (API-2) is used to perform water allocations in the YRB based on the negotiation weight coefficients of nine agents. Moreover, four alternative allocation approaches are considered: the proportional (PRO) rule, symmetric power index approach without considering the agent’s minimum water allocation (SPI-1), symmetric power index approach considering the agent’s minimum water allocation (SPI-2) and asymmetric power index approach without considering the agent’s negotiation weight coefficients (API-1). Table 5 reports the water allocation results of nine agents in the YRB under different allocation methods, and their water distribution satisfactions are presented in Figure 5.
The PRO rule distributes the water resources among the agents proportionally according to their claims [29], hence nine agents in the YRB obtain the same water allocation satisfaction of 83.52% and 77.93%, respectively, under the “87” Water Allocation Plan and the Yellow River Basin Plan. It is the best and most widely used bankruptcy rule [8,55] and usually suggested as the definition of fairness for conflicting claims [56]. Nevertheless, its “equity” and “rationality” in dealing with common pool resource management issues is questioned as it does not take into account multidimensional characteristic factors of decision-making agents other than their demands. For one thing, decision-making agents (provincial districts) who contribute more water volume to the entire system should be allocated more water [29]. For another, agents with a higher marginal benefit of water usage should obtain more water from the perspective of reasonable utilization [28]. In short, the based-claim PRO rule does not conform to the normative principle of “equitable and reasonable utilization” defined by the Convention on the Law of the Non-Navigational Uses of International Watercourses [57].
From Figure 5, the SPI-1 method generates the same water allocation results as the PRO rule when the minimum water allocations of the decision-making agents are not considered and equal weights are assigned to them. The main reason is that the SPI-1 method adopts the ratio of the allocated water amount of the decision-making agents to their water claims (demands) (i.e., water allocation satisfaction) as their utility functions, and the optimization objectives of these methods are to achieve equal utility distribution among the decision-making agents as much as possible without considering their minimum water allocations and asymmetric negotiation weight coefficients.
Figure 6 presents a comparison of results between symmetric (SP-1,2) methods and asymmetric (API-1,2) methods under the “87” Water Allocation Plan (a) and the Yellow River Basin Plan (b). It can be seen intuitively from Figure 6 that the water allocation satisfaction of Qinghai, Shaanxi, Henan and Shandong are raised under the asymmetric (API-1,2) methods compared to that under the symmetric (SPI-1,2) methods, whereas the water allocation satisfaction of the other agents decreases. It reveals how the negotiation weight coefficients of the agents modify the allocation solutions derived from the symmetric (SPI-1,2) methods. Alternatively, it can also explain how the external negotiation power of the agents affects the internal power distribution among them. Consequently, transboundary water allocation under scarcity is far more complicated than general enterprise bankruptcy problems, and it is not fair or reasonable to only consider the water claims of the agents when redistributing water without considering their other characteristic factors such as water contribution, current water consumption, water economic efficiency and efforts made for eco-environmental protection.
In brief, two main conclusions can be observed from Figure 6. One is that the water allocation results yielded by the API-2 method are highly sensitive to the variability of the negotiation weight coefficients of the decision-making agents. Another is that, in the API-2 method, water allocation satisfaction changes of the decision-making agents present as positively correlated with a change in their negotiation weight coefficients.
Table 6 reports the water allocation satisfaction changes of the agents under the solutions considering the agent’s minimum water allocation compared to those without considering the agent’s minimum water allocation. Compared to the SPI-1 solution, the water allocation satisfaction of Inner Mongolia and Shandong is increased in the SPI-2 solution under the “87” Water Allocation Plan, while that of the other agents is decreased. The reason is that only these two agents obtain a minimum water allocation under the “87” Water Allocation Plan (Table 4). Similarly, the SPI-2 solution gives more water to Shandong than the SPI-1 solution under the Yellow River Basin Plan as it is the only agent who receives the minimum water allocation. These results verify the impact of the agent’s minimum water allocation on the proposed method for finding continuous optimization solutions.
Inner Mongolia gains more water allocation in the API-2 solution than that in the API-1 solution and Qinghai and Shandong remain unchanged, while those of the other agents are reduced. Under the Yellow River Basin Plan, the API-2 and API-1 methods produce identical water allocation results. The explanation for the differentiated conclusions between symmetric (SPI-2~SPI-1) and asymmetric (API-2~API-1) cases is that not only the agent’s minimum water allocation but also their asymmetric negotiation weight coefficients are taken into account in the API-2 method. In addition, as the agent’s minimum water allocation is affected by the water scarcity in transboundary rivers, the API-2 method is sensitive to the water shortage degree when producing water allocation solutions.
Table 7 depicts the comparison results of water allocation satisfaction between the two plans (“87” Water Allocation Plan and Yellow River Basin Plan) customized for the division of the YRB and the API-2 solution. In the “87” Water Allocation Plan, Qinghai, Sichuan and Shanxi obtain water allocations that exceed their water claims, while Inner Mongolia receives the lowest water allocation satisfaction (72.75%). Based on the average water consumption from 2013 to 2020, this allocation solution obviously violates the claim-boundedness constraint [6,48], resulting in the unnecessary waste of limited water resources. Meanwhile, it is also economically inefficient as those who gain lower water allocation satisfaction (Shaanxi, Henan and Shandong) possess a higher marginal benefit of water usage. The analysis above, to some extent, explains why the “87” Water Allocation Plan is no longer applicable to the current and future development circumstances of the social economy and ecological environment in the YRB.
Compared to the “87” Water Allocation Plan, the water allocation satisfaction of Qinghai in the API-2 solution is reduced by 28.49%; however, its water claim is fully satisfied in this solution. Shaanxi, Henan and Shandong obtain higher water allocation satisfaction under the API-2 solution than that under the “87” Water Allocation Plan. Qinghai, located in the upper reaches of the YRB, contributes the most to water volume and has made the most efforts to protect the eco-environment; therefore, it ought to receive a higher water distribution satisfaction level. Shaanxi, Henan and Shandong, which are located in the middle and lower reaches, have relatively good socio-economic development and larger current water consumption, as well as higher economic benefits of water usage, hence it is reasonable for them to achieve a higher water distribution satisfaction level under the API-2 solution than that under the “87” Water Allocation Plan, which is more conducive to the efficient and intensive utilization of water resources in the YRB. Due to the fact that the Yellow River Basin Plan is formulated by reducing the “87” Water Allocation Plan according to a certain proportion, analogous conclusions can be drawn by comparing it with the API-2 solution.
Based on the minimum water allocation and disagreement utility point of the agents, the Shapley–Shubik power index approach is used to quantify agents’ willingness to cooperate and the stability of the various solutions, respectively, in equal and asymmetric negotiation cases, and the results are presented in Figure 7. From Figure 7a, the power index values of nine agents under the SPI-2 solution are exactly the same at 0.111 in an equal negotiation case, which indicates that the agents’ internal power is evenly distributed among them and is thus the highest stability achieved by the solution [9]. Conversely, the “87” Water Allocation Plan is identified as the most unstable solution in this case. Apparently, Qinghai and Sichuan enthusiastically embrace the “87” Water Allocation Plan, whereas Shandong, Inner Mongolia and Shaanxi are very likely to oppose it. Compared to the symmetric (SPI-1,2) solutions, the asymmetric (API-1,2) solutions are more unstable from the power index values of the nine agents. From Figure 7b, the “87” Water Allocation Plan is also considered as the most unstable solution in the asymmetric negotiation case as the agents’ internal power is extremely unevenly distributed among them. In this solution, Sichuan and Ningxia are most likely to remain in the negotiation and seek agreement rather than leave prematurely, whereas Shandong, Shaanxi and Inner Mongolia are reluctant to continue the negotiation and hope to seek other options. Compared to the symmetric (SPI-1,2) solutions, the asymmetric (API-1,2) solutions are more stable from the asymmetric power index values of the nine agents.
From the comparison between Figure 7a,b, the willingness of nine agents in the YRB to cooperate under the same solution and the stability of this solution differ significantly in equal and asymmetric negotiation cases. Although the “87” Water Allocation Plan is considered the most unstable option in both cases, the power index value of the agents and the stability index value of this solution both are significantly different. In the equal negotiation case, the SPI-2 solution is chosen as the most stable solution, while the API-2 solution is the most stable one in asymmetric negotiation case. These numerical results highlight the necessity of considering the negotiation power of the agents in the decision-making process of transboundary water allocations. It is important to emphasize that the same insights and conclusions can be obtained when using the above-mentioned methods to allocate the available water quantity in the Yellow River Basin Plan and, consequently, repeated analysis is not necessary to conduct.
Due to the agents’ willingness to cooperate, their minimum acceptable water allocations and asymmetric information on water volume contribution, current water consumption, water economic efficiency and efforts for eco-environmental protection are simultaneously quantified and taken into account and the proposed water allocation framework satisfies multidimensional desirable properties such as fairness, stability and self-enforceability. Meanwhile, all the methods used in the framework are relatively objective and easy to implement, which ensures its flexibility. Nevertheless, the following limitations deserve attention and should be further investigated. Firstly, as this study only considers two water allocation scenarios under the “87” Water Allocation Plan and the Yellow River Basin Plan in the YRB, and the water demands of nine agents were obtained from their historical water consumption data, the application effect of the proposed allocation framework in other allocation scenarios has not been fully explored. Secondly, the continuous variability in climate, hydrology and ecological environment in the YRB, as well as the constantly developing socio-economic processes of its nine provinces, will inevitably change the basic input data (including the annual average runoff, water availability, water consumption, water use economic benefits, ecological environment sustainability, etc.) for the proposed allocation framework. These uncertainties, however, have not been studied in detail as this study aims to propose a water allocation framework for transboundary water management under water scarcity. Finally, although this study takes into account the multidimensional characteristic factors of nine provinces in the YRB when performing water allocations, in essence, it only focuses on the consumptive demand of water resources without paying attention to other functional values of water resources including hydropower generation, navigation, fisheries, ecosystem service, etc.

5. Conclusions

Considering agents’ cooperative willingness and capturing their strategic interactions are the key instruments to settle water geopolitical conflicts. This study proposed a water allocation framework by combining an asymmetric power index approach with bankruptcy theory for solving the transboundary water allocation problem under scarcity. Subsequently, the allocation framework was applied to the YRB together with six alternative methods including the “87” Water Allocation Plan, Yellow River Basin Plan, PRO solution, SPI-1 solution, SPI-2 solution and API-1 solution to demonstrate its effectiveness. The major conclusions can be summarized as follows:
The SPI-1 method and the PRO rule yield the same water allocation results, and their practical feasibility is difficult to guarantee since they use some mathematical criteria to perform allocations only according to agents’ aspiration claims without considering other characteristic factors that affect their actions.
Compared to the “87” Water Allocation Plan and the Yellow River Basin Plan, the proposed method is relatively superior in terms of fairness and reasonableness, as it can ensure the water allocation satisfaction of those who contribute the most while improving that of those with higher water economic benefits.
The findings of this study could offer practical decision insights for YRB water management under water scarcity and underscore the critical necessity of considering agents’ willingness to cooperate and their asymmetric negotiation power, as well as disagreement allocation points, when performing transboundary water allocations.
Apart from the basic principles of Pareto efficiency, individual rationality and claim boundedness, the proposed water allocation framework satisfies multidimensional desirable properties such as fairness, stability and self-enforceability, which makes it more reasonable and realistic than other alternative methods. In addition, all the methods used are relatively objective and easy to implement. Consequently, the proposed water allocation framework can not only be applied to the YRB in a country with a unique political structure and decision-making process like China but also can be flexibly transplanted to other transboundary watersheds in China and other countries by replacing basic research materials and data.
Based on the findings of this study, future research should be conducted. For one thing, uncertainty in hydrological conditions, socio-economic development plans and water management policies should be given attention and further investigated in future research to strengthen the proposed method’s ability and adaptability. For another, the initial water allocations may not necessarily realize efficient and sustainable utilization of water resources in transboundary river systems, and consequently further research on water rights trading mechanisms, water quality risk control, ecological compensation systems, etc., is still urgently needed.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, J.Q. and X.F.; methodology, J.Q. and X.F.; data curation, J.H., J.W. and J.Z.; formal analysis, J.Q. and J.H.; investigation, J.Q. and J.Z.; writing-original draft, J.Q.; writing-review & editing, X.F., X.W. and J.L.; visualization, X.C.; project administration, J.W; supervision, X.F. and X.W. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This study was supported by the China Postdoctoral Science Foundation (No. 2023M731040) and National Natural Science Foundation of China (Nos. 12271061, U21A2002).

Data Availability Statement

Data are contained within the article.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflicts of interest.

References

  1. Tian, J.; Yu, Y.; Li, T.; Zhou, Y.; Li, J.; Wang, X.; Han, Y. A cooperative game model with bankruptcy theory for water allocation: A case study in China Tarim River Basin. Environ. Sci. Pollut. Res. 2022, 29, 2353–2364. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  2. Yang, L.; Pan, Z.; Li, H.; Wang, D.; Wang, J.; Wu, C.; Wu, X. Study on the Spatiotemporal Evolution and Driving Factors of Water Resource Carrying Capacity in Typical Arid Regions. Water 2024, 16, 2142. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Ssekyanzi, G.; Ahmad, M.J.; Choi, K.S. Sustainable Solutions for Mitigating Water Scarcity in Developing Countries: A Comprehensive Review of Innovative Rainwater Storage Systems. Water 2024, 16, 2394. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Eliasson, J. The rising pressure of global water shortages. Nature 2015, 517, 6. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. UN. The Sustainable Development Goals Report 2022; UN: New York, NY, USA, 2022. [Google Scholar]
  6. Qin, J.; Fu, X.; Peng, S.; Xu, Y.; Huang, J.; Huang, S. Asymmetric Bargaining Model for Water Resource Allocation over Transboundary Rivers. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2019, 16, 1733. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Zeng, Y.; Li, J.; Cai, Y.; Tan, Q. Equitable and reasonable freshwater allocation based on a multi-criteria decision making approach with hydrologically constrained bankruptcy rules. Ecol. Indic. 2017, 73, 203–213. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Giuliani, M.; Castelletti, A.; Amigoni, F.; Cai, X. Multiagent systems and distributed constraint reasoning for regulatory mechanism design in water management. J. Water Resour. Plan. Manag. 2015, 141, 04014068. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Read, L.; Madani, K.; Inanloo, B. Optimality versus stability in water resource allocation. J. Manag. Eng. 2014, 133, 343–354. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Housh, M. Optimizing bilinear multi-source water supply systems using mixed-integer linear programming approximations: An analysis of the Israeli seawater desalination array. Adv. Water Resour. 2023, 178, 104498. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Nematollahi, B.; Nikoo, M.R.; Gandomi, A.H.; Talebbeydokhti, N.; Rakhshandehroo, G.R. A Multi-criteria Decision-making Optimization Model for Flood Management in Reservoirs. Water Resour. Manag. 2022, 36, 4933–4949. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Ayele, W.T.; Tenagashaw, D.Y.; Belew, A.Z.; Andualem, T.G. Optimal Water Allocation Under Climate Change, Based on Stochastic Dynamic Programming Model Approach in Ribb Reservoir, Amhara, Ethiopia. Water Conserv. Sci. Eng. 2022, 7, 33–44. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Tabari, M.M.R.; Safari, R. Development of water re-allocation policy under uncertainty conditions in the inflow to reservoir and demands parameters: A case study of Karaj AmirKabir dam. Soft. Comput. 2023, 27, 6521–6547. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Li, S.; He, Y.; Chen, X.; Zheng, Y. The improved bankruptcy method and its application in regional water resource allocation. J. Hydro-Environ. Res. 2020, 28, 48–56. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Degefu, D.M.; He, W.; Yuan, L.; Zhao, J. Water Allocation in Transboundary River Basins under Water Scarcity: A Cooperative Bargaining Approach. Water Resour Manag. 2016, 30, 4451–4466. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Madani, K.; Zarezadeh, M.; Morid, S. A new framework for resolving conflicts over transboundary rivers using bankruptcy methods. Hydrol. Earth Syst. Sci. 2014, 18, 3055–3068. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Darvishi Boloorani, A.; Najafi Marghmaleki, S.; Soleimani, M.; Papi, R.; Kardan Moghaddam, H.; Samany, N.N. Development of a scenario-based approach using game theory for the restoration of Hawizeh Marsh and dust mitigation. Hydrol. Sci. J. 2022, 68, 131–147. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Eleftheriadou, E.; Mylopoulos, Y. Game Theoretical Approach to Conflict Resolution in Transboundary Water Resources Management. J. Water Resour. Plan. Manag. 2008, 134, 466–473. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Kucukmehmetoglu, M. An integrative case study approach between game theory and Pareto frontier concepts for the transboundary water resources allocations. J. Hydrol. 2012, 450–451, 308–319. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Mehrparvar, M.; Ahmadi, A.; Safavi, H.R. Resolving water allocation conflicts using WEAP simulation model and non-cooperative game theory. Simulation 2020, 96, 17–30. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Madani, K.; Hipel, K.W. Non-Cooperative Stability Definitions for Strategic Analysis of Generic Water Resources Conflicts. Water Resour. Manag. 2011, 25, 1949–1977. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Sedghamiz, A.; Nikoo, M.R.; Heidarpour, M.; Sadegh, M. Developing a non-cooperative optimization model for water and crop area allocation based on leader-follower game. J. Hydrol. 2018, 567, 51–59. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Houba, H.; Do, K.H.P.; Zhu, X. Saving a river: A joint management approach to the Mekong River Basin. Environ. Dev. Econ. 2012, 18, 93–109. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Madani, K.; Hooshyar, M. A game theory-reinforcement learning (GT-RL) method to develop optimal operation policies for multi-operator reservoir systems. J. Hydrol. 2014, 519, 732–742. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Noori, M.; Emadi, A.; Fazloula, R. An agent-based model for water allocation optimization and comparison with the game theory approach. Water Supply 2021, 21, 3584–3601. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Gómez, R.; Weikard, H.P. Cooperative water-sharing agreements between highlands and drylands: The Tambo-Santiago-Ica river basin in Peru. Int. J. Water Resour. Dev. 2023, 39, 796–818. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Far, S.M.; Ashofteh, P.S. Optimization Operation of Water Resources Using Game Theory and Marine Predator Algorithm. Water Resour. Manag. 2024, 38, 665–699. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Janjua, S.; Hassan, I. Use of bankruptcy methods for resolving interprovincial water conflicts over transboundary river: Case study of Indus River in Pakistan. River Res. Appl. 2020, 36, 1334–1344. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Mianabadi, H.; Mostert, E.; Zarghami, M.; van de Giesen, N. A new bankruptcy method for conflict resolution in water resources allocation. J. Manag. Eng. 2014, 144, 152–159. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Fletcher, S.; Hadjimichael, A.; Quinn, J.; Osman, K.; Giuliani, M.; Gold, D.; Figueroa, A.J.; Gordon, B. Equity in water resources planning: A path forward for decision support modelers. J. Water Resour. Plan. Manag. 2022, 148, 02522005. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Gullotta, A.; Campisano, A.; Creaco, E.; Modica, C. A Simplified Methodology for Optimal Location and Setting of Valves to Improve Equity in Intermittent Water Distribution Systems. Water Resour. Manag. 2021, 35, 4477–4494. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Nyahora, P.P.; Babel, M.S.; Ferras, D.; Emen, A. Multi-objective optimization for improving equity and reliability in intermittent water supply systems. Water Supply 2020, 20, 1592–1603. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Yang, G.; Giuliani, M.; Castelletti, A. Operationalizing equity in multipurpose water systems. Hydrol. Earth Syst. Sci. 2023, 27, 69–81. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Koh, H. Why do nations obey International Law? Yale Law J. 1997, 106, 2599–2659. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Konow, J. Which is the fairest one of all? A positive analysis of justice theories. J. Econ. Lit. 2003, 41, 1188–1239. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Rahaman, M.M. Principles of transboundary water resources management and water-related agreements in Central Asia: An analysis. Int. J. Water Resour. Dev. 2012, 28, 475–491. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Shapley, L.S.; Shubik, S.M. A method for evaluating the distribution of power in a committee. Am. Polit. Sci. Rev. 1954, 48, 787–792. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Loehman, E.; Orlando, J.; Tschirhart, J.; Whinston, A. Cost allocation for a regional wastewater treatment system. Water Resour. Res. 1979, 15, 193–202. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Dinar, A.; Howitt, R.E. Mechanisms for Allocation of Environmental Control Cost: Empirical Tests of Acceptability and Stability. J. Manag. Eng. 1997, 49, 183–203. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Masood, M.; Ahmad, I.; Sarwar, M.K.; Khan, N.M.; Waseem, M.; Nabi, G.; Saleem, M. A Bilevel Multiobjective Model for Optimal Allocation of Water Resources in the Punjab Province of Pakistan. Arab. J. Sci. Eng. 2021, 46, 10597–10612. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Wu, W.; Zhao, X.; Zhang, X.; Wu, X.; Zhao, Y.; Guo, Q.; Yao, L.; Liu, X. An ordered multi-objective fuzzy stochastic approach to sustainable water resources management: A case study from Taiyuan City, China. Water Supply 2024, 24, 10–11. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Hussein, H.; Grandi, M. Dynamic political contexts and power asymmetries: The cases of the Blue Nile and the Yarmouk Rivers. Int. Environ. Agreem. 2017, 17, 795–814. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Zeitoun, M.; Mirumachi, N.; Warner, J.F. Transboundary water interaction II. Int. Environ. Agreem. 2011, 11, 159–178. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Diakoulaki, D.; Mavrotas, G.; Papayannakis, L. Determining objective weights in multiple criteria problems: The critic method. Comput. Oper. Res. 1995, 22, 763–770. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Rostamzadeh, R.; Ghorabaee, M.K.; Govindan, K.; Esmaeili, A.; Nobar, H.B.K. Evaluation of sustainable supply chain risk management using an integrated fuzzy TOPSIS-CRITIC approach. J. Clean. Prod. 2018, 175, 651–669. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Curiel, I.J.; Maschler, M.; Tijs, S.H. Bankruptcy games. Math. Methods Oper. Res. 1987, 31, 143–159. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Wu, Q.; Xu, N. Improved interactive methods of multi-objective decision-making based on target satisfaction degree. J. Manag. Eng. 1996, 4, 217–222. [Google Scholar]
  48. Janjua, S.; Ali, M.U.; Kallu, K.D.; Zafar, A.; Hussain, S.J.; Gardezi, H.; Lee, S.W. An Asymmetric Bargaining Model for Natural-Gas Distribution. Appl. Sci. 2022, 12, 5677. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Gao, R.; Chen, H.; Wei, C.; Jiang, Y.; Zeng, S.; Zhang, C.; Jin, Y.; Zhang, W. Research Hotspots and Trends in the Environment Condition of the Yellow River Basin (2014–2024): A Bibliometric and Visualization. Water 2024, 16, 2359. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Omer, A.; Ma, Z.; Xing, Y.; Zheng, Z.; Saleem, F. A hydrological perspective on drought risk-assessment in the Yellow River Basin under future anthropogenic activities. J. Manag. Eng. 2021, 289, 112429. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Zhao, F.; Ma, S.; Wu, Y. Changes in Dry-Season Water Availability and Attributions in the Yellow River Basin, China. Front. Environ. Sci. 2021, 9, 762137. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Sun, X.; Zhou, Z.; Wang, Y. Water resource carrying capacity and obstacle factors in the Yellow River basin based on the RBF neural network model. Environ. Sci. Pollut. Res. 2023, 30, 22743–22759. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Yang, Y.; Zhao, J.; Cai, X. Decentralized Optimization Method for Water Allocation Management in the Yellow River Basin. J. Water Resour. Plan. Manag. 2012, 138, 313–325. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Zhou, K.; Wang, Y.; Chang, J.; Zhou, S.; Guo, A. Spatial and Temporal Evolution of Drought Characteristics Across the Yellow River basin. Ecol. Indic. 2021, 131, 108207. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Herrero, C.; Villar, A. The three musketeers: Four classical solutions to bankruptcy problems. Math. Soc. Sci. 2001, 42, 307–328. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Thomson, W. Axiomatic and game-theoretic analysis of bankruptcy and taxation problems: An update. Math. Soc. Sci. 2015, 74, 41–59. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. UN Watercourses Convention. Convention on the Law of the Non-navigational Uses of International Watercourses. Adopted by the General Assembly of the United Nations on 21 May 1997. Available online: https://unece.org/environment-policy/water/un-watercourses-convention (accessed on 1 September 2024).
Figure 1. Methodological flowchart of the proposed water allocation framework.
Figure 1. Methodological flowchart of the proposed water allocation framework.
Water 16 02828 g001
Figure 2. Geographical location of the Yellow River Basin in China.
Figure 2. Geographical location of the Yellow River Basin in China.
Water 16 02828 g002
Figure 3. Water consumption of each province in YRB.
Figure 3. Water consumption of each province in YRB.
Water 16 02828 g003
Figure 4. Negotiation weight coefficients of nine agents in YRB.
Figure 4. Negotiation weight coefficients of nine agents in YRB.
Water 16 02828 g004
Figure 5. Water allocation satisfaction of nine agents in YRB under different allocation methods.
Figure 5. Water allocation satisfaction of nine agents in YRB under different allocation methods.
Water 16 02828 g005
Figure 6. Comparison results between symmetric (SPI-1,2) methods and asymmetric (API-1,2) methods under the “87” Water Allocation Plan (a,b) and the Yellow River Basin Plan (c,d).
Figure 6. Comparison results between symmetric (SPI-1,2) methods and asymmetric (API-1,2) methods under the “87” Water Allocation Plan (a,b) and the Yellow River Basin Plan (c,d).
Water 16 02828 g006
Figure 7. Quantitative results of the willingness of nine agents in YRB to cooperate and the stability of the solutions in equal and asymmetric negotiation cases.
Figure 7. Quantitative results of the willingness of nine agents in YRB to cooperate and the stability of the solutions in equal and asymmetric negotiation cases.
Water 16 02828 g007
Table 1. Representative indicators that are used to quantify agents’ external negotiation power.
Table 1. Representative indicators that are used to quantify agents’ external negotiation power.
Objective LayerCriterion LayerIndicator LayerUnitAttribute
Solving the transboundary water allocation conflicts under scarcityWater contributionProportion of annual average runoff to the total runoff of the entire watershed%Positive
Respecting the current situationCurrent water consumption108 m3Positive
Economic efficiencyEconomic output per cubic meter of water consumptionYuan/m3Positive
Eco-environmental sustainabilityReserved water for inner-river eco-environment108 m3Positive
Sewage discharged108 tonNegative
Table 2. Water allocations of the “87” Water Allocation Plan and the Yellow River Basin Plan (unit: billion m³).
Table 2. Water allocations of the “87” Water Allocation Plan and the Yellow River Basin Plan (unit: billion m³).
Existing PlanningDecision-Making AgentsOff-Stream Water AllocationInner-river Water AllocationTotal
QinghaiSichuanGansuNingxiaInner MongoliaShaanxiShanxiHenanShandongHebei and Tianjin
“87” Water Allocation Plan1.4100.0403.0404.0005.8603.8004.3105.5407.0002.00037.00021.00058.000
Yellow River Basin Plan1.3160.0372.8373.7325.4683.5464.0225.1696.5320.62033.27918.70051.979
Table 3. Representative indicators that are used to quantify the external negotiation power of nine agents in YRB.
Table 3. Representative indicators that are used to quantify the external negotiation power of nine agents in YRB.
IndicatorUnitDecision-Making Agents
QinghaiSichuanGansuNingxiaInner
Mongolia
ShaanxiShanxiHenanShandong
Proportion of annual average runoff to the total runoff of the entire watershed%34.057.8220.111.563.4414.948.157.182.75
Current water consumption108 m310.640.2030.3044.1984.5250.0943.0365.1888.87
Economic output per cubic meter of water consumptionYuan/m3123.80205.1882.0555.8589.30288.98242.47231.96328.67
Reserved water for riverine eco-environment108 m371.5116.4342.223.297.2331.3617.1215.085.78
Sewage discharged108 ton1.410.034.723.125.729.896.646.945.54
Table 4. Minimum water allocations of nine agents in YRB (unit: billion m³).
Table 4. Minimum water allocations of nine agents in YRB (unit: billion m³).
Existing
Planning
Decision-Making AgentsTotal
QinghaiSichuanGansuNingxiaInner MongoliaShaanxiShanxiHenanShandong
Water demand1.0970.0273.4164.2028.0555.0374.2406.5479.28541.906
“87” Water Allocation Plan00001.1490002.3793.528
Yellow River Basin Plan000000000.0380.038
Table 5. Water allocation results of nine agents in YRB under different allocation methods (unit: billion m³).
Table 5. Water allocation results of nine agents in YRB under different allocation methods (unit: billion m³).
Allocation
Scenarios
Decision-Making AgentsPROSPI-1SPI-2API-1API-2
x i d i x i d i x i d i x i d i x i d i
Available water quantity under the “87” Water Allocation PlanQinghai9.171.819.171.819.001.9710.970.0010.970.00
Sichuan0.230.040.230.040.220.050.200.070.190.08
Gansu28.535.6328.535.6328.016.1526.048.1225.768.40
Ningxia35.096.9235.096.9234.467.5621.4020.6221.1720.85
Inner Mongolia67.2813.2767.2813.2768.1212.4359.9620.5962.0418.52
Shaanxi42.078.3042.078.3041.309.0646.503.8745.974.39
Shanxi35.416.9935.416.9934.777.6333.808.6033.438.97
Henan54.6810.7954.6810.7953.6911.7858.287.19 57.607.87
Shandong77.5515.3077.5515.3080.4212.4392.850.0092.850.00
Total350.0069.06350.0069.06350.0069.06350.0069.06350.0069.06
Qinghai8.552.428.552.428.552.4210.970.0010.970.00
Available water quantity under the Yellow River Basin PlanSichuan0.210.060.210.060.210.060.180.090.180.09
Gansu26.627.5426.627.5426.627.5423.7910.3723.7910.37
Ningxia32.749.2732.749.2732.749.2819.6022.4219.6022.42
Inner Mongolia62.7817.7762.7817.7762.7617.7953.9126.6453.9126.64
Shaanxi39.2511.1139.2511.1139.2411.1242.078.2942.078.29
Shanxi33.049.3633.049.3633.049.3630.7711.6330.7711.63
Henan51.0214.4551.0214.4551.0114.4652.4413.0352.4413.03
Shandong72.3620.4972.3620.4972.4320.4292.850.0092.850.00
Total326.5992.47326.5992.47326.5992.47326.5992.47326.5992.47
Note: x i denotes the water quantity allocated to agent i ; d i denotes the water deficit endured by agent i .
Table 6. Comparison of results of water allocation satisfaction between the solutions with and without considering the agent’s minimum water allocation (unit: %).
Table 6. Comparison of results of water allocation satisfaction between the solutions with and without considering the agent’s minimum water allocation (unit: %).
Agents“87” Water Allocation PlanYellow River Basin Plan
SPI-2~SPI-1API-2~API-1SPI-2~SPI-1API-2~API-1
Qinghai−1.520.00−0.020.00
Sichuan−1.52−0.71−0.020.00
Gansu−1.52−0.81−0.020.00
Ningxia−1.52−0.53−0.020.00
Inner Mongolia1.052.58−0.020.00
Shaanxi−1.52−1.04−0.020.00
Shanxi−1.51−0.87−0.020.00
Henan−1.52−1.04−0.020.00
Shandong3.100.000.070.00
Note: (1) SPI-2~SPI-1 denotes the water allocation satisfaction changes of the agents under SPI-2 solution relative to SPI-1 solution; (2) API-2~API-1 denotes the water allocation satisfaction of the agents under API-2 solution relative to API-1 solution.
Table 7. Comparison of results of water allocation satisfaction between the two plans customized for division of YRB and the API-2 solution (unit: %).
Table 7. Comparison of results of water allocation satisfaction between the two plans customized for division of YRB and the API-2 solution (unit: %).
AgentsWater Allocation SatisfactionRelative Changes in Water Allocation Satisfaction
“87” Water Allocation PlanYellow River Basin Plan“87” Water Allocation PlanYellow River Basin Plan
Qinghai128.49119.92−28.49−19.92
Sichuan148.15137.04−76.25−69.82
Gansu88.9983.05−13.58−13.40
Ningxia95.2088.82−44.81−42.19
Inner Mongolia72.7567.884.26−0.96
Shaanxi75.4570.4115.8313.13
Shanxi101.6594.86−22.80−22.29
Henan84.6278.953.371.15
Shandong75.3970.3524.6129.65
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Qin, J.; Fu, X.; Wu, X.; Wang, J.; Huang, J.; Chen, X.; Liu, J.; Zhang, J. Transboundary Water Allocation under Water Scarcity Based on an Asymmetric Power Index Approach with Bankruptcy Theory. Water 2024, 16, 2828. https://doi.org/10.3390/w16192828

AMA Style

Qin J, Fu X, Wu X, Wang J, Huang J, Chen X, Liu J, Zhang J. Transboundary Water Allocation under Water Scarcity Based on an Asymmetric Power Index Approach with Bankruptcy Theory. Water. 2024; 16(19):2828. https://doi.org/10.3390/w16192828

Chicago/Turabian Style

Qin, Jianan, Xiang Fu, Xia Wu, Jing Wang, Jie Huang, Xuxun Chen, Junwu Liu, and Jiantao Zhang. 2024. "Transboundary Water Allocation under Water Scarcity Based on an Asymmetric Power Index Approach with Bankruptcy Theory" Water 16, no. 19: 2828. https://doi.org/10.3390/w16192828

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop