1. Introduction
China’s urbanization has entered the late stage of rapid development, and its development process is in the transition period from “size expansion” to “quality improvement” [
1,
2]. The main conflict that constrains China’s urbanization is promoting the quality of urban development while solving resource and environmental problems that arise in the process of urbanization [
1,
3]. In October 2021, the General Office of the State Council issued “Opinions on Promoting Green Development in Urban and Rural Construction”, which explicitly incorporates green development into the assessment of urban development and proposes that “by 2025 the problem of ‘urban disease’ will be alleviated, the green transformation of cities will be effective, and cities will achieve holistic and growth enhancement”. This indicates that urban green development is a necessary part of solving the main conflict between China’s urbanization and the promotion of the green and sustainable development of cities, as well as the inevitable need to build a quality modern economic system [
4,
5].
Urban green development efficiency (GDE) is an effective alternative indicator with which to measure the level of urban green development. It is a comprehensive indicator that pays more attention to resource input and environmental pollution on the basis of economic development efficiency. The improvement in urban GDE is considered as an important way to improve the level of urban green development [
6,
7]. It has thus become increasingly important to study how to improve the urban GDE in enhancing the level of urban development. With the rapid development of transportation interconnection and the industrial division of labor among cities, the trend of networking among cities has become increasingly prominent, and the role of the urban network and its external effects in economic development has become increasingly important [
8,
9]. Additionally, the “borrowing size” arising from the interaction between the markets of different cities can substitute for the local agglomeration economy and thus enhance urban development, i.e., a city exhibits urban functions or economic performance that is greater than that of its larger counterpart [
10]. Under the constraints of resources and the environment [
11], we ask whether the “borrowing size” based on the city network affects the quality of urban development. Furthermore, considering the constraints of the cities’ own sizes, we want to know the effect of the borrowing size on the urban GDE. An in-depth study of these problems will be helpful in moving on from the long-standing debate on China’s urbanization development model and will have theoretical and practical importance for promoting the quality development of new urbanization, the quality development of the economy and the establishment of an urban ecological civilization in China.
There has been disagreement about how to develop urbanization in China, i.e., whether to focus on the development of large cities or to focus on small and medium-sized cities in a polycentric city network [
12]. The source of disagreement mainly relates to whether the agglomeration economy or agglomeration diseconomy dominates in urban expansion. Supporters of focusing on large cities have mainly viewed urbanization from the perspective of an agglomeration economy [
13,
14]; i.e., they hold the belief that the agglomeration economy benefits urban development increase with the size of cities [
15,
16]. However, the agglomeration economy effect of the urban size also has a boundary in that the marginal payoff of the urban size economy starts to diminish once the urban size development exceeds a critical point, which may lead to the dilemma of “agglomeration not economy” and many problems of “big city disease” [
17], several of which have been discussed [
18,
19]. Scholars [
20,
21,
22] who support a polycentric network development model focusing on small and medium-sized cities argue that, with the interconnection of a city network, small and medium-sized cities can borrow the agglomeration economy effects of other cities for their own urban productivity while avoiding agglomeration costs [
23]. In the process of China’s urban development, the mechanism of inter-city borrowing size provides a reasonable explanatory logic for the rapid growth of Chinese cities [
10].
The relationship between the borrowing size, urban network externality and urban development have been key topics of research on urban economics [
12]. The realization of the borrowing size depends on the increasing improvement in urban networks; the borrowing size and urban development need to allow the full play of urban network externality, and the borrowing size and urban network externality are, in turn, driving forces of urban development [
24,
25]. The importance of urban network externality has increased with the gradual improvement in urban network accessibility and inter-city connectivity, and the network advantage has become a club product [
23,
26]. Zonneveld was the first to propose the study of economies of scale based on inter-city connectivity channels from the perspective of the “city network” [
27]. The concept of “urban network externality” emerged from frequent economic activities and functional linkages between cities in an urban network to build a complementary urban network system and to obtain higher economic benefits through the division of labor and functional complementarity between cities [
26,
28]. The borrowing size, which is based on inter-city interconnection, is often considered a manifestation of positive urban network externality [
29], to a certain extent. This overcomes the dilemma of diminishing returns of increasing the size of cities, replaces the local agglomeration economy and improves urban productivity [
10,
27]. Liu and Chen empirically examined the phenomenon of the borrowing size and borrowing functions in China’s urban system from the perspective of network externality and pointed out that building a polycentric city network system with complementary functions should become an important direction of China’s urbanization [
30]. Yao and Song examined the effects of the borrowing size and network externalities on the agglomeration economy of urban agglomerations using data for prefecture-level cities [
24]. Other studies explored the effect of the borrowing size on the productivity of small and medium-sized cities considering three dimensions of the borrowing size, namely the population, economic performance and urban functions [
31]. However, the effects of the borrowing size, population and functions from other cities in an urban network are not necessarily beneficial to urban development [
32]. Rather, the competitive behavior of cities in the urban network may lead to the “siphoning effect” of some large cities on neighboring cities, which negatively affects the development of these neighboring cities, and the urban competition leads to a partial loss of urban development efficiency [
33,
34]. This negative effect of network externality is called the agglomeration shadow [
35,
36]. In the urban network, the borrowing size and agglomeration shadow may coexist in the same urban development process [
37], and there may be differences in the magnitudes of their effects [
24,
38]. Many studies have confirmed the phenomenon of the borrowing size, but no study has directly confirmed the existence of agglomeration shadows [
39,
40].
There are three clear gaps in the existing literature. (1) Scholars have empirically tested the influencing factors of urban GDE from different perspectives [
41], but few studies have linked the urban borrowing size with the urban GDE from the perspective of the urban network. (2) There is no consensus on any of the research findings regarding the possible agglomeration economic effect and congestion effect of urban size expansion on urban green development [
32,
42]. Green development efficiency is a comprehensive indicator that considers economic development, resource conservation and pollution emission. However, few studies have included the urban borrowing size, urban GDE and urban size within the same research framework. (3) The realization of the borrowing size depends on the urban network, and the inter-city traffic accessibility largely affects the borrowing size [
8]. It is thus important to set distance weights when measuring the borrowing size. At present, many scholars choose the spatial Euclidean distance or inter-city train travel time matrix to measure the accessibility of the urban network, but both methods have limitations. The present paper expands and extends the existing research in the following respects. First, the required traffic distance matrix of cities is calculated by crawling the driving path planning of Gaode Map using the R programming language to make the setting of weights more realistic and improve the accuracy of the measurement of borrowing size. Second, this paper uses the data of 280 prefecture-level cities in China to construct the urban network system from the perspective of urban network externality, and incorporates urban borrowing size, urban GDE and city size into the same research framework to explore the effect of borrowing size on the urban GDE. Moreover, considering the possible “threshold effect” of the city size, a panel threshold model is used to test the nonlinear relationship between the borrowing size and urban GDE.
The remainder of the paper is structured as follows.
Section 2 composes the theoretical mechanism and proposes research hypotheses.
Section 3 introduces the econometric model.
Section 4 conducts an empirical analysis and analyzes the results.
Section 5 summarizes the research findings and proposes policy recommendations accordingly.
2. Hypothesis Development
In the urban network, a city’s access to or utilization of the potential size of other cities by virtue of its own node location and functional connection in the urban network is called the borrowing size [
32,
40]. This paper considers three dimensions of the borrowing size, namely the borrowing population size, borrowing economic activity density and borrowing advanced functions [
24,
31]. The realization of the borrowing size requires continual improvement in the urban network [
9]. Additionally, the frequent economic connections between cities and the frequently interacting economic activities between cities are important carriers through which the borrowing size exerts the externality of the urban network [
30]. Therefore, from the perspective of urban network externality, inter-city interconnection accelerates the flow of various factors in the flow space of the urban network, reduces the time cost of factor circulation, improves the efficiency of factor allocation and flow and reduces the waste of resources [
43,
44]. Cities participate in the city network as a kind of club product, which means that not only do the cities themselves receive the city network externality effect but also the cities affect other cities in the city network [
45]. Instead of emphasizing the disorderly competition between cities, city network externality focuses on the division of labor, functional complementarity and synergistic development among cities. In a complementary city network, the borrowing size depends on the mutual integration of the city network, which not only helps cities escape from the dilemma of the diminishing returns of increasing the city size in the development process but also accounts for social and ecological benefits, thus improving the urban GDE [
12,
42].
Hypothesis 1 (H1). The use of the borrowing size is an effective way to promote urban GDE.
In the urban network, the huge borrowing population size provides a potential market size for urban economic development [
26], which breaks the traditional geographical boundary limitation of the location, the vertical spatial hierarchy, the limitation of the local spatial locations of cities and the limitation of the local capacity. On the basis that the interconnection of cities is strengthening, the borrowing population size eliminates many intermediate links of cooperation and transaction between cities, reduces information friction and greatly reduces the cost loss due to information asymmetry. Conversely, it also optimizes the cross-regional allocation of factor and product markets, which is conducive to improving the matching efficiency of supply and demand and factors in the market. This decreases the transaction matching cost in the market and thus reduces the unnecessary efficiency loss and improves the urban GDE [
8]. To a certain extent, the density of economic activities reflects the Jacobs-type externality of urban economic development [
46] and thus the knowledge diffusion and technology spillover among different industries. The urban GDE can be increased through knowledge diffusion and technology spillover. Although the public-good nature of knowledge itself determines its strong spillover, the spillover is still subject to spatial localization effects. In a city network, inter-city interconnection is conducive to both the breaking of the spatial limitation of knowledge spillover and a complementary synergy of inter-city functions [
29]. Having dense borrowing economic activity is an effective method of knowledge diffusion and technology spillover and accelerates inter-city factor flow and technology transfer, resulting in jumping spatial network spillover effects and better transforming knowledge diffusion and technology spillover into economic, social and ecological benefits and thus improved urban GDE [
47]. With the increasingly frequent connection of economic activities among cities, functional linkages and a synergistic relationship among cities have developed. The borrowing of advanced functions for urban development is mainly realized through the spatial division of labor in inter-city functional linkages. With the promotion of borrowing advanced functions, cities can make use of their node status, functional linkages and role relationships in the urban network to borrow advanced functions and thus realize the reasonable division of labor and collaboration of cities in the industrial system [
48]; promote the networking, rationalization and linking of the inter-city division of labor and collaboration through the reasonable division of labor and collaboration among products, industries and industrial chains [
49]; and promote the adding of value to products and industrial upgrades, which are conducive to achieving economies of scale while avoiding non-essential costs and realizing the inclusive growth of cities, thus improving the urban GDE. Accordingly, the following hypothesis is proposed.
Hypothesis 2 (H2). Increases in the borrowing population size, borrowing economic activity density and borrowing advanced functionality are conducive to efficient urban green development.
Scholars generally agree that urban development is closely related to local factors such as the city size [
50,
51]. In recent years, with the deepening of the urban network, the borrowing size based on urban networks is considered to be a substitute for the local agglomeration economy in enhancing urban development. In the new era, the effect of the borrowing size on the urban GDE may also be constrained by the city size [
52]. As one possibility, the expansion of the urban development size may have an agglomeration economy effect on the development of an urban green economy, i.e., the positive externality of the urban size. An expansion of the city size can accelerate the flow of labor and other factors, reduce matching and market transaction costs, expand the spillover effect of knowledge and technology and accelerate the cumulative transformation of knowledge and technology, thus creating higher marginal value-added gains of knowledge and technology. Additionally, it can realize the efficient industrial division of labor and collaboration, improve the efficiency of factor utilization and reduce energy consumption and pollution through synergistic effects [
41]. At the same time, the expansion of the city size provides convenient conditions for industrial spatial agglomeration, which is conducive to large-size and intensive product production, and thus promotes the inclusive development of the urban economy and improves the urban GDE [
53]. Conversely, there may be a critical point in the expansion of the urban size, and once the critical point is exceeded, there is negative externality of the urban size. This negative externality is due to a series of urban diseases that may be brought about by the expansion of the urban size [
54], leading to inefficient urban economic growth, stricter resource constraints and environmental pollution and, therefore, lower urban green economic efficiency. Accordingly, the following hypothesis is proposed.
Hypothesis 3 (H3). The effect of the borrowing size on the urban GDE is constrained by the urban development size, i.e., the expansion of urban development size may expand the positive green effect of the borrowing size, but there is a critical point which, once exceeded, may lead to a decrease in urban GDE.
5. Conclusions and Policy Recommendations
5.1. Conclusions and Discussion
This paper explores the effect of the borrowing size on the urban GDE in a city network and draws the following conclusions. (1) The effect of all three dimensions of the borrowing size on the urban GDE is significantly positive, and the effect of each of the three dimensions of the borrowing size on the urban GDE is significantly positive. This shows that the borrowing size is indeed beneficial to the improvement in the urban GDE, and cities can improve their urban GDE through the borrowing size in the urban network. (2) There is a nonlinear panel threshold effect of the city size between the borrowing size and urban GDE, and the panel threshold effect is a significant double-threshold effect. (3) Under the threshold constraint of the city size, there is a U-shaped relationship between the borrowing population size, borrowing advanced functions and urban GDE, whereas there is an inverted U-shaped relationship between the borrowing economic activity density and urban GDE.
Borrowing size provides a new idea for promoting urban development. Based on panel data of 280 prefecture-level cities in China from 2009 to 2019, this paper explores the impact of borrowing size on urban GDE from the perspective of urban network externality and performs panel threshold regression to quantitatively evaluate the nonlinear relationship between borrowing size and urban GDE using city size as the threshold variable. This paper provides reliable information for promoting urban GDE in China from a new perspective of “borrowing size” through theoretical analysis and empirical research. At the same time, it also provides reference for other countries to study the impact of borrowing size on urban development and enriches the theory related to the impact of borrowing size on urban development.
However, due to the availability of data and the limited level of this research, this paper still has some shortcomings: (1) In terms of theoretical mechanism analysis, this paper has not yet established the corresponding mathematical model from classical theories, but only conducted some qualitative analysis at the theoretical level. (2) In terms of the research object, the positive effect of borrowing size depends on microscopic such as individuals and enterprises. However, the research in this paper does not go deeper into such a micro level. Of course, theoretical analysis often needs to be combined with classical mathematical and theoretical models to make its arguments more rigorous and robust. In the future, it will be necessary to combine macro-city data, micro-enterprise data and meso-industry data on the basis of the combination of theoretical analysis and quantitative models to achieve deep interactive integration on the research scale in order to draw more and more meaningful research conclusions.
5.2. Policy Recommendations
The core argument of this paper is that, in the urban network, an increase in the borrowing size facilitates efficient urban green development. Cities can increase their urban GDE by leveraging the demographic, economic and functional effects of the borrowing size in the urban network. Three important points can be made.
First, it is important to improve the infrastructure of the urban network and the accessibility of urban transportation. Government needs to provide good conditions for infrastructure to support the play of the borrowing size, implement key projects of comprehensive transportation such as highways and railroads to improve the comprehensive transportation network, accelerate communication links between cities and create good conditions for the efficient flow of production factors between cities. Additionally, it is important to actively improve and optimize all kinds of basic hardware and software facilities, upgrade and expand the urban carrying capacity, make up for the shortcomings of urban infrastructure, improve the urban network effect and urban operation efficiency and enhance the comprehensive competitiveness of cities. Second, the city size should be viewed correctly and coordinated development among cities should be pursued. It is important to avoid the crowding effect of the city size resulting from having a few mega or super cities and to reduce the loss of urban GDE resulting from the negative externality of population benefits. To pursue coordinated development among cities, for small and medium-sized cities, the city size should be expanded moderately so as to better utilize the agglomeration effect of the city size and realize the positive population externality effect in promoting GDE. Good use should be made of the radiation effect and diffusion effect of the city size to further improve the urban GDE. Third, from the perspective of the function relationship, a polycentric city network with complementary functions should be constructed. Looking beyond the dispute over the development of large, medium and small cities in China, the starting point for analyzing China’s urban problems is the enhancement of the status of cities as nodes in the urban network and the strengthening of frequent economic activities among cities. It is important to build a polycentric city network with complementary functions and to strive to expand the agglomeration advantage of a single center into a synergistic effect of an inclusive polycentric city network. By integrating into the urban network, each city can realize a borrowing population, advanced functions and economic activity density of the city network based on its advantages, node position and city functions to promote urban GDE.