1. Introduction
Farmland is not only the most important input of farm production, but also the main asset of a farm household. The price of farmland is an important determinant of farm household wellbeing in that it represents a major proportion of farm production expenses [
1]. There has been longstanding research interest in the determinants of farmland values. The correlation between agricultural subsidies and farmland values has been acknowledged. Floyd’s seminal paper on this topic provided a simple theory to demonstrate that agricultural subsidies can affect farmers’ gross income and contribute to increasing returns related to farmland [
2]. The author stated that different agricultural programs can impact farmland values to different extents. This strand of literature highlights the capitalization effect of agricultural subsidies on farmland values.
Copious empirical studies have examined the capitalization effect of different forms of agricultural support programs on farmland values. This strand of literature focuses on a variety of government policies in different countries; it includes the assessment of the impacts on farmland values resulting from the subsidies of farm programs [
3,
4,
5,
6,
7,
8,
9]. A general consensus drawn from the existing studies is that subsidies of agricultural programs can capitalize farmland values to some extent. Few studies found insignificant capitalization effects. For instance, Devadoss and Manchu [
10] found an insignificant influence of government payments on farmland prices in the state of Idaho in the United States. A negative effect of direct payments on farmland values is found in Mishra et al. [
11]. The authors argued that the negative capitalization effect is due to credit constraints. A comprehensive review of the theory and empirical evidence regarding the capitalization effect of agricultural program subsides on farmland values can be found in Latruffe and Mouel [
12]. However, not much is known about agricultural disaster relief subsidies.
In this study, we argue that the agricultural disaster relief program (ADRP) should not be treated in the same manner as other farm programs because the nature of the ADRP is quite different from other farm support programs. On the one hand, when farmland is affected by disaster and it could result in a stigmatized effect on the affected parcels of land, which can lower its overall market value. The concept of the stigmatized effect has been used to examine the impacts of environmental risk, such as flood hazards [
13,
14,
15], on housing or property values. For example, McKenzie and Levendis [
14] examined the influences of consumers’ willingness to pay for housing in New Orleans before and after the flooding of hurricane Katrina. That study pointed out a negative stigmatized effect on housing prices after Katrina. Beltran, Maddison, and Elliott [
15] recently conducted a meta-analysis that summarized 384 point estimates from journal articles and found a 4.6% price reduction for land located in a 100 year inland floodplain area. In sum, most studies in this strand of literature focus on the impacts on housing prices or property values by different types of environmental risk. Relatively little research has focused on farmland. One exception is found. Wang [
16] investigated the extent to which flood risk premiums can capitalize into farmland values in Lancaster County in the state of Pennsylvania in the United States. The author found a 6% reduction in market prices on farmland located in Federal Emergency Management Agency (FEMA) flood zones.
The primary objective of this paper is to quantify the effects of the ADRP payments on farmland prices using a case study of Taiwan as an illustration. Since urban-rural disparity of farmland values has been documented in existing studies [
17,
18], we also examine the regional differences in relation to the effects of the ARDP on farmland values. In Taiwan, farmers can receive cash payments to compensate for their losses in farm production resulting from natural disaster shocks (the ADRP program in Taiwan is described in
Section 2). In contrast to the cases in other countries such as the United States, there is no private crop insurance programs available to farmers in Taiwan. The ADRP is therefore the only program that can be used to compensate farmers’ loss resulting from disaster shocks. As documented in the literature [
19,
20], farmers can decide whether they want to participate in private crop insurance programs or not. This can result in self-selection bias and create complications in the empirical analysis regarding the disaster shocks on farm production practice.
This study contributes to existing studies with respect to several aspects. A sizable body of literature has documented the stigmatized effect of real estate values that are associated with a variety of environmental risks, but not much attention has been paid to farmland. This study complements this strand of literature by examining the stigmatized effect on farmland prices resulting from disaster shocks. Only two studies were found that examined the capitalization effect of agricultural disaster payments on farmland values in the United States [
19,
20]. Our study differs from these two studies in several manners. First, farmland prices and the amount of disaster relief payments in their studies are self-reported by the farmers. In contrast, our measurements of farmland prices were drawn from the sale values of farmland transacted in the farmland market and the level of disaster payments was drawn from the administrative profile managed by the government. Using these objective measurements can avoid measurement errors in statistical analysis. Second, the category of disaster payments was documented in the farm household survey data as conducted by Goodwin et al. [
19] and includes payments from different government programs. In contrast, our study only considers payments for disaster relief assistance. Our measure is more likely to capture the pure effect of the disaster relief payments on farmland values. Third, we address the issue of urban-rural disparity with respect to the effect of the ADRP on farmland prices which has not been addressed in previous two studies.
The remainder of this paper is constructed as follows. A brief introduction to the farmland market and agricultural disaster relief program in Taiwan is provided in the next section. The data used in this study are introduced in the following section. We then discuss the econometric strategy. After presenting and discussing the empirical results, we conclude this paper with a brief summary.
2. The Agricultural Disaster Relief Program in Taiwan
Agriculture production in Taiwan is vulnerable to natural disasters because it is located in a semi-tropical zone. On average, 3.2 typhoons struck Taiwan annually between 1960 and 2010 [
21]. Heavy rainfall brought by typhoons causes severe damage to agriculture, especially to crop production. In 2015, the aggregated annual loss in agricultural products and farm facilities due to natural disasters amounted to USD
$ 535 million [
22]. To compensate farmers for their losses, the Agricultural Disaster Relief Program (ADRP) was launched in 1991 and agricultural disaster payments were instituted. The ADRP is applicable to farm damages caused by natural disasters. From 2000 to 2010, the total ADRP cash payments reached US
$ 935 million [
21]. Unlike the United States where different types of agricultural insurance programs (such as crop insurance programs) are available to farmers, the government-sponsored ADRP is the only program in Taiwan that provides compensation to farmers for their losses resulting from natural disasters.
The ADRP payments are provided by the central government’s financial budget. The ADRP program provides lump sum cash payments to farm producers who have suffered catastrophic losses and the cash payments are used to reimburse producers for crop and facility losses. The calculation of the crop losses is based on the following criteria. For crops which can be harvested by transferred cultivation, losses are calculated as 50% of the total production costs; for crops that cannot be transferred for cultivation, losses are calculated as total production costs; and for crops that cannot be harvested, losses are calculated as the cost of restoring the farm. Similarly, the level of ADRP payments paid for livestock farms depend on the values of production costs, which vary according to the types of livestock. After the occurrence of a natural disaster, the officials at the local agricultural station collect information on all of the applications and report to the Council of Agriculture for final inspection and approval. The administrative profile of the ADRP program provides precise measurement of the crop and facility losses due to natural disasters.
To provide a visual understanding of the regional disparity of the ADRP payments, we depict the distribution of the cumulated ADRP payments from August 2012 to December 2015 in each township in
Figure 1. In total, there are 368 townships in Taiwan. Of these, 311 (approximately 87%) have been affected by agricultural disasters. Among the 311 disaster-affected townships, those with darker color have higher ADRP payments. It appears that townships located in mid-western areas tend to be the hot spots of receiving ADRP payments. The distribution of the ADRP payments is consistent with the fact that the mid-western areas are flatter and they are the primary agricultural production zones (i.e., rural areas) in Taiwan.
3. Data
Our data are unique in that we combined information from different sources. We describe each of the data sources in detail below.
3.1. Administrative Profile of Agricultural Disaster Relief Program
The first dataset we used is a national administrative profile that contains all of the recipients of the ADRP payments between August 2012 and December 2015 (41 months in total). This profile was managed by the Agriculture and Food Agency of the Council of Agriculture. This profile documents the size of the damaged farm, total received cash payments, and the township of each parcel of farmland. Moreover, it documents the name of each disaster event that is associated with the payments. Due to the concern of confidentiality, we could not access each individual farm record in this data. With the technical assistance provided by the Council of Agriculture, we were only able to access the information of the ADRP in each township.
Based on the information in the ADRP administrative profile, we categorize the types of disasters into two groups: typhoons and non-typhoons events (including strong wind, heavy rainfall, low or high temperature, droughts, and cold fronts). In
Table 1, we report sample statistics for the number of visits, the number of townships that were affected, total disaster payments, sizes of the affected farmland, and average ADRP payments. As reported in
Table 1, there were 50 natural disasters that struck Taiwan between August 2012 and December 2015; of these, 41 and 9 were typhoons and non-typhoon events, respectively. In total, 1166 townships were affected by disasters; 52% of them were affected by typhoons (603/1166 = 0.52). With respect to the total amount of ADRP payments, a higher level of payments was found to compensate for farmers’ losses resulting from typhoons (approximately 81% of the total ADRP payments). In terms of the average ADRP payments, farmland was paid NTD 62,000/hectare and NTD 37,000/hectare for typhoons and non-typhoons, respectively.
In accordance with the information contained in the administrative ADRP profile, two variables are defined. The first variable is a dummy variable which indicates the specific townships that received the ADRP payments in each month. Since ADRP payments were only paid to the farmland that was affected by disasters, this variable captures the extensive margin of disaster shocks. The second variable is the average monthly ADRP payments per hectare of the damaged farmland in each township between August 2012 and December 2015. These two variables are then merged into the individual farmland sales dataset by the township of the transacted farmland and the month of transaction (see more of the introduction below).
3.2. Administrative Profile of the Sales Record in the Farmland Market
The primary dataset is the farmland sales records drawn from the Actual Price Registration System (APRS). The APRS is an administrative and population-based sales dataset of property transactions conducted by the Minister of the Interior in Taiwan. The profile contains all of the real estate transactions since 1 August 2012. Information contained in this administrative profile includes sales prices, date of transaction, size and other characteristics of the property, and geographic location of each transacted object. To maintain confidentiality, the Minister of the Interior in Taiwan only releases the month of the transaction and the township of the real estate; the exact date and geographical location of the real estate are not released.
Since this study focuses on farmland, we first limit our sample to farmland only. Farmland is defined following the criterion used by the Council of Agriculture. The final sample contains 97,864 parcels of farmland that were transacted in the farmland market between August 2012 and December 2015 (41 months in total). For each parcel of the transacted farmland, the characteristics of the farmland are documented. The value of farmland is captured by the sales price per hectare of the transacted farmland. In accordance with the hedonic price theory and information documented in the data, we specify a continuous variable for the size of each parcel of the farmland. In addition, four dummy variables are specified if the farmland is located in a specific agricultural zone, regular agricultural zone, conservation zone, or other types of agricultural zones, respectively.
3.3. Characteristics of Typhoons
We collected additional information to capture the severity of the disaster shocks. Given that the ADRP payments associated with typhoons account for approximately 81% of the total ADRP payments and that there were nine typhoons that passed through Taiwan during our sample period, we defined two variables that captured the severity of each typhoon: the minimum central pressure and the maximum wind speed of each typhoon. For each typhoon, we assigned the same value of the minimum central pressure and the maximum wind speed to its affected townships. These two variables were constructed and provided by the Central Weather Bureau.
The definitions and sample statistics of the selected variables are reported in
Table 2. In
Table 2, we report the sample statistics of the selected variables in the full sample and the two subgroups of farmland: those affected by disasters and those that were not. In the full sample, the average sales price was NTD 39,680,000 per hectare of farmland. It appears that the average sales price is lower among the farmlands that had been affected by natural disasters (NTD 39,060,000/hectare) than their counterparts that were never affected by natural disasters (NTD 39,740,000/hectare). The average ADRP payments were NTD 4270/hectare in the full sample and NTD 45,220/hectare for the farmland affected by natural disasters.
To provide snapshot evidence of the regional differences in the association between the ADRP and farmland prices, we report the sample statistics of the selected variables for the urban and rural sample, respectively, in
Table 3. The definition of rural and urban areas follows the categorization of Chang and Fu [
23]. These authors applied the Beale code which has been used in the United States to categorize all of the townships in Taiwan into seven subgroups of different economic development based on population density, the degree of industrialization, public facilities, and geographic characteristics. For simplicity, the authors further combine the seven subgroups of townships into a binary classification for rural and urban area. This binary categorization has been a protocol of rural-urban classification in official governmental reports.
In our sample, approximately 26% of the farmland transactions occurred in urban areas (24,966/97,864 = 0.26). It appears that the average prices per hectare are much higher for farmland in urban areas than in rural areas (NTD 6315 vs. NTD 3164, respectively). Regarding the urban-rural disparity in farmland prices, it appears that the average price of farmland is higher for those that were never affected by disasters compared to the disaster-affected farmland.
In addition to the differences in farmland prices displayed in
Table 2,
Table 3 also indicates the differences in the sample statistics of other explanatory variables between the disaster-affected and non-disaster-affected groups of farmland. For example, farmland located in a specific agricultural zone is more likely to be affected by natural disasters. This finding reveals that it is necessary to control for the differences in other explanatory variables between farmland in the two groups in order to identify the effects of the ADRP on farmland prices.
4. Econometric Framework
The primary objective of the empirical analysis is to estimate the farmland price equation. To reach this objective, it is important to understand the determinants of farmland prices. We build our empirical estimation based on the hedonic price theory. The hedonic price model is a revealed preference technique which states that the price of a good observed in the marketplace is a function of its attributes or characteristics. It provides the theoretical underpinnings for empirical models that estimate the marginal prices for a product’s characteristics. This model has been widely used to examine the role of environmental factors and land characteristics on farmland prices (see Nickerson and Zhang [
24] for a comprehensive review of the literature). In the case of farmland prices, the hedonic price theory predicts that farmland characteristics, geographic location, and government programs should be associated with farmland prices. We follow the guidance of the hedonic price model to specify our farmland price equation.
In addition to the variables that reflect farmland characteristics and government program, some unobserved environmental factors may also determine farmland prices. For example, the unobserved soil quality in an area that each farmland is located can possibly be associated with farmland prices. That is, farmland that is located in an environmentally sensitive area may have lower market value and may be more vulnerable to natural disaster shocks. In this case, the unobserved soil quality will result in lower farmland prices and a higher likelihood of receiving ADRP payments. This problem refers to the omitted variable bias or endogeneity bias [
25]. The endogeneity issue of modeling the farmland price equation has been addressed. A literature review of modeling farmland price equations can be found in Nickerson and Zhang [
24]. In this study, we apply the fixed effect (FE) model and the instrumental variable fixed effect (IV-FE) model to cope with endogeneity bias. By using the FE model, bias can be controlled for in terms of modeling farmland prices that is due to time-invariant unobserved factors, such as soil quality. The FE model has been shown as a powerful method to deal with the endogeneity bias resulting from unobserved factors [
25].
4.1. The Fixed Effect Model
The baseline model we estimate is the FE model for the farmland price equation. The equation that controls for the township and month fixed effects is specified as the following:
where
is the logarithm of the sale prices of
ith parcel of farmland in township
j and time
t. The variable
is related to the ADRP. In the empirical analysis, we used the likelihood of receiving ADRP payments and the amount of ADRP payments to measure the extensive and intensive margin of the ADRP, respectively.
is a vector of explanatory variables related to farmland prices (i.e., different types of agricultural zones and the size of farmland; see
Table 2).
and
are the fixed effects in townships and months, respectively, and
is the random error.
,
are the parameters to be estimated. In Equation (1), the most interesting parameter is
, which captures the effect of the ADRP on farmland prices,
ceteris paribus.
4.2. The Instrumental Variable Fixed Effect Model
In addition to the standard FE model, we estimate the farmland price equation using the Instrumental Variable Fixed Effect (IV-FE) model. The IV-FE model is a straightforward application of the IV method to the FE framework. The IV-FE can overcome the endogeneity bias that is due to unobservable heterogeneity [
25]. In this study, we use the minimum central pressure and the maximum wind speed of each typhoon that struck Taiwan in our sample period as the IVs. The justification of using these two IVs is as follows. First, nine typhoons hit Taiwan in our sample period, with 603 townships affected by them (approximately 52% of the 1166 disaster-affected townships). The characteristics of typhoons provide enough statistical power of exogenous variation to identify the econometric model. Second, it is expected that the characteristics of typhoons and the severity of damages are directly correlated. Given that the ADRP payments are used to compensate for the loss of farm production and farm facilities, the characteristics of typhoons and the ADRP payments should be directly connected as well. This argument is also supported by some studies which have pointed out a positive correlation between weather conditions and agricultural disaster payments. For example, Nadolnyak and Hartarska [
26] used county-level data from four states in the Southeastern United States to show that weather and climate variables explain most of the crop disaster payments. They also suggest that advancements in weather and climate forecasts could be used to determine disaster compensation.
4.3. Identification Conditions
The identification condition of the standard FE model relies on the assumption that the inclusion of the township and time fixed effects can cope with endogeneity bias as long as the source of endogeneity is due to time-invariant unobservable factors [
25]. As an example, soil quality may vary by township and it cannot be observed by researchers. If soil quality does not change over time in a specific township, the endogeneity bias of the ADRP on farmland prices can be controlled by the fixed effect parameter
.
Although the standard FE model can ease the endogeneity bias, its identification condition relies on the assumption that all of the sources that result in endogeneity bias must come from unobservable time-invariant factors. This assumption is somewhat a strong one in that some unobservable determinants of farmland prices may change over time. If any of the time-variant unobservable determinants exist, the standard FE model will produce inconsistent estimation results. In continuing with the example of soil quality for illustration, the standard FE model can produce inconsistent estimates if the unobservable soil quality changes over time in a specific township. To further avoid the endogeneity bias due to time-variant unobservable factors, we estimate the farmland price equation using the IV-FE model. Although the IV-FE models can further control for endogeneity bias due to time-variant unobservable factors on farmland prices, the validation of the IV model relies on two critical assumptions. We will discuss each of them in the following and empirically test the appropriateness of these assumptions in
Section 6.
6. Conclusions
The world has witnessed a rapid increase in extreme natural events and natural disasters are expected to be more frequent in the future. The need to address the impacts of natural disaster shocks on farmland values is becoming more important. This study contributes to this issue by examining the effects of the agricultural disaster relief program on farmland prices. In contrast to other farm support programs, the effect of agricultural disaster relief programs on farmland prices can be either positive or negative depending on the trade-off between a positive capitalization effect of the subsidies into farmland and a negative stigmatized effect on farmland values resulting from disaster shocks.
Using a unique dataset that combines the sales records of farmland in the farmland market and the administrative profile of the agricultural disaster relief program in Taiwan, we estimated a farmland price equation using the fixed effect and the instrumental variable fixed effect model to cope with endogeneity bias. The results pointed out a negative program effect on farmland prices. Farmland affected by disasters has a lower market price by 2.43% on average compared to farmland that was never affected by disasters. Moreover, an increase of NTD 10,000 in disaster relief payments lowers farmland prices by 0.54%, ceteris paribus. Furthermore, compared to farmland located in a rural area, the negative effect of disaster shocks on farmland prices is more pronounced among farmlands in an urban area.
In regard to policy relevance, the evident negative effect of the disaster relief subsidies on farmland prices may point out the possibility that the current level of the cash subsidies on the disaster-affected farmland is not high enough to outweigh the negative stigmatized effect resulting from disaster shocks. This result may not be too surprising since the level of the disaster relief subsidies in the current policy regime is meant to compensate for the loss of farm production and does not account for the non-production values of the farmland, such as the option values in development.
Although this paper reveals interesting findings, some caveats remain. For instance, it will be interesting to further investigate whether different types of disasters result in different effects on farmland prices. This paper omits this issue due to the difficulty in accessing the payments data on non-typhoon events because such events only affect a limited number of farms in a few townships. For example, droughts have been found to be a severe event that affects farm production in other countries. However, this is not the case in Taiwan. Given the geographic location of Taiwan, agricultural disaster payments given to farmers as a result of drought damage only accounts for approximately 5% of the total payments of the agricultural disaster relief program. Another potential caveat is the lack of buyers’ information in farmland transactions, especially buyers’ motivation and purposes in regard to purchasing farmland. If this information becomes available, it will be helpful to understand whether farmland in an urban area is more likely to be used for farm production or asset investment.