Next Article in Journal
Prognostic Value of Histone Modifying Enzyme EZH2 in RCHOP-Treated Diffuse Large B-Cell Lymphoma and High Grade B-Cell Lymphoma
Previous Article in Journal
Gut Microbiota Composition across Normal Range Prostate-Specific Antigen Levels
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Review

Equity or Equality? Which Approach Brings More Satisfaction in a Kidney-Exchange Chain?

by
Arian Hosseinzadeh
1,
Mehdi Najafi
1,2,
Wisit Cheungpasitporn
3,*,
Charat Thongprayoon
3 and
Mahdi Fathi
4,*
1
Industrial Engineering Department, Sharif University of Technology, Tehran 1458889694, Iran
2
Ted Rogers School of Management, Ryerson University, Toronto, ON M5G 2C5, Canada
3
Department of Medicine, Mayo Clinic, Rochester, MN 55905, USA
4
Department of Information Technology and Decision Sciences, G. Brint Ryan College of Business, University of North Texas, Denton, TX 76201, USA
*
Authors to whom correspondence should be addressed.
J. Pers. Med. 2021, 11(12), 1383; https://doi.org/10.3390/jpm11121383
Submission received: 13 November 2021 / Revised: 12 December 2021 / Accepted: 14 December 2021 / Published: 18 December 2021

Abstract

:
In United States (U.S.), government-funded organizations, such as NLDAC, reimburse travel and subsistence expenses incurred during living-organ donation process. However, in Iran, there is a non-governmental organization called Iranian Kidney Foundation (IKF) that funds the direct and indirect costs of donors through charitable donations and contributions from participants in the exchange program. In this article, for countries outside the U.S. that currently use an equality approach, we propose a potential new compensation-apportionment approach (equitable approach) for kidney-exchange chains and compare it with the currently available system (equality approach) in terms of the apportionment of compensation in a kidney-exchange chain to cover the expenses incurred by the initiating living donor of the chain in the act of donation. To this end, we propose a mechanism to apportion compensation among all participating pairs based on the equity approach by utilizing a prediction model to calculate the probability of graft survival in each transplant operation. These probabilities are then used to define the utility of any transplantation, considering the quality of each pair’s donated and received kidney in the chain. Afterward, the corresponding cost is apportioned by a mechanism based on the normalized differences between the utility of donated and received kidneys for each incompatible pair of the chain. In summary, we demonstrate that by utilizing the equitable approach, there is more fairness and equity in the allocation of resources in organ-procurement systems, which results in more satisfaction among incompatible pairs. Additional future prospective studies are needed to assess this proposed equitable approach for kidney-exchange chains in countries outside the U.S., such as Iran, that currently use an equality approach.

1. Introduction

The two currently available treatment options for patients with kidney failure are dialysis or kidney transplantation [1]. Although both treatments are used for end-stage kidney disease (ESKD) patients, kidney transplantation results in better survival and quality of life (QOL) [2,3,4]. Therefore, it is not surprising that kidney transplantation is the preferred treatment for ESKD patients. Kidney allografts used for transplant operations can come from deceased donors or living donors [5].
Patients with an incompatible living donor can participate in kidney-exchange programs. Kidney exchange or kidney paired donation (KPD) involves the exchange of kidneys between living donors and recipients so as to facilitate transplantation of incompatible pairs and optimize available resource utilization. Blood group O recipients are often disadvantaged in this process [6,7]. KPD can occur between two incompatible pairs (two-way swap) or through a chain whereby a chain starter, often a non-designated donor, who is a member of blood group O, donates altruistically. This kidney is used to initiate a chain of kidney exchanges between incompatible donor-recipient pairs [8]. This dependency on a living non-designated donor intuitively blunts the transplantation process. In other words, according to the operational aspects of kidney-exchange chains, all patients in the chain have to wait until the authorized entity finds an altruistic donor to initiate the chain.
There are financial barriers for non-designated living donors, despite their altruism. Living donors face both direct and indirect costs for their act of donation. Direct costs are related to transportation, lodging and parking, whereas indirect costs include lost wages, use of paid time off, dependent care expenses and risks to job stability [9,10,11,12,13,14]. Eliminating these financial disincentives may result in an increase in access to living-donor transplantation [9,11,12]. To eliminate these factors, different measures have been taken in different countries. For instance, in United States (U.S.), recipients are allowed to pay for a donor’s travel, housing and lost wages, according to the National Organ Transplant Act of 1984 (NOTA), although this forbids organ purchases [9,14]. To this end, the National Living Donor Assistance Center (NLDAC) was established in 2007 to reimburse travel and subsistence expenses incurred toward living organ donation. Thenceforth, NLDAC has been funded through a federal grant and has supported applicants with significant financial hardship [9,13]. Furthermore, other means have been set up to raise money to cover the costs of living donors. These efforts include bake sales, fundraising events, crowdfunding, etc., [14]. There have been other measures adopted in other countries outside the U.S. For example, in Iran, there is no government-funded program developed to cover the direct and indirect costs associated with donation. However, an organization called the Iranian Kidney Foundation (IKF) has been established that funds donors’ direct and indirect costs through charitable donations and contributions from participants in the exchange program [15,16,17].
Given to the current process of the IKF, the amount of money that should be paid from participants varies under different circumstances. To determine these amounts, the IKF tries to fund a part of compensation, usually about 30%, from the individual donors or organizations once the kidney-exchange chain and the initial donor are identified [18]. The remaining compensation is funded equally by the participants in the chain [15,19]. The equal apportionment of compensation is dissatisfactory for some participants who have better conditions in terms of age, lifestyle and health situation that affect the quality of kidney each pair donates and receives [20]. To overcome this drawback in countries outside U.S. that currently utilize the equality approach, we aim to develop a cost-apportionment mechanism based on equity and to compare its results with the current approach, which based on equality. In other words, we analyze two following approaches:
Equality approach: equality is easily reached by allocating an equal amount of the living donor’s costs to all pairs participating in the exchange plan. We named this approach the equal compensation amount (ECA) approach.
Equitable approach: unlike the ECA approach, this approach is complicated and aims to consider equity in the apportionment of the non-designated donor’s costs among the incompatible pairs in the exchange plan. Regarding the focus of this approach on fairness, it is named the fair compensation amount (FCA) approach.
Regarding these definitions, we aim to develop a mechanism to adopt the FCA approach in compensation apportionment. We also compare the results achieved by this approach with those achieved by the ECA to determine which approach brings more satisfaction to participants in the chain. Note that the developed FCA approach can also be employed in transplantation systems in which government-funded programs have limited funding and cannot cover all expenses of living donors.
The rest of the article is organized as follows: In Section 2, a review of the related literature is presented. Section 3 defines the problem under investigation, presents the assumptions and methodology used in the current study and develops a mechanism to apportion compensation among patients regarding the FCA approach. Section 4 presents numerical examples, investigates the operational characteristics of the proposed mechanism and compares the apportionment results of the FCA and ECA approaches. Finally, conclusions and several recommendations for future research are presented in Section 5.

2. Literature Review

Kidney exchange between incompatible pairs was first proposed in 1986 by Rapaport [21]. The simplest method of KPD is a two-way exchange. This method of kidney exchange was first implemented in 1991 in Korea [22]. Since then, owing to operational innovations, models used in KPD have become considerably more advanced. Three-way and four-way exchanges are examples of other implemented exchange models between incompatible or compatible pairs [23,24].
As mentioned earlier, chain kidney donation is another approach in kidney-exchange programs, which has been widely discussed in living donor availability [8,25,26,27,28,29]. Due to the variations in types of kidney exchange methods and different circumstances in operational exchange programs worldwide, operations research has been utilized to maximize the benefits of these methods [30].
Prediction of future events has been a matter of attention for decades; however, prognostic studies only began to receive adequate attention a few years ago [31]. Prediction models in medicine, especially in the last decade, have been designed to help physicians predict the risk of events in patient-related decision-making processes [32]. The ability to predict graft survival among kidney-transplant recipients is critical in allocating donors to patients since the rate of success in finding compatible donors is always limited. Therefore, many researchers have worked on prediction models for kidney-graft survival, classified into three categories: simulation and operation research, conventional statistics, and data analytic approaches [33]. A known subcategory of conventional statistical studies is the Cox proportional hazards model, a widely used multivariate approach in medical literature to assess survival time, which can be utilized for categorical and numerical types of predictors [34,35,36,37,38]. This model aims to evaluate the effects of several variables/covariates on the rate of a specific event (e.g., graft failure) at a particular point in time.
Regarding the mentioned limitations of kidney-exchange programs, the main contributions of this work are summarized below:
We aim to (1) propose a new equity-based approach to achieve financial neutrality of the initiating non-designated donor in kidney-exchange chains in sharing the direct and indirect costs of the living donor between the participating incompatible pairs that can be considered outside the U.S., and (2) compare two different approaches, ECA and FCA, in terms of apportioning the required compensation among chain participants.
To implement the FCA approach for the apportionment of the participant compensation, we must take the characteristics of all donated and received kidneys in the chain into account. To address this issue, we develop a mathematical mechanism that determines each pair’s share regarding the attributes its donated and received kidneys.
The proposed mechanism determines the probability of graft survival by utilizing multivariate Cox regression survival analysis [20,39], converts it to transplant’s utility and determines the compensation share according to the obtained extra utility as a more equitable attribute for compensation sharing.

3. Problem Definition and Formulation

To define and formulate the problem under investigation, we first describe the problem and list its assumptions. Then, we discuss the methodology and approaches used to apportion compensation among the available pairs in a kidney-exchange chain.

3.1. Problem Definition and Underlying Assumptions

As mentioned in the preceding section, the purpose of this article is to compare ECA and FCA approaches in the operation of apportioning the compensation of external donors who starts a kidney-exchange chain among the participating incompatible pairs and to present a mathematical mechanism for this goal under the FCA approach. The share of the total compensation allocated to each incompatible pair in the chain under the FCA approach must be according to the characteristics to both kidneys being receives and donated to the chain.
To describe the problem, Figure 1 illustrates a kidney-exchange chain with a non-designated living donor, four incompatible pairs and a recipient from the waiting list. Intuitively, several recipients and donors in the chain have different characteristics, such as age, sex, blood type, and body size. Therefore, they need to find a donor whose kidney is compatible with the patient of pair 1. Though all incompatible pairs pay the compensation altogether, they may not have the same payment share due to their variant situation.
Several authors in the literature have discussed the notion of fairness and equity in the allocation of divisible and indivisible goods [40,41,42,43,44]. In general, an allocation is defined as equitable if no agent envies another, i.e., no agent prefers another agent’s bundle to his own. Additionally, an allocation is defined as fair if it is both equitable and Pareto efficient. Therefore, to have a fair allocation, one must minimize envy between agents. In our problem, agents are incompatible pairs in the chain, and bundles are the recipients’ allocated kidneys. Therefore, it is possible that an incompatible pair envies another incompatible pair’s place in the chain if the exchange of places is feasible between those two agents. However, since an optimization model already forms the exchange chain, any exchange of places between its participating pairs will result in less overall transplant quality and, consequently, more overall envy. Therefore, the allocation of places in each chain between participating pairs has the minimum feasible overall envy.
The main question of this article is how this compensation should be apportioned among incompatible pairs to have the minimum overall envy after the operations. To answer this question, this study presents a mathematical mechanism to determine the share of compensation paid by each participating pair under the FCA approach. Then, the results from this mechanism are compared with the apportionment results under the ECA approach. The following major assumptions are considered:
The exchange chain is given in this study. To obtain this chain, one can employ approaches available in the literature [5,45,46]. Therefore, the characteristics of incompatible pairs are known, and there is no limitation for the length of the chain used in the proposed approach.
Living donor’s cost apportionment is carried out to determine the share of each participating pair before the transplantation process.
The chain pairs have been chosen from a predefined pool and do not choose to move to another chain [8]. That is because of two facts: first, they are not aware of the existence of any other chain; second, they are not aware whether the other chain, if available, is more appropriate for them or not.
All donor-recipient participants in the chain program are incompatible, and their orders in the chain have been defined based on the exchange program’s objective. Therefore, an incompatible pair cannot alter its corresponding pair for the kidney exchange [8,25].
It is assumed that all of the transplants in the chain would be performed successfully. In case of failure of the exchange chain due to last-minute failure of a transplant, the total share of subsequent incompatible pairs from the compensation is paid by the organization responsible for organ procurement and transplantation in the system.
The characteristics of the kidney initiating the chain program are known. The amount of compensation that should be paid to the initial donor to cover his costs associated with the donation process is also given, and all participants are informed about and have agreed to this value.
Although the last donor-recipient pair of the chain pays a share of the corresponding patient’s compensation, their donated kidney would be assigned to the first compatible patient on the waiting list.

3.2. Methodology

We compared two different approaches based on equality and equity to determine the share of the compensation for incompatible pairs. If C is the total amount of compensation, n is the number of participating incompatible pairs in the chain and Ci is the portion of compensation allocated to incompatible pair i. In the ECA approach, Ci is easily calculated as follows:
C i = C n   i   1.2 , , n
However, the FCA approach is complicated. To develop this approach, we employ the Shapley value, one of the most prominent ways to allocate gains obtained by a set of players in coalitional cooperative games. The main idea of Shapley value is that members should receive payments or shares proportional to their marginal contributions in a cooperative game [47]. Allocation of costs in a cooperative game is another application of the Shapley value [48,49,50,51]. To employ the Shapley value for the purpose of compensation apportionment in the problem under investigation, the expected marginal contributions of each incompatible pair must be calculated [47]. In other words, compensation apportioning should match the characteristics of the kidney that participants are receiving from the system and the kidney they are donating to the system. For instance, receiving a younger kidney should result in a higher share, or conversely, donating a younger kidney should reduce the pair’s share.
Taking into account all mentioned factors, we calculate the odds of graft survival and determine patients’ share in providing compensation according to these probabilities. To this end, we employ the utility function to capture the nonlinear impact of graft-survival probability on the satisfaction of the pairs. Afterwards, compensation is apportioned among all pairs of the chain, considering their utility to the system. Given Ui is the utility that transplant i brings about the system, the FCA approach is defined as:
C i = f C , u i 1 , u i     i     1.2 , , n
where ui is the utility donated by the ith incompatible pair to the chain and equivalents to the utility of the ith transplant, estimated based on the system administrator’s preferences as the entity responsible for matching donors and patients. In addition, ui−1 indicates the amount of utility received by incompatible pair i and, similarly, equals the utility of transplantation i−1. Accordingly, u0 indicates the utility of the initiating transplantation of the chain.
Note that each transplant has a utility value for the social planner, e.g., the IKF, aiming to maximize the number of patients receiving a kidney in the exchange program. Since Equation (2) takes the condition of both received and donated kidneys into account, it diminishes total envy between participants and consequently increases fairness.
Utility theory has been proposed by Von Neumann and Morgenstern [52] to measure a decision maker’s preferences in a mathematical form. To apply this theory, a function known as a utility function can generally be estimated to calculate a decision maker’s preferences between various choices in a decision-making problem [53]. According to this theory, if the decision maker prefers choice A to other choices, the utility of choice A must be higher than that of other choices [52]. In addition, another characteristic of the corresponding utility function is monotonicity. A monotonically increasing utility function means that the decision maker prefers higher values of an attribute.
Conversely, the decision maker prefers lower values of an attribute if the utility function is monotonically decreasing. With a non-monotonic utility function, the decision maker’s preferences concerning different attribute levels may increase or decrease [53]. Risk aversion is a characteristic of the decision maker that can be inferred from the utility function. In general, a decision maker is risk-averse if and only if his/her utility function is concave. On the contrary, risk-prone decision makers have convex utility functions [53]. Utility theory has been widely used in healthcare problems, such as measuring patients’ quality of life based on their condition [54,55,56] and measuring quality of life for ESKD patients on dialysis [57].
To estimate the utility of a transplant, different characteristics of the recipient and the donor must be considered. Therefore, rather than directly estimating the utility function based on these attributes, we propose using these attributes to estimate the probability of graft survival and then defining each transplant’s utility based on its graft-survival probability. In this article, the likelihood of graft survival is estimated by a calculator based on the multivariate Cox regression survival analysis presented in [20]. This calculator, called the kidney graft survival calculator (KGSC), developed based on 15 years of United States transplantation data from the Scientific Registry of Transplant Recipients (SRTR), can estimate the probability of graft survival 5 and 10 years post-transplant. It takes into account several attributes of donors and recipients, such as age, sex and body size. It also considers the type of the living donor (related/unrelated), number of HLA ABDR mismatches, ABO compatibility between donor and recipient, donor and recipient race, donor’s history of cigarette use, transplant year, recipient’s panel reactive antibody (PRA), time on dialysis, insurance type, history of previous transplants and recipient’s diabetes status the potential impact of these factors on the probability of graft survival. Regarding the variant of attributes utilized in this calculator and its ability to estimate the likelihood of graft survival for transplants with living donors [20], we chose KGSC in our proposed equitable-cost-apportionment mechanism. Additionally, we established our mechanism based on the probability of graft survival 10 years after transplant, since this period is frequently considered and used in graft-survival predictions and evaluations in the literature [20,58,59,60,61].
As mentioned, converting the graft-survival probability to the transplant’s utility requires definition of a utility function. This study estimated this function using the standard gamble (SG) technique [62] on the data gathered from 10 selected experienced experts of the Iranian Kidney Foundation who are in charge of the matching process in Tehran, Iran. To utilize this technique, we designed an interview structure and asked these experts to state their preferences of different probability levels of graft survival. According to this structure, presented in Figure 2, each interviewee was subjected to seven sets of lotteries in three stages. In each lottery, based on the SG technique, the participant was asked to imagine a situation where they had two alternatives to assign an unknown kidney to a recipient. The first alternative was participating in a gamble in which the graft-survival probability after transplant was one of two known values with a 50-50 chance. The second alternative was undergoing the transplant with a different fixed value of graft-survival probability. After knowing the graft-survival probability values of the two probable outcomes of the first alternative in each lottery, the respondents were asked to declare the minimum probability of graft survival they would still prefer as the second alternative rather than the first alternative. The utility of the declared value is the average of utilities of the outcomes of the first alternative. As presented in the Appendix A, for simplicity, the participants were asked to declare this value as a number multiple of 5%. After calculating the utility of the declared value of survival probability, by replacing the gamble outcomes one by one with this value, two different lotteries of the next stage were designed. After receiving each of the interviewees’ responses to all seven lotteries, the average probabilities of graft survival in each level of utility were estimated. It is worth mentioning that since the utility values are defined in the interval between 0 and 1, we could not increase the number of the independent values extracted from the participants, so calculation of utility function was based on these values.

3.3. Mechanisms of Compensation Apportionment

As Equation (1) shows, the ECA approach apportions the identified compensation among all participants equally. However, the mechanism proposed under the FCA approach aims to apportion compensation among all participants regarding the characteristics of both kidneys they will receive and donate. These characteristics can be represented by the amount of utility provided for each participant. Due to the impacts of transplantation failure on the recipient’s quality of life and length of the waiting list, a kidney’s survival probability in the recipient’s body is usually considered the main factor in patient-utility estimation [63]. According to this factor and based on our interview structure, presented in Section 3.2, the utility values of transplants and the corresponding values of graft-survival probability were obtained from the interviewees. Utility values of 0.0% and 100.0% survival probability were assumed at 0.0 and 1.0, respectively, to initiate the interview process. The results of these interviews are presented in the Appendix A. In addition, the average results of the interviews are shown in Table 1. Based on these results, Figure 3 illustrates the relationship between the probability of graft survival and transplant utility. As this figure shows, the obtained utility function is monotonically increasing and concave, demonstrating that decision makers are risk-averse [53].
Regarding the collected data, provided in the Appendix A and presented in Table 1 and Figure 3, and the characteristics of the utility function being appropriate to capture this behavior [52], transplant’s utility function is estimated as follow:
U = 1.32077 1.32847 × exp 1.46741 × T
where U is the estimated utility of the transplant and T is the probability of graft survival 10 years after transplantation.
Although the acquired utility function helps us estimate any transplantation utility, it could not be directly utilized to determine the share of an incompatible pair. Each pair grants an amount of utility to the chain and receives another amount from the chain. Therefore, the difference between the granted and the received utilities should be considered as an index to determine the share of compensation. To this end, let us assume that n is the number of incompatible pairs, Δ u i is the difference between the granted and the received utilities for incompatible pair i, that is the net utility, and be calculated as follows:
Δ u i = u i 1 u i   i   1.2 , , n
To avoid a negative value of Δu and to keep the share of incompatible pairs non-negative, Equation (4) is normalized as follows:
Δ u i = Δ u i + m i n j Δ u j j   1.2 , , n   i f   m i n j Δ u j < 0 Δ u i j   1.2 , , n   i f   m i n j Δ u j 0
In this Equation Δ u i is the normalized value of the net utility of incompatible pair i. Regarding Equation (5), an incompatible pair pays more portion of compensation if it has a higher value of normalized net utility. Therefore, each pair’s percentage of total compensation is calculated as follows:
C i = C n i f   i Δ u i = 0 C Δ u i i Δ u i i f   i Δ u i > 0   i   1.2 , , n
where Ci is the portion of the compensation allocated to incompatible pair i and C is the total amount of compensation that should be paid to the external donor. It is worth mentioning that if all pairs receive the same utility, the total normalized net utility would be zero. In this case, all pairs should pay an equal portion of the total compensation. Conversely, if the pairs receive variant normalized net utility, they would pay a different portion of the total compensation that could be obtained by Equation (6). Additionally, according to this Equation, the incompatible pair with the lowest Δu value does not pay any share of the compensation if its respective Δ u 0 .

4. Comparing Equity and Equality Approaches

To compare the results of cost apportionment under ECA and FCA approaches, first, we must evaluate the validity of our proposed cost-apportionment mechanism under the FCA approach. Therefore, Section 4.1 includes investigations of two different scenarios as a numerical study to this end. Then, in Section 4.2, we implement the comparison by utilizing a simulation model.

4.1. Numerical Study

To analyze the properties of the developed mechanism, we investigate two different scenarios of an operational kidney-exchange chain and discuss how the chain’s attribution mechanism and the amount of total compensation affect the compensation portion each participating incompatible pair should pay. The first scenario assumes four incompatible pairs (i.e., five kidney transplantations) with different characteristics available in the kidney-exchange chain. A woman with a high BMI (body mass index) in the age range of 50–59 donates her kidney to the exchange chain. Besides, the total compensation for this donation is considered $5000.
The latter scenario also includes four incompatible pairs similar to those in the former scenario. However, the external donor is a man with a healthy BMI and in the age range of <30. In addition, the living donor’s total cost in this scenario is set to $5500. Table 2 presents all required characteristics of transplants for estimating the probability of graft survival. As previously mentioned, the donor of transplant 1 is the external donor of the chain, and the recipient of transplant 5 is a patient from the waiting list. Additionally, the structure of the data in Table 2 is similar to that presented in [20].
Considering the data presented in Table 2 and the proposed mechanism, the probability of graft survival after 10 years and the corresponding utility of each transplantation are calculated and shown in Table 3. As shown in Table 3, the better characteristics of the external donor in scenario 2 lead to an increase of 6.3% in the probability of graft survival and 0.06 in the utility of the first transplantation. Since the amount of utility for the remaining transplantations is unchanged, the share of the total compensation assigned to the first incompatible pair in scenario 2 is expected to be higher than in scenario 1. Table 4 and Table 5, respectively, present the share of each incompatible pair in scenarios 1 and 2.
As the results show, incompatible pair 2 is not supposed to pay any portion of the compensation since it has the minimum negative net utility in both scenarios. In addition, a significant part of the compensation is assigned to incompatible pair 3 due to the positive value of its net utility. Furthermore, the obtained result shows that finding a non-designated living donor who increases the graft-survival probability in the first transplantation certainly increases the share of the first incompatible pair and decreases the share of other participants, except for those pairs whose shares are zero.

4.2. Numerical Analysis

In this section, intending to assess the functionality of the mechanism under the FCA approach and compare its results with the apportionment scenario under the ECA approach, we implement 1000 rounds of simulations of kidney-exchange chains. Through this process, each pair’s share of the compensation and the outcome of each transplant operation 10 years after the procedure is determined. All of the characteristics of transplants in the chains are generated using uniform distributions within their parameter ranges specified by the KGSC [20]. We perform a total of 1000 simulations, each representing a chain that contains 6–10 incompatible pairs. Additionally, the amount of compensation is set to $5000 for all of the chains. Figure 4 represents the frequency distribution of different chain lengths in our simulation.
Accordingly, these 1000 kidney-exchange chains include 8920 transplants in total, with random characteristics. According to our mechanism based on the FCA approach, the 10-year probability of graft survival and the utility value can be estimated for each of these transplants; Figure 5 and Figure 6 illustrate the distribution of these values for our total number of transplants, respectively.
Furthermore, Table 6 shows the frequency of each possible outcome for 8920 transplants derived from the simulation process. According to this table, 55.7% of transplants in our analysis did not survive for 10 years after transplantation.
The final results of the simulation process are presented in Table 7. As shown in this table, cost apportionment is implemented based on the FCA and ECA approaches. The former utilizes our proposed cost-apportionment mechanism to determine the share of each participant of the total compensation. The latter determines the share of participants by dividing the compensation equally among them. Additionally, there are two possible outcomes for each transplant after 10 years: graft survival or graft failure. Therefore, there are two possible outcomes for the received transplants of each incompatible pair. Table 7 includes the cost-apportionment results derived from the simulation process for these two possible outcomes by utilizing two approaches.
As previously mentioned, we aim to compare the results of cost apportionment based on two different approaches, ECA and FCA. In this regard, the functionality of these approaches must be assessed in the simulation results. As in Table 7, the total share of compensation for participants who received a kidney that survived 10 years after the transplant is determined to be 52% of the total compensation via the FCA approach and 44% via the ECA approach. Additionally, the average compensation contribution for these pairs is defined as $740 via the FCA approach and $629 via the ECA approach. In the results of the FCA approach, incompatible pairs that received successful transplants pay a higher amount of money than the according to the results of the ECA approach. On the other hand, the total share of compensation for incompatible pairs that received a kidney that did not survive is determined to be 48% of the total compensation via the FCA approach and 56% via the ECA approach. Additionally, the average compensation contribution for these pairs is determined to $545 via the FCA approach and $633 via the ECA approach. Thus, in the results obtained from the FCA approach, incompatible pairs that received unsuccessful transplants pay a lower amount of money than according to the results of the ECA approach. In addition, 767 of these incompatible pairs did not pay any amount of money by using the cost-apportionment mechanism based on the FCA approach, compared to the other outcome, in which only 233 participants did not pay. Generally, by analyzing the results obtained from the ECA and FCA approaches, it can be inferred that our proposed cost-apportionment mechanism seems to function in alignment with the goal of the FCA approach, which is moving towards more fairness and equity in the allocation of costs and resources in organ-procurement systems.

5. Conclusions and Future Research

In current renal-transplantation systems, living donors face financial burdens related to their act of donation, which can act as disincentives to donate. These financial burdens include transportation costs, lodging and parking costs, lost wages, etc. In many transplantation systems in other countries outside the U.S., such as Iran, organizations and governmental funds cannot cover these expenses. In these situations, compensation of the initiating living donors of kidney-exchange chains may potentially be paid by the participating pairs in the chains. We proposed the apportionment of the compensation of the initiating living donor in kidney-exchange chains between incompatible pairs of the chain based on the notion of equity, and compared its final results to those derived from the equality approach.
To achieve this goal, this study developed a new mechanism employing the kidney chain of exchanges and utility function to apportion compensation among participating incompatible pairs based on the FCA approach. The proposed mechanism considers all donor and recipient characteristics in the chain and attempts to determine a compensation ratio according to the utility value of pairs. According to this mechanism, the amount of compensation allocated to incompatible pairs increases as they receive a better-matched kidney, and their share decreases as they donate a better-matched kidney.
Furthermore, in comparison with dividing compensation equally between all participating pairs according to the ECA approach, the apportionment of total compensation between incompatible pairs by the proposed mechanism based on the FCA approach results in a decrease in total envy between the agents and an increase in fairness of the apportionment model. The reason for this is that by utilizing our mechanism, the apportioned share of compensation to agents with better bundles will be higher than that of other agents. Therefore, the amount of envy in their bundles will be lower. Thus, it can be concluded that by utilizing the FCA approach, we are moving towards more fairness and equity in the allocation of resources in organ-procurement systems, which results in more satisfaction among incompatible pairs.
It is worth mentioning that in the proposed mechanism, each transplant’s utility is calculated solely based on the probability of graft survival post-transplantation. It does not investigate other factors, such as patient health status, affordability, etc. In addition, this FCA approach is not developed for the U.S.; instead, it is mainly intended for other countries that currently use an equality approach, such as Iran, and we do not endorse the use of this FCA approach in the U.S.
The following are suggestions of topics that future research could investigate to improve the concept we presented in this research:
Developing a multi-attribute utility function to capture other factors, such as affordability and survival probability, is another research line for future studies in the FCA approach. As mentioned, the current research assumes that the main factor determining utility is graft-survival probability. Although this factor is the most effective, other factors, such as affordability, the recipient’s health condition and PRA and the expected time for recipients to reach the top of the waiting, list may affect the recipient’s utility.
Implementation of the FCA approach in the apportionment of compensation, assessing the potential increase in the number of kidney-exchange chains and the satisfaction level of participating incompatible pairs in these chains.
In summary, we demonstrated that by utilizing the equitable approach, there is more fairness and equity in the allocation of resources in organ-procurement systems, which results in more satisfaction among incompatible pairs. Additional future prospective studies are needed to assess this proposed equitable approach for kidney-exchange chains in countries outside the U.S., such as Iran, that currently use an equality approach.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, M.N. and A.H.; methodology, A.H., M.N. and M.F.; software, A.H. and M.F.; validation, M.N., M.F. and W.C.; formal analysis, A.H.; investigation, A.H.; resources, A.H. and M.F.; data curation, A.H. and M.F.; writing—original draft preparation, A.H., M.N. and M.F.; writing—review and editing, W.C. and C.T.; visualization, A.H.; supervision, M.N.; project administration, M.N. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A

The data extracted from the decision makers using the SG method is presented in the table below.
Table A1. Reference Data for Utility Function.
Table A1. Reference Data for Utility Function.
Probability of Graft Survival (10 Years Post Transplant) Extracted from Participants Average Probability of Graft Survival (10 Years Post Transplant) Utility
12345678910
0%0%0%0%0%0%0%0%0%0%0.0%0.0%
10%10%10%5%5%5%5%5%5%5%6.5%12.5%
25%20%20%10%15%20%10%15%15%10%16.0%25.0%
35%25%35%15%20%30%15%20%30%15%24.0%37.5%
45%35%45%25%30%40%30%30%40%30%35.0%50.0%
60%45%55%30%35%45%35%35%45%35%42.0%62.5%
70%60%65%40%45%55%40%50%65%60%55.0%75.0%
85%75%80%60%65%80%65%65%85%70%73.0%87.5%
100%100%100%100%100%100%100%100%100%100%100.0%100.0%
By using asymptotic regression, the utility function based on the data presented above is constructed as follows:
Utility = 1.32077 − 1.32847 × exp(−1.46741 × ‘Average Probability of Kidney Survival’)

References

  1. Levey, A.S.; Coresh, J.; Balk, E.; Kausz, A.T.; Levin, A.; Steffes, M.W.; Hogg, R.J.; Perrone, R.D.; Lau, J.; Eknoyan, G. National Kidney Foundation Practice Guidelines for Chronic Kidney Disease: Evaluation, Classification, and Stratification. Ann. Intern. Med. 2003, 139, 137–147. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  2. Ogutmen, B.; Yildirim, A.; Sever, M.; Bozfakioglu, S.; Ataman, R.; Erek, E.; Cetin, O.; Emel, A. Health-Related Quality of Life After Kidney Transplantation in Comparison Intermittent Hemodialysis, Peritoneal Dialysis, and Normal Controls. Transplant. Proc. 2006, 38, 419–421. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Wolfe, R.A.; Ashby, V.B.; Milford, E.L.; Ojo, A.O.; Ettenger, R.E.; Agodoa, L.Y.C.; Held, P.J.; Port, F.K. Comparison of Mortality in All Patients on Dialysis, Patients on Dialysis Awaiting Transplantation, and Recipients of a First Cadaveric Transplant. N. Engl. J. Med. 1999, 341, 1725–1730. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
  4. Oniscu, G.C.; Brown, H.; Forsythe, J.L. Impact of Cadaveric Renal Transplantation on Survival in Patients Listed for Transplantation. J. Am. Soc. Nephrol. 2005, 16, 1859–1865. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  5. Roth, A.E.; Sönmez, T.; Ünver, M.U. “Kidney Exchange”. Q. J. Econ. 2004, 119, 457–488. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  6. Ross, L.F.; Woodle, E.S. Ethical issues in increasing living kidney donations by expanding kidney paired exchange programs. Transplantation 2000, 69, 1539–1543. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  7. Zenios, S.A.; Woodle, E.S.; Ross, L.F. Primum non nocere: Avoiding harm to vulnerable wait list candidates in an indirect kidney exchange. Transplantation 2001, 72, 648–654. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  8. Roth, A.E.; Sönmez, T.; Ünver, M.U.; Delmonico, F.L.; Saidman, S.L. Utilizing List Exchange and Nondirected Donation through ‘Chain’ Paired Kidney Donations. Am. J. Transplant. 2006, 6, 2694–2705. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  9. Mathur, A.K.; Lewis, Z.A.S.; Warren, P.H.; Walters, M.; Gifford, K.A.; Xing, J.; Goodrich, N.; Bennett, R.; Brownson, A.; Ellefson, J.; et al. Best practices to optimize utilization of the National Living Donor Assistance Center for the financial assistance of living organ donors. Arab. Archaeol. Epigr. 2019, 20, 25–33. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Rodrigue, J.R.; Schold, J.D.; Morrissey, P.; Whiting, J.; Vella, J.; Kayler, L.K.; Katz, D.; Jones, J.; Kaplan, B.; Fleishman, A.; et al. Direct and Indirect Costs Following Living Kidney Donation: Findings From the KDOC Study. Arab. Archaeol. Epigr. 2016, 16, 869–876. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
  11. Mittelman, M.; Bertha, R.; Sutha, K. Challenges, Innovations, and Next Steps in Achieving Financial Neutrality for Living Donors. Curr. Transplant. Rep. 2020, 7, 215–222. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Maghen, A.; Mendoza, G.; Vargas, G.B.; Connor, S.E.; Nassiri, S.; Kwan, L.; Wood, E.L.; Lalezari, J.; Friedman, S.; Waterman, A.D.; et al. How Can We Help Alleviate the Financial Concerns of Non-Directed (Altruistic) Living Kidney Donors? Prog. Transplant. 2021, 31, 19–26. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Rudow, D.L.; Cohen, D. Practical Approaches to Mitigating Economic Barriers to Living Kidney Donation for Patients and Programs. Curr. Transplant. Rep. 2017, 4, 24–31. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Mittelman, M.; Thiessen, C.; Chon, W.J.; Clayville, K.; Cronin, D.C.; Fisher, J.S.; Fry-Revere, S.; Gross, J.A.; Hanneman, J.; Henderson, M.L.; et al. Miscommunicating NOTA Can Be Costly to Living Donors. Arab. Archaeol. Epigr. 2016, 17, 578–580. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
  15. Kidney Foundation of Iran. Available online: http://www.irankf.com/ (accessed on 10 September 2021).
  16. Ghods, A.J.; Savaj, S. Iranian Model of Paid and Regulated Living-Unrelated Kidney Donation. Clin. J. Am. Soc. Nephrol. 2006, 1, 1136–1145. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
  17. Mahdavi-Mazdeh, M. The Iranian model of living renal transplantation. Kidney Int. 2012, 82, 627–634. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  18. Iranian Model of Kidney Transplantation; The Only Solution to a Global Crisis. Available online: http://www.irankf.com/ (accessed on 10 September 2021).
  19. Introduction to Living Kidney Transplantation. Available online: http://www.irankf.com/ (accessed on 10 September 2021).
  20. Ashby, V.B.; Leichtman, A.B.; Rees, M.A.; Song, P.X.-K.; Bray, M.; Wang, W.; Kalbfleisch, J.D. A Kidney Graft Survival Calculator that Accounts for Mismatches in Age, Sex, HLA, and Body Size. Clin. J. Am. Soc. Nephrol. 2017, 12, 1148–1160. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
  21. Rapaport, F.T. The case for a living emotionally related international kidney donor exchange registry. Transplant. Proc. 1986, 18 (Suppl. 2), 5–9. [Google Scholar] [PubMed]
  22. Kwak, J.; Kwon, O.; Lee, K.; Kang, C.; Park, H.; Kim, J. Exchange-donor program in renal transplantation: A single-center experience. Transplant. Proc. 1999, 31, 344–345. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Lucan, M. Five Years of Single-Center Experience with Paired Kidney Exchange Transplantation. Transplant. Proc. 2007, 39, 1371–1375. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  24. Kaçar, S.H.; Eroglu, A.; Tilif, S.; Guven, B.; Kadıoğlu, Z.O. A Novel Experience in Living Donor Renal Transplantation: Voluntary Exchange Kidney Transplantation. Transplant. Proc. 2013, 45, 2106–2110. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Roodnat, J.W.; Zuidema, J.; van de Wetering, M.; de Klerk, M.; Erdman, R.A.M.; Massey, K.E.; Hilhorst, M.; Ijzermans, J.; Weimar, W. Altruistic donor triggered domino-paired kidney donation for unsuccessful couples from the kidney-exchange program. Am. J. Transplant. 2010, 10, 821–827. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Montgomery, R.A.; Gentry, S.; Marks, W.H.; Warren, D.S.; Hiller, J.; Houp, J.; Zachary, A.A.; Melancon, J.K.; Maley, W.R.; Rabb, H.; et al. Domino paired kidney donation: A strategy to make best use of live non-directed donation. Lancet 2006, 368, 419–421. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  27. Ashlagi, I.; Gilchrist, D.S.; Roth, A.E.; Rees, M.A. Nonsimultaneous Chains and Dominos in Kidney-Paired Donation—Revisited. Am. J. Transplant. 2011, 11, 984–994. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
  28. Gentry, S.E.; Montgomery, R.A.; Swihart, B.J.; Segev, D.L. The Roles of Dominos and Nonsimultaneous Chains in Kidney Paired Donation. Am. J. Transplant. 2009, 9, 1330–1336. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  29. Melcher, M.L.; Roberts, J.P.; Leichtman, A.B.; Roth, A.E.; Rees, M.A. Utilization of Deceased Donor Kidneys to Initiate Living Donor Chains. Am. J. Transplant. 2016, 16, 1367–1370. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
  30. Fathi, M.; Khakifirooz, M. Kidney-related operations research: A review. IISE Trans. Heal. Syst. Eng. 2019, 9, 226–242. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Moons, K.G.M.; Royston, P.; Vergouwe, Y.; Grobbee, D.E.; Altman, D.G. Prognosis and prognostic research: What, why, and how? BMJ 2009, 338, b375. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  32. Steyerberg, E.W. Clinical Prediction Models: A Practical Approach to Development, Validation, and Updating; Springer Science & Business Media: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 2008. [Google Scholar]
  33. Topuz, K.; Zengul, F.D.; Dag, A.; Almehmi, A.; Yildirim, M.B. Predicting graft survival among kidney transplant recipients: A Bayesian decision support model. Decis. Support Syst. 2018, 106, 97–109. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Isaacs, R.B.; Nock, S.L.; Spencer, C.E.; Connors, A.F.; Wang, X.-Q.; Sawyer, R.; Lobo, P.I. Racial disparities in renal transplant outcomes. Am. J. Kidney Dis. 1999, 34, 706–712. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Rabbat, C.G.; Thorpe, K.E.; Russell, J.D.; Churchill, D.N. Comparison of mortality risk for dialysis patients and cadaveric first renal transplant recipients in Ontario, Canada. J. Am. Soc. Nephrol. 2000, 11, 917–922. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Williams, R.C.; Opelz, G.; McGarvey, C.J.; Weil, E.J.; Chakkera, H.A. The Risk of Transplant Failure with HLA Mismatch in First Adult Kidney Allografts From Deceased Donors. Transplantation 2016, 100, 1094–1102. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Sapir-Pichhadze, R.; Pintilie, M.; Tinckam, K.J.; Laupacis, A.; Logan, A.G.; Beyene, J.; Kim, S.J. Survival Analysis in the Presence of Competing Risks: The Example of Waitlisted Kidney Transplant Candidates. Am. J. Transplant. 2016, 16, 1958–1966. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  38. Bradburn, M.J.; Clark, T.G.; Love, S.; Altman, D. Survival analysis part II: Multivariate data analysis—An introduction to concepts and methods. Br. J. Cancer 2003, 89, 431. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Kalbfleisch, J.D.; Prentice, R.L. The Statistical Analysis of Failure Time Data; John Wiley & Sons: Hoboken, NJ, USA, 2011. [Google Scholar]
  40. Foley, D.K. Resource Allocation and the Public Sector. Yale Econ. Essays 1967, 7, 45–98. [Google Scholar]
  41. Varian, H.R. Equity, envy, and efficiency. J. Econ. Theory 1973, 9, 63–91. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  42. Feldman, A.; Kirman, A. Fairness and envy. Am. Econ. Rev. 1974, 64, 995–1005. [Google Scholar]
  43. Alkan, A.; Demange, G.; Gale, D. Fair Allocation of Indivisible Goods and Criteria of Justice. Econ. 1991, 59, 1023. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Maskin, E.S. On the Fair Allocation of Indivisible Goods. In Arrow and the Foundations of the Theory of Economic Policy; Springer: Singapore, 1987; pp. 341–349. [Google Scholar]
  45. Sönmez, T.; Ünver, M.U. Matching, Allocation, and Exchange of Discrete Resources. In Handbook of Social Economics; Elsevier: Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 2011; Volume 1, pp. 781–852. [Google Scholar]
  46. Anderson, R.; Ashlagi, I.; Gamarnik, D.; Roth, A.E. Finding long chains in kidney exchange using the traveling salesman problem. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2015, 112, 663–668. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
  47. Winter, E. The shapley value. In Handbook of Game Theory with Economic Applications; Elsevier: Amsterdam, The Nethelands, 2002; Volume 3, pp. 2025–2054. [Google Scholar]
  48. Chen, R.R.; Yin, S. The equivalence of uniform and Shapley value-based cost allocations in a specific game. Oper. Res. Lett. 2010, 38, 539–544. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Littlechild, S.C.; Owen, G. A Simple Expression for the Shapley Value in a Special Case. Manag. Sci. 1973, 20, 370–372. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Young, H.P. Cost allocation. In Handbook of Game Theory with Economic Applications; Elsevier: Amsterdam, The Nethelands, 1994; Volume 2, pp. 1193–1235. [Google Scholar]
  51. Fragnelli, V.; García-Jurado, I.; Norde, H.; Patrone, F.; Tijs, S. How to share railways infrastructure costs. In Game Practice: Contributions from Applied Game Theory; Springer: Berlin/Heildeberg, Germany, 2000; pp. 91–101. [Google Scholar]
  52. Morgenstern, O.; von Neumann, J. Theory of Games and Economic Behavior; Princeton university press: Princeton, NJ, USA, 1953. [Google Scholar]
  53. Keeney, R.L.; Raiffa, H.; Meyer, R.F. Decisions with Multiple Objectives: Preferences and Value Trade-Offs; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 1993. [Google Scholar]
  54. Hawthorne, G.; Richardson, J.; Day, N. A Comparison of Five Multi Attribute Utility Instruments. Aust. Stud. Health Serv. Adm. 2001, 89, 151–179. [Google Scholar]
  55. Feeny, D.; Furlong, W.; Torrance, G.W.; Goldsmith, C.H.; Zhu, Z.; Depauw, S.; Denton, M.; Boyle, M. Multiattribute and Single-Attribute Utility Functions for the Health Utilities Index Mark 3 System. Med. Care 2002, 40, 113–128. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Torrance, G.W.; Feeny, D.H.; Furlong, W.J.; Barr, R.D.; Zhang, Y.; Wang, Q. Multiattribute Utility Function for a Comprehensive Health Status Classification System. Med. Care 1996, 34, 702–722. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Hays, R.D.; Kallich, J.D.; Mapes, D.L.; Coons, S.J.; Carter, W.B. Development of the kidney disease quality of life (KDQOL TM) instrument. Qual. Life Res. 1994, 3, 329–338. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Cecka, J.M. Kidney transplantation in the United States. Clin. Transpl. 2008, 1–18. [Google Scholar]
  59. Matas, A.J.; Gillingham, K.J.; Humar, A.; Kandaswamy, R.; Sutherland, D.E.R.; Payne, W.D.; Dunn, T.B.; Najarian, J.S. 2202 Kidney Transplant Recipients with 10 Years of Graft Function: What Happens Next? Am. J. Transplant. 2008, 8, 2410–2419. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  60. Takiff, H.; Cook, D.J.; Himaya, N.S.; Mickey, M.R.; Terasaki, P.I. Dominant effect of histocompatibility on ten-year kidney transplant survival. Transplantation 1988, 45, 410–414. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Akioka, K.; Takahara, S.; Ichikawa, S.; Yoshimura, N.; Akiyama, T.; Ohshima, S. Factors Predicting Long-term Graft Survival after Kidney Transplantation: Multicenter Study in Japan. World J. Surg. 2005, 29, 249–256. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  62. Gafni, A. The standard gamble method: What is being measured and how it is interpreted. Heal. Serv. Res. 1994, 29, 207–224. [Google Scholar]
  63. Massie, A.B.; Leanza, J.; Fahmy, L.M.; Chow, E.; Desai, N.M.; Luo, X.; King, E.A.; Bowring, M.; Segev, D.L. A Risk Index for Living Donor Kidney Transplantation. Am. J. Transplant. 2016, 16, 2077–2084. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
Figure 1. An illustrative statement of the problem under investigation. A kidney-exchange chain with one initiating living donor, four incompatible pairs and a waiting-list recipient. Each incompatible pair makes a payment to the organ-procurement organization, and the total compensation is paid to the initiating donor.
Figure 1. An illustrative statement of the problem under investigation. A kidney-exchange chain with one initiating living donor, four incompatible pairs and a waiting-list recipient. Each incompatible pair makes a payment to the organ-procurement organization, and the total compensation is paid to the initiating donor.
Jpm 11 01383 g001
Figure 2. Interview structure based on SG technique. SG, standard gamble.
Figure 2. Interview structure based on SG technique. SG, standard gamble.
Jpm 11 01383 g002
Figure 3. Relationship between probability of graft survival and utility of transplant.
Figure 3. Relationship between probability of graft survival and utility of transplant.
Jpm 11 01383 g003
Figure 4. Frequency distribution of chain lengths.
Figure 4. Frequency distribution of chain lengths.
Jpm 11 01383 g004
Figure 5. Frequency distribution of 10-year graft-survival probability.
Figure 5. Frequency distribution of 10-year graft-survival probability.
Jpm 11 01383 g005
Figure 6. Frequency distribution of utility values.
Figure 6. Frequency distribution of utility values.
Jpm 11 01383 g006
Table 1. Average results of the interviews based on SG technique. SG, standard gamble.
Table 1. Average results of the interviews based on SG technique. SG, standard gamble.
Stage123
Lottery1234567
10-Year Survival Probability35.0%16.0%55.0%6.5%24.0%42.0%73.0%
Utility0.5000.2500.7500.1250.3750.6250.875
Table 2. Characteristics of transplants in the chain in scenarios 1 & 2. HLA, human leukocyte antigen. MM, mismatch. BMI, body mass index. PRA, panel reactive antibody.
Table 2. Characteristics of transplants in the chain in scenarios 1 & 2. HLA, human leukocyte antigen. MM, mismatch. BMI, body mass index. PRA, panel reactive antibody.
CharacteristicsTransplant 1 Scenario 1Transplant 1 Scenario 2Transplant 2Transplant 3Transplant 4Transplant 5
Living-donor TypeUnrelatedUnrelatedUnrelatedUnrelatedUnrelatedUnrelated
Recipient Age18–2918–2918–2930–3918–2950–59
Donor Age50–59<3030–3940–49<30<30
Donor-Recipient TypeF-MM-MM-MM-FF-FM-M
HLA ABDR MM1–2 HLA, Any DR1–2 HLA, Any DR1–2 HLA, 0 DR0 HLA0 HLA1–2 HLA, 0 DR
Recipient BMINot Obese (<30)Not Obese (<30)Not Obese (<30)Not Obese (<30)Obese (>30)Not Obese (<30)
Donor BMIObese (>30)Not Obese (<30)Not Obese (<30)Not Obese (<30)Not Obese (<30)Not Obese (<30)
Donor-Recipient Weight Ratio>1.150.90–1.150.90–1.150.90–1.150.90–1.150.75–0.90
Donor-Recipient Height Ratio1.00–1.061.00–1.061.00–1.061.00–1.061.00–1.060.94–1.00
Recipient RaceWhiteWhiteWhiteWhiteWhiteWhite
Donor RaceNot Black or HispanicNot Black or HispanicNot Black or HispanicNot Black or HispanicNot Black or HispanicNot Black or Hispanic
Donor History of Cigarette UseNoNoNoNoYesNo
ABO CompatibilityNot IncompatibleNot IncompatibleNot IncompatibleNot IncompatibleNot IncompatibleNot Incompatible
PRA0–90–910–790–90–90–9
Recipient DiagnosisNot DiabetesNot DiabetesNot DiabetesNot DiabetesNot DiabetesNot Diabetes
Previous TransplantNoNoNoNoNoNo
Time on Dialysis1–2 Years1–2 Years0–1 Years3+ Years0–1 Years2–3 Years
Recipient Hepatitis C SerologyNegative or MissingNegative or MissingNegative or MissingNegative or MissingNegative or MissingNegative or Missing
Recipient InsurancePublic Primary PayerPublic Primary PayerPublic Primary PayerPublic Primary PayerPublic Primary PayerPublic Primary Payer
Transplant Year2008–20122008–20122008–20122008–20122008–20122008–2012
Table 3. Survival probability and utility of transplants in the chain in scenarios 1 and 2.
Table 3. Survival probability and utility of transplants in the chain in scenarios 1 and 2.
Survival Pr. and Utility of TransplantsTransplant 1Transplant 2Transplant 3Transplant 4Transplant 5
Scenario 110-Year Survival Probability46.20%55.40%73.70%57.40%64.80%
Estimated Utility0.650.730.870.750.81
Scenario 210-Year Survival Probability52.50%55.40%73.70%57.40%64.80%
Estimated Utility0.710.730.870.750.81
Table 4. Results of cost-apportionment process in scenario 1.
Table 4. Results of cost-apportionment process in scenario 1.
Total Compensation = $5000Incompatible Pair 1Incompatible Pair 2Incompatible Pair 3Incompatible Pair 4
Net Utility−0.09−0.140.12−0.06
Normalized Net Utility0.0500.260.08
Portion of Total Compensation Assigned13.60%0.00%66.30%20.10%
Assigned Cost ($)680-33131007
Table 5. Results of cost-apportionment process in scenario 2.
Table 5. Results of cost-apportionment process in scenario 2.
Total Compensation = $5500Incompatible Pair 1Incompatible Pair 2Incompatible Pair 3Incompatible Pair 4
Net Utility−0.03−0.140.12−0.06
Normalized Net Utility0.1100.260.08
Portion of Total Compensation Assigned24.90%0.00%57.60%17.50%
Assigned Cost ($)1368-3169963
Table 6. Frequency distribution of 10-year survival outcomes of transplants.
Table 6. Frequency distribution of 10-year survival outcomes of transplants.
Transplant’s OutcomeSurvivedNot-Survived
Frequency39484972
Percentage Frequency44.3%55.7%
Table 7. Results of cost-apportionment process.
Table 7. Results of cost-apportionment process.
Receiving Transplant’s OutcomeSurvivedNot Survived
ApproachFCAECAFCAECA
% of Total Compensation Paid52%44%48%56%
Average Compensation Paid ($)740629545633
Participants without Payment233-767-
% of Incompatible Pairs44%56%
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Hosseinzadeh, A.; Najafi, M.; Cheungpasitporn, W.; Thongprayoon, C.; Fathi, M. Equity or Equality? Which Approach Brings More Satisfaction in a Kidney-Exchange Chain? J. Pers. Med. 2021, 11, 1383. https://doi.org/10.3390/jpm11121383

AMA Style

Hosseinzadeh A, Najafi M, Cheungpasitporn W, Thongprayoon C, Fathi M. Equity or Equality? Which Approach Brings More Satisfaction in a Kidney-Exchange Chain? Journal of Personalized Medicine. 2021; 11(12):1383. https://doi.org/10.3390/jpm11121383

Chicago/Turabian Style

Hosseinzadeh, Arian, Mehdi Najafi, Wisit Cheungpasitporn, Charat Thongprayoon, and Mahdi Fathi. 2021. "Equity or Equality? Which Approach Brings More Satisfaction in a Kidney-Exchange Chain?" Journal of Personalized Medicine 11, no. 12: 1383. https://doi.org/10.3390/jpm11121383

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop