Farmland Dispute Prevention: The Role of Land Titling, Social Capital and Household Capability
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Institutional Background and Theoretical Framework
2.1. Farmland Tenure Reform in China
2.2. Farmland Disputes and Land Titling in China
2.3. Theoretical Consideration
3. Empirical Model and Estimation Strategy
3.1. Model Setting
3.2. Data and Variable Definition
4. Estimation Results and Robustness Check
4.1. Results
4.2. Robustness Check
5. Conclusions and Policy Implications
Author Contributions
Funding
Data Availability Statement
Acknowledgments
Conflicts of Interest
1 | This database consists of the China Family Database (CFD), produced by Zhejiang University, the China Household Finance Survey(CHFS) and the China Community Governance Survey(CCGS) produced by Southwestern University of Finance and Economics, and the China Grassroots Governance Survey(CGGS) prodeuced by Nanjing Audit University. |
2 | The time intervals are approximate due to the regional difference at the time of contracting. |
3 | It’s noteble that the land area is calculated on the basis of GIS coordinates for most of the practical cases. |
4 | This map contains information about the provinces from which the samples emanate. However, the dataset is quasi-open access; therefore, names of counties and villages and spatial information pertaining to them have been kept confidential to the users (Source of the map: Ministry of Natural Resources of the PRC). |
5 | The value of total consumption is calculated by authors based on the sum of various terms including the consumption of food, clothes, healthcare, house maintain, transportation, communication, energy, education, entertainment. |
6 | We use willingness to accept because land sale is forbidden in rural China. |
7 | For the convenience of reading we omitted the results of unnecessary variables. |
References
- Coser, L.A. The Functions of Social Conflict; Routledge: London, UK, 1956. [Google Scholar]
- André, C.; Platteau, J. Land relations under unbearable stress: Rwanda caught in the Malthusian trap. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 1998, 34, 1–47. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wagner-Pacifici, R.; Hall, M. Resolution of Social Conflict. Annu. Rev. Sociol. 2012, 38, 181–199. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dower, P.C.; Pfutze, T. Land titles and violent conflict in rural Mexico. J. Dev. Econ. 2020, 144, 102431. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sjaastad, E.; Bromley, D.W. The Prejudices of Property Rights: On Individualism, Specificity, and Security in Property Regimes. Dev. Policy Rev. 2000, 18, 365–389. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Deininger, K.; Feder, G. Land Registration, Governance, and Development: Evidence and Implications for Policy. World Bank Res. Obs. 2009, 24, 233–266. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Deininger, K.; Castagnini, R. Incidence and impact of land conflict in Uganda. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 2006, 60, 321–345. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Holden, S.T.; Deininger, K.; Ghebru, H. Can Land Registration and Certification Reduce land Border Conflicts? Available online: https://www.econstor.eu/bitstream/10419/242701/1/clts-wp2011-05.pdf (accessed on 20 September 2022).
- Linkow, B. Causes and Consequences of Perceived Land Tenure Insecurity: Survey Evidence from Burkina Faso. Land Econ. 2016, 92, 308–327. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wehrmann, B. Cadastre in Itself Won ’t Solve the Problem: The Role of Institutional Change and Psychological Motivations in Land Conflicts—Cases from Africa. In Proceedings of the Promoting Land Administration and Good Governance 5th FIG Regional Conference, Accra, Ghana; 2006. [Google Scholar]
- Coase, R.H. The Federal Communications Commission. J. Law Econ. 1959, 2, 1–40. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Bezu, S.; Holden, S. Demand for second-stage land certification in Ethiopia: Evidence from household panel data. Land Use Policy 2014, 41, 193–205. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Jansen, K.; Roquas, E. Modernizing Insecurity: The Land Titling Project in Honduras. Dev. Chang. 1998, 29, 81–106. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Benjaminsen, T.A.; Holden, S.; Lund, C.; Sjaastad, E. Formalisation of land rights: Some empirical evidence from Mali, Niger and South Africa. Land Use Policy 2009, 26, 28–35. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ege, S. Land tenure insecurity in post-certification Amhara, Ethiopia. Land Use Policy 2017, 64, 56–63. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Pagiola, S. Economic Analysis of Rural Land Administration Projects. Available online: https://citeseerx.ist.psu.edu/viewdoc/download?doi=10.1.1.203.1281&rep=rep1&type=pdf (accessed on 20 September 2022).
- Broegaard, R.J. Land Tenure Insecurity and Inequality in Nicaragua. Dev. Chang. 2005, 36, 845–864. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bromley, D.W. Formalising property relations in the developing world: The wrong prescription for the wrong malady. Land Use Policy 2009, 26, 20–27. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Fatema, N. Can land title reduce low-intensity interhousehold conflict incidences and associated damages in eastern DRC? World Dev. 2019, 123, 104612. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Di Falco, S.; Laurent-Lucchetti, J.; Veronesi, M.; Kohlin, G. Property Rights, Land Disputes and Water Scarcity: Empirical Evidence from Ethiopia. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 2020, 102, 54–71. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Rahman, A.; Hossain, R. The uncomfortable truth about land disputes in Bangladesh: Insights from a household survey. Land Use Policy 2020, 95, 104557. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wen, T.; Lang, X.; Zheng, F. The Status Quo of the Social Stability in China’s Villages and the Characteristics thereof: An Analysis Based on an Investigation into 1765 Households in 100 Villages. Manag. World 2011, 3, 66–76. [Google Scholar]
- Peng, Y. Kinship Networks and Entrepreneurs in China’s Transitional Economy. Am. J. Sociol. 2004, 109, 1045–1074. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Zhang, M. Social capital and perceived tenure security of informal housing: Evidence from Beijing, China. Urban Stud. 2022, 59, 2506–2526. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Guan, C.; Shi, X.; Ma, X. Do Social Networks Affect Irrigation Behaviors? A Case Study of Water Theft in Rural Xinjiang, China. Soc. Nat. Resour. 2021, 34, 785–804. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Field, E. Entitled to Work: Urban Property Rights and Labor Supply in Peru. Q. J. Econ. 2007, 122, 1561–1602. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- De Janvry, A.; Emerick, K.; Gonzalez-Navarro, M.; Sadoulet, E. Delinking Land Rights from Land Use: Certification and Migration in Mexico. Am. Econ. Rev. 2015, 105, 3125–3149. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Fenske, J. Land tenure and investment incentives: Evidence from West Africa. J. Dev. Econ. 2011, 95, 137–156. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Barzel, Y. Dispute and its resolution: Delineating the economic role of the common law. Am. Law Econ. Rev. 2000, 2, 238–258. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Krul, K.; Ho, P.; Yang, X. Land titling as a conflict remedy or driver? Analyzing institutional outcomes through latent and manifest conflicts in China’s forest sector. Land Use Policy 2021, 100, 104880. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Deininger, K.; Jin, S. The potential of land rental markets in the process of economic development: Evidence from China. J. Dev. Econ. 2005, 78, 241–270. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ma, X.; Heerink, N.; Feng, S.; Shi, X. Farmland tenure in China: Comparing legal, actual and perceived security. Land Use Policy 2015, 42, 293–306. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wang, H.; Riedinger, J.; Jin, S. Land documents, tenure security and land rental development: Panel evidence from China. China Econ. Rev. 2015, 36, 220–235. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhao, Y. China Rural Land Registration and Certification Piloting Project. Available online: https://www.fig.net/resources/proceedings/2009/fig_wb_2009/papers/sys/sys_3_zhao.pdf (accessed on 20 September 2022).
- Yu, J. Land issues is becoming the focus of farmers’ rights and struggles: A special survey of current rural social status in China. World Surv. Res. 2005, 3, 22–23. [Google Scholar]
- Sun, X. The source of litigation involving agricultural land: An analysis of based on judicial big data. Glob. Law Rev. 2021, 43, 38–53. [Google Scholar]
- Miller, R.E.; Sarat, A. Grievances, Claims, and Disputes: Assessing the Adversary Culture. Law Soc. Rev. 1980, 15, 525–566. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Felstiner, W.L.F.; Abel, R.L.; Sarat, A. The Emergence and Transformation of Disputes: Naming, Blaming, Claiming. Law Soc. Rev. 1980, 15, 631–654. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Polinsky, A.M.; Shavell, S. The Economic Theory of Public Enforcement of Law. J. Econ. Lit. 2000, 38, 45–76. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Bowles, S.; Gints, H. Social capital and community governance. Econ. J. 2002, 112, F419–F436. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ostrom, E.; Ahn, T.K. The Meaning of Social Capital and Its Link to Collective Action. In Handbook of Social Capital; Svendsen, G.T., Svendsen, G.L.H., Eds.; Edward Elgar Publishing: Cheltenham, UK, 2009; pp. 17–35. [Google Scholar]
- Katz, E.G. Social Capital and Natural Capital: A Comparative Analysis of Land Tenure and Natural Resource Management in Guatemala. Land Econ. 2000, 76, 114. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Rao, F.; Spoor, M.; Ma, X.; Shi, X. Land tenure (in)security and crop-tree intercropping in rural Xinjiang, China. Land Use Policy 2016, 50, 102–114. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- King, G.; Zeng, L. Logistic regression in rare events data. Political Anal. 2001, 9, 137–163. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Chen, Q. Climate Shocks, Dynastic Cycles and Nomadic Conquest. China Econ. Q. 2015, 14, 373–394. [Google Scholar]
- Deininger, K.W.; Ayalew, D.; Alemu, T. Impacts of Land Certification on Tenure Security, Investment, and Land Market Participation: Evidence from Ethiopia. Land Econ. 2011, 87, 312–334. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cheng, X.; Wang, J.; Chen, K.Z. Does villager social capital hinder poverty targeting? Evidence from poverty-stricken county of Western China. China Econ. Rev. 2022, 71, 101728. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhang, Y.; Lu, M. Does Social Network Enhance the Wage Rate of Migrant Workers. Manag. World 2009, 3, 45–54. [Google Scholar]
- Ma, G.; Yang, E. Social Networks, Informal Finance and Entrepreneurship. Econ. Res. J. 2011, 46, 83–94. [Google Scholar]
- Tan, S. Exploring the causes of the frequent land conflicts in China. China Land Sci. 2009, 23, 44–50. [Google Scholar]
- Li, L. Between land reallocation and right’s confirmation: How to achieve equity and efficiency in rural land system? A case study on L village in north central Shandong Province. J. Public Manag. 2017, 14, 117–127. [Google Scholar]
- Liu, Z.; Wei, Y.; Li, Q.; Lan, J. The Mediating Role of Social Capital in Digital Information Technology Poverty Reduction an Empirical Study in Urban and Rural China. Land 2021, 10, 634. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Variables | Definition | Means | Std. Dev |
---|---|---|---|
Dependent variable | |||
Farmland disputes | =1 if the household experienced farmland dispute at least once in 2016; =0 otherwise | 0.033 | 0.179 |
Tenure protection | |||
Land titling | =1 if the household holds an official farmland certificate; =0 otherwise | 0.639 | 0.480 |
Moderate variables | |||
Social capital | Average amount of gift money in the village (10 thousand yuan) | 0.182 | 0.155 |
Household capability | Household expenditure per capita in 2016 (10 thousand yuan) | 1.870 | 2.560 |
Land characteristics | |||
Land fragmentation | Number of plots of the contracted farmland | 4.637 | 4.931 |
Land value (WTA) | Willingness to accept farmland sales (ten thousand/mu) | 3.064 | 11.588 |
Household characteristics | |||
Age | Age of household head | 55.251 | 13.615 |
Gender | =1 if gender of household head is male; =0 otherwise | 0.850 | 0.357 |
Household size | Numbers of family members | 3.263 | 1.638 |
Education | Education level of household head | 8.243 | 1.879 |
Village Characteristics | |||
Political stability | Number of years current cadres have been in office (party secretary or committee head) | 7.722 | 6.872 |
Land value (rent) | Average land rent in the village (ten thousand/mu) | 0.061 | 0.157 |
Village economics | Disposable income per capita in 2016 (ten thousand) | 0.845 | 0.593 |
Wealth inequality | The deviation of household expenditure in village | 1.871 | 1.774 |
Land redistribution experience | Lapse of time since the last land redistribution | 18.529 | 6.403 |
Regional dummy | |||
East China | =1 if the household/village locates in east China; =0 otherwise | 0.391 | 0.488 |
Middle China | =1 if the household/village locates in middle China; =0 otherwise | 0.384 | 0.487 |
West China | =1 if the household/village locates in west China; =0 otherwise | 0.224 | 0.417 |
Total Sample | Low Social Capital | Middle Social Capital | High Social Capital | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Not Titled | Titled | Not Titled | Titled | Not Titled | Titled | Not Titled | Titled | |
Pro(Dispute) | 4.20 | 2.80 | 4.35 | 2.40 | 4.31 | 3.04 | 3.95 | 2.96 |
Difference | 1.40 ** | 1.95 ** | 1.27 | 0.99 | ||||
Total sample | Low consumption | Low consumption | High consumption | |||||
Not titled | titled | Not titled | titled | Not titled | titled | Not titled | titled | |
Pro(Dispute) | 4.20 | 2.80 | 3.45 | 1.96 | 5.47 | 3.36 | 3.63 | 3.05 |
Difference | 1.40 ** | 1.49 * | 2.11 ** | 0.58 |
Independent Variables | Probit1 | CLL1 | Probit2 | CLL2 | Probit3 | CLL3 |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Land titling (T) | −0.260 ** | −0.579 ** | −0.697 *** | −1.528 *** | −0.451 *** | −0.901 *** |
0.126 | 0.281 | 0.269 | 0.574 | 0.158 | 0.330 | |
Moderate variables | ||||||
Social capital (S) | −1.054 | −2.406 | −4.020 * | −9.134 * | −1.037 | −2.325 |
0.868 | 2.058 | 2.156 | 4.931 | 0.865 | 2.037 | |
Household capability (H) | −0.007 | −0.016 | −0.003 | −0.004 | −0.103* | −0.172 |
0.020 | 0.042 | 0.020 | 0.041 | 0.054 | 0.110 | |
Cross Term | ||||||
T*S | / | / | 3.896 * | 8.873 * | / | / |
2.273 | 5.188 | |||||
T*H | / | / | / | / | 0.122 ** | 0.204 * |
0.059 | 0.120 | |||||
Land Characteristics | ||||||
Land fragmentation | 0.017 | 0.036 * | 0.015 | 0.031 | 0.017 | 0.036 * |
0.011 | 0.021 | 0.011 | 0.020 | 0.011 | 0.021 | |
Land value (WTA) | 0.017 * | 0.030 * | 0.017* | 0.031 * | 0.017 * | 0.031 * |
0.010 | 0.018 | 0.010 | 0.018 | 0.010 | 0.018 | |
Household Characteristics | ||||||
Age | −0.001 | −0.004 | −0.001 | −0.004 | −0.002 | −0.005 |
0.006 | 0.013 | 0.006 | 0.013 | 0.006 | 0.013 | |
Gender | 0.435 * | 0.917 | 0.450 * | 0.958 | 0.436 * | 0.894 |
0.259 | 0.638 | 0.262 | 0.637 | 0.258 | 0.638 | |
Household size | 0.036 | 0.062 | 0.037 | 0.059 | 0.034 | 0.058 |
0.039 | 0.086 | 0.040 | 0.087 | 0.039 | 0.086 | |
Education | 0.009 | 0.015 | 0.007 | 0.009 | 0.008 | 0.015 |
0.021 | 0.050 | 0.021 | 0.052 | 0.021 | 0.050 | |
Village Characteristics | ||||||
Political stability | −0.014 | −0.030 | −0.014 | −0.029 | −0.014 | −0.030 |
0.010 | 0.023 | 0.010 | 0.023 | 0.010 | 0.023 | |
Land value (rent) | 0.723 | 1.491 | 0.655 | 1.308 | 0.761 | 1.604 |
0.924 | 1.958 | 0.878 | 1.782 | 0.922 | 1.929 | |
Village economics | 0.021 | 0.056 | 0.030 | 0.070 | 0.026 | 0.067 |
0.108 | 0.259 | 0.108 | 0.257 | 0.109 | 0.261 | |
Wealth inequality | 0.063 ** | 0.118 ** | 0.060 ** | 0.108 ** | 0.065 ** | 0.117 ** |
0.028 | 0.049 | 0.028 | 0.048 | 0.029 | 0.050 | |
Land redistribution experience | 0.046 *** | 0.095 *** | 0.042 ** | 0.086 *** | 0.046 *** | 0.095 *** |
0.017 | 0.032 | 0.017 | 0.033 | 0.017 | 0.032 | |
Regional dummy | YES | YES | YES | YES | YES | YES |
Constant | −3.168 *** | −6.007 *** | −2.786 *** | −5.100 *** | −3.008 *** | −5.717 *** |
0.571 | 1.213 | 0.638 | 1.347 | 0.567 | 1.202 |
Variables | Social Capital | Household Consumption | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Groups | High | Middle | Low | High | Middle | Low |
Land titling | −0.054 | −0.133 | −0.382 ** | −0.020 | −0.336 ** | −0.287 * |
(0. 153) | (0.148) | (0.161) | (0.160) | (0.146) | (0.170) | |
Other variables | Controlled |
Variables | Probit (Vote Rate) | Cloglog | Probit (Norms) | Cloglog |
---|---|---|---|---|
Land titling | −2.979 *** | −6.446 *** | −0.996 ** | −2.443 ** |
(0.854) | (2.044) | (0.397) | (1.060) | |
Social capital | −0.014 *** | −0.026 *** | −0.438 ** | −1.000 ** |
(0.004) | (0.007) | (0.210) | (0.453) | |
Cross terms (C*S) | 0.032 *** | 0.068 *** | 0.914 ** | 2.272 ** |
(0.009) | (0.022) | (0.451) | (1.114) | |
Other variables | Controlled |
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations. |
© 2022 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Wang, S.; Rao, F.; Ma, X.; Shi, X. Farmland Dispute Prevention: The Role of Land Titling, Social Capital and Household Capability. Land 2022, 11, 1742. https://doi.org/10.3390/land11101742
Wang S, Rao F, Ma X, Shi X. Farmland Dispute Prevention: The Role of Land Titling, Social Capital and Household Capability. Land. 2022; 11(10):1742. https://doi.org/10.3390/land11101742
Chicago/Turabian StyleWang, Shunran, Fangping Rao, Xianlei Ma, and Xiaoping Shi. 2022. "Farmland Dispute Prevention: The Role of Land Titling, Social Capital and Household Capability" Land 11, no. 10: 1742. https://doi.org/10.3390/land11101742
APA StyleWang, S., Rao, F., Ma, X., & Shi, X. (2022). Farmland Dispute Prevention: The Role of Land Titling, Social Capital and Household Capability. Land, 11(10), 1742. https://doi.org/10.3390/land11101742