Institutions, Labor Market Insecurity, and Well-Being in Europe
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Theoretical Background
2.1. Labor Market Structures and Policies
2.2. Social Welfare Protection Policies
2.3. Worker Power
2.4. Conceptual Model
2.5. Hypotheses
3. Data, Variables, and Analytical Strategy
3.1. Data
3.2. Variables
3.2.1. Institutional Variables
3.2.2. Individual-Level Outcome Variables
3.2.3. Macroeconomic Controls
3.2.4. Individual-Level Characteristics
3.3. Analytic Strategy
4. Results
4.1. Country Differences in Labor Market Insecurity
4.2. Country Differences in Economic Security and Subjective Well-Being
4.3. Changes in Country Differences in Labor Market Insecurity and Well-Being
5. Discussion and Conclusions
Author Contributions
Funding
Data Availability Statement
Conflicts of Interest
Appendix A
Study | Data Source | Analysis Method | Geographic Coverage | Definitions and Associations Found |
---|---|---|---|---|
Effects of ALMPs on labor market insecurity | ||||
T. Berglund (2015) | EWCS 2010 | Multilevel models | 26 European countries | Increased expenditure on ALMP decreases the level of job insecurity. |
Lűbke and Erlinghagen (2014) | ESS 2004 and 2010 | Multilevel models | 19 European countries | A decrease in ALMP expenditure is negatively associated with job insecurity; however, the current level of expenditure on ALMP does not affect job insecurity. |
Chung and Oorschot (2011) | ESS 2008 | Multilevel models | 22 European countries | In countries with extensive ALMP measures, individuals are less likely to perceive employment insecurity. |
Anderson and Pontusson (2007) | ISSP 1997 | Multilevel models | 15 OECD countries | Government spending on ALMP reduces labor market insecurity—one’s ability to find another job. |
Effects of EPL on labor market insecurity | ||||
L. Hipp (2016) | ISSP 2005 | Multilevel models | 23 countries | Dismissal protection (i.e., the former one-dimensional EPL index) increases cognitive job insecurity—whether one thinks that one’s job is secure if the share of temporary work is high in that country. |
A. Balz (2017) | ESS 2004 and 2010 | Multilevel models | 17 to 22 European countries | The gap between temporary and permanent employees increased when (a) job security provisions within the employment protection legislation of a country were strong, and (b) when regulations on temporary contracts were strict. |
T. Berglund (2015) | EWCS 2010 | Multilevel models | 26 European countries | No significant effect of the strictness of EPL on overall subjective job insecurity. However, temporary employees with insecure jobs may experience more insecurity with a stricter EPL. |
Lűbke and Erlinghagen (2014) | ESS 2004 and 2010 | Multilevel models | 19 European countries | There is no significant association between the level of EPL with job insecurity. However, workers with temporary contracts benefit less from increased EPL than workers with unlimited contracts. |
Esser and Olsen (2012) | ESS 2004 | Multilevel models | 19 European countries | No evidence that stricter EPL (measures as a single index) affects job insecurity. |
Chung and Oorschot (2011) | ESS 2008 | Multilevel models | 22 European countries | There is an interaction effect between EPL for regular workers and permanent contracts, which is a positive, significant relationship. Having a permanent contract decreases the chance of feeling insecure about employment. |
Clark and Postel-Vinay (2009) | ECHP, 1997 through 2001 | 2-step regression models | 12 European countries | Among temporary employees and permanent employees in the private sector, stricter EPL reduces the perceived risk of job loss. However, stricter EPL also, at the same time, increases unemployment duration (in other words, it reduces the outflow rate from unemployment). |
Erlinghagen (2008) | ESS 2004 | Multilevel models | 17 European countries | Controlling for the long-term unemployment rate in a country, dismissal protection (i.e., the former one-dimensional EPL index) is not associated with perceived job insecurity. |
Anderson and Pontusson (2007) | ISSP 1997 | Multilevel models | 15 OECD countries | Stricter EPL is associated with reduced cognitive job insecurity—the self-rated probability of losing one’s current job. |
Effects of unemployment insurance on labor market insecurity | ||||
L. Hipp (2016) | ISSP 2005 | Multilevel models | 23 countries | Unemployment assistance decreases affective job insecurity—workers’ worries about losing their jobs. |
Berglund (2015) | EWCS 2010 | Multilevel models | 26 European countries | Increased expenditure on passive labor market policies reduces the level of job insecurity. |
Chung and Oorschot (2011) | ESS 2008 | Multilevel models | 22 European countries | In countries with generous unemployment benefits, individuals are less likely to perceive employment insecurity. |
Esser and Olsen (2012) | ESS 2004 | Multilevel models | 19 European countries | No evidence that the generosity of the unemployment benefit system affects job insecurity. |
Clark and Postel-Vinay (2009) | ECHP, 1997 through 2001 | 2-step regression models | 12 European countries | Unemployment benefit insurance generosity is positively correlated with perceived job security. |
Erlinghagen (2008) | ESS 2004 | Multilevel models | 17 European countries | When controlling for long-term unemployment rates in a country, social expenditure on unemployment insurance is not associated with perceived job insecurity. |
Effects of collective bargaining arrangements on labor market insecurity | ||||
Dixon et al. (2013) | Eurobarometer 2006 | Hierarchical linear models | 27 European countries | Perceived job and employment insecurity are generally greater in countries with lower worker unionization. |
Esser and Olsen (2012) | ESS 2004 | Multilevel models | 19 European countries | Union density negatively affects job insecurity when introduced solely, and when tested for interaction effects with the unemployment rate. |
Anderson and Pontusson (2007) | ISSP 1997 | Multilevel models | 15 OECD countries | Union membership is associated with decreased cognitive job insecurity (self-rated probability of losing one’s current job) but increased labor market insecurity (one’s ability to find another job). |
Edlund and Grӧnlund (2008) | ESS 2004 | Multilevel models | 21 European countries | Trade union density is positively associated with employer–employee dependence (i.e., the difficulty of finding another job and the difficulty of the employer in replacing an employee). |
Effects of unemployment insurance on SWB | ||||
Sjöberg (2010) | ESS 2004 | Multilevel models | 21 European countries | Unemployment benefit generosity has a positive effect on employed individuals’ sense of well-being, especially on those who have limited economic resources or an insecure position in the labor market. |
Di Tella and MacCulloch (2008) | Eurobarometer and GSS, 1975 to 1997 | Regression analysis | 12 OECD countries | By keeping the unemployment rate, income, and individual employment status constant, more generous benefits increase happiness. |
Job Insecurity | Employment Insecurity | Economic Security | SWB | |
---|---|---|---|---|
(1a) | (2a) | (3a) | (4a) | |
Age | 0.07 *** (0.01) | −0.06 *** (0.01) | −0.09 *** (0.02) | −0.06 *** (0.01) |
Age squared | −0.00 ** (0.00) | 0.00 *** (0.00) | 0.00 *** (0.00) | 0.00 *** (0.00) |
Female | −0.00 *** (0.03) | 0.17 *** (0.04) | −0.10 ** (0.05) | 0.10 *** (0.02) |
Illness/disability:Yes, to some extent | 0.04 (0.05) | 0.18 *** (0.05) | −0.48 *** (0.06) | −0.42 *** (0.03) |
Illness/disability: Yes, a lot | 0.04 ** (0.12) | 0.66 *** (0.14) | −0.61 *** (0.15) | −0.98 *** (0.08) |
1st income decile (bottom) | 0.16 (0.11) | 0.18 (0.13) | −1.10 *** (0.12) | −0.44 *** (0.07) |
2nd income decile | 0.03 ** (0.09) | 0.19 * (0.10) | −0.87 *** (0.10) | −0.23 *** (0.06) |
3rd income decile | 0.14 * (0.08) | 0.25 *** (0.09) | −0.64 *** (0.09) | −0.14 *** (0.05) |
4th income decile | 0.01 (0.07) | 0.03 (0.08) | −0.16 * (0.09) | 0.09 ** (0.05) |
6th income decile | −0.11 * (0.07) | −0.07 (0.08) | 0.22 *** (0.08) | 0.14 *** (0.04) |
7th income decile | −0.21 *** (0.07) | −0.11 (0.08) | 0.67 *** (0.09) | 0.19 *** (0.04) |
8th income decile | −0.21 *** (0.07) | −0.03 (0.08) | 1.21 *** (0.10) | 0.27 *** (0.04) |
9th income decile | −0.25 *** (0.07) | −0.25 *** (0.08) | 1.15 *** (0.10) | 0.24 *** (0.04) |
10th income decile (top) | −0.35 *** (0.07) | −0.39 *** (0.08) | 1.55 *** (0.11) | 0.35 *** (0.04) |
Log weekly hours | 0.02 (0.05) | −0.08 (0.05) | 0.14 ** (0.06) | −0.16 *** (0.03) |
Firm size: 10–24 | 0.00 (0.05) | 0.04 (0.06) | −0.06 (0.07) | −0.03 (0.03) |
Firm size: 25–99 | −0.05 (0.05) | 0.12 ** (0.05) | −0.09 (0.06) | 0.00 (0.03) |
Firm size: 100–499 | 0.01 (0.05) | 0.26 *** (0.06) | −0.11 (0.07) | −0.03 (0.03) |
Firm size: 500+ | 0.02 (0.06) | 0.31 *** (0.07) | 0.08 (0.09) | −0.08 ** (0.04) |
Union member, currently | −0.01 (0.04) | 0.20 *** (0.05) | −0.02 (0.06) | 0.01 (0.03) |
Union member, previously | 0.04 (0.05) | 0.25 *** (0.06) | −0.18 *** (0.06) | −0.05 (0.03) |
Separated | −0.11 ** (0.13) | −0.27 * (0.15) | 0.01 (0.15) | −0.77 *** (0.08) |
Divorced | −0.06 (0.06) | −0.22 *** (0.07) | −0.25 *** (0.07) | −0.45 *** (0.04) |
Widow | −0.12 (0.12) | −0.05 (0.14) | −0.16 (0.14) | −0.56 *** (0.08) |
Single | 0.05 (0.04) | −0.15 *** (0.05) | 0.26 *** (0.06) | −0.37 *** (0.03) |
Lower secondary education | 0.07 (0.09) | 0.16 (0.10) | −0.01 (0.10) | −0.06 (0.06) |
Upper secondary education | 0.03 (0.08) | 0.100.09) | 0.21 * (0.10) | −0.10 ** (0.05) |
Post-secondary education | 0.03 (0.10) | −0.04 (0.12) | 0.44 *** (0.13) | −0.12 * (0.07) |
Tertiary education | −0.26 *** (0.08) | −0.15 (0.10) | 0.70 *** (0.11) | −0.02 (0.05) |
n | 20,030 | 20,030 | 20,030 | 20,030 |
N | 17 | 17 | 17 | 17 |
VPC | 0.13 | 0.10 | 0.21 | 0.17 |
1 | The countries included in our analysis are: Belgium, the Czech Republic, Germany, Denmark, Estonia, Finland, France, Hungary, Ireland, the Netherlands, Norway, Poland, Portugal, Sweden, Slovakia, Spain, and the United Kingdom. |
2 | |
3 | Here, we limit the analysis to temporary workers only, which helps to visualize the predicted probabilities of a three-way interaction term between EPLs, contract type, and survey year. |
References
- Anderson, Christopher J., and Jonas Pontusson. 2007. Workers, worries and welfare states: Social protection and job insecurity in 15 OECD countries. European Journal of Political Research 46: 211–35. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Balz, Anne. 2017. Cross-National Variations in the Security Gap: Perceived Job Insecurity among Temporary and Permanent Employees and Employment Protection Legislation. European Sociological Review 33: 675–92. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Bell, Daniel. 1973. The Coming of Post-Industrial Society: A Venture in Social Forecasting. New York: Basic Books. [Google Scholar]
- Berglund, Tomas. 2015. Flexicurity, job insecurity, and well-being in European labor markets. In Sustainable Working Lives. Managing Work Transitions and Health Throughout the Life Course. Aligning Perspectives on Health, Safety and Well-Being. Edited by Jukka Vuori, Roland Blonk and Richard H. Price. Dordrecht: Springer, pp. 145–67. [Google Scholar]
- Boeri, Tito, and Jan Van Ours. 2008. The Economics of Imperfect Labor Markets. Princeton: Princeton University Press. [Google Scholar]
- Burchell, Brendan. 2011. A temporal comparison of the effects of unemployment and job insecurity on wellbeing. Sociological Research Online 16: 66–78. Available online: https://journals.sagepub.com/doi/10.5153/sro.2277 (accessed on 29 March 2022). [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Burgard, Sarah A., Jennie E. Brand, and James S. House. 2009. Perceived Job Insecurity and Worker Health in the United States. Social Science and Medicine 69: 777–85. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
- Chung, Heejung, and Wim van Oorschot. 2011. Institutions versus Market Forces: Explaining the Employment Insecurity of European Individuals During (the Beginning of) the Financial Crisis. Journal of European Social Policy 21: 287–301. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Clark, Andrew, and Conchita D’Ambrosio. 2014. Attitudes to Income Inequality: Experimental and Survey Evidence. Working Paper No. 8136. Bonn: Institute for the Study of Labor. [Google Scholar]
- Clark, Andrew, and Fabien Postel-Vinay. 2009. Job Security and Job Protection. Oxford Economic Papers 61: 207–39. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- De Witte, Hans. 1999. Job insecurity and psychological well-being: Review of the literature and exploration of some unresolved issues. European Journal of Work and Organizational Psychology 8: 155–77. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Di Tella, Rafael, and Robert J. MacCulloch. 2008. Gross national happiness as an answer to the Easterlin Paradox? Journal of Development Economics 86: 22–42. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dickerson, Andrew, and Francis Green. 2012. Fears and Realisations of Employment Insecurity. Labour Economics 19: 198–210. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Diener, Ed, Shigehiro Oishi, and Richard E. Lucas. 2003. Personality, culture and subjective well-being: Emotional and cognitive evaluations of life. Annual Review of Psychology 54: 403–25. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dixon, Jeffrey C., Andrew S. Fullerton, and Deanna L. Robertson. 2013. Cross-National Differences in Workers’ Perceived Job, Labour Market, and Employment Insecurity in Europe: Empirical Tests and Theoretical Extensions. European Sociological Review 29: 1053–67. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Edlund, Jonas, and Anne Grӧnlund. 2008. Protection of mutual interests? Employment protection and skill formation in different labour market regimes. European Journal of Industrial Relations 14: 245–64. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Erlinghagen, Marcel. 2008. Self-Perceived Job Insecurity and Social Context: A Multilevel Analysis of 17 European Countries. European Sociological Review 24: 183–97. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Esping-Andersen, Gϕsta. 1990. The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism. Princeton: Princeton University Press. [Google Scholar]
- Esser, Ingrid, and Karen M. Olsen. 2012. Perceived Job Quality: Autonomy and Job Security within a Multi-level Framework. European Sociological Review 28: 443–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- European Social Survey. 2004. Round 2 Data. Data File Edition 3.6. NSD—Norwegian Centre for Research Data, Norway—Data Archive and Distributor of ESS Data for ESS ERIC. Available online: https://ess-search.nsd.no/en/study/5296236e-b5ee-40dc-a554-81ea09211d1d (accessed on 29 March 2022). [CrossRef]
- European Social Survey. 2010. Round 5 Data. Data File Edition 3.4. NSD—Norwegian Centre for Research Data, Norway—Data Archive and distributor of ESS Data for ESS ERIC. Available online: https://ess-search.nsd.no/en/study/fd0dc7b6-3d5a-42d4-ad46-7a78e44e3963 (accessed on 29 March 2022). [CrossRef]
- Ferrer-i-Carbonell, Ada, and Xavier Ramos. 2012. Inequality and Happiness: A Survey. GINI Discussion Paper 38. Amsterdam: Amsterdam Institute for Advanced Labour Studies. [Google Scholar]
- Festinger, Leon. 1954. A theory of social comparison processes. Human Relations 7: 117–40. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Glavin, Paul, and Marisa Young. 2017. Insecure people in insecure places: The influence of regional unemployment on workers’ reactions to the threat of job loss. Journal of Health and Social Behavior 58: 232–52. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Green, Francis. 2009. Subjective Employment Insecurity Around the World. Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and Society 2: 343–63. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Greenhalgh, Leonard, and Zehava Rosenblatt. 1984. Job Insecurity: Toward Conceptual Clarity. Academy of Management Review 9: 438–48. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Hall, Peter A., and David Soskice, eds. 2001. Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage. Oxford: Oxford University Press. [Google Scholar]
- Hipp, Lena. 2016. Insecure times? Workers’ Perceived Job and Labor Market Security in 23 OECD Countries. Social Science Research 60: 1–14. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Howell, David R., and Arne L. Kalleberg. 2019. Declining Job Quality in the United States: Explanations and Evidence. RSF: Russell Sage Foundation Journal of the Social Sciences: Changing Job Quality: The Rise of Low-Wage Jobs and Nonstandard Work Arrangements 5: 1–53. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Inanc, Hande. 2018. Unemployment, temporary work and subjective well-being: The gendered effect of spousal labor market insecurity. American Sociological Review 83: 536–66. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kalleberg, Arne L. 2018. Precarious Lives: Job Insecurity and Well-Being in Rich Democracies. Cambridge: Polity. [Google Scholar]
- Kalleberg, Arne L., and Steven P. Vallas. 2018. Probing Precarious Work: Theory, Research, and Politics. In Precarious Work: Causes, Characteristics, and Consequences. Edited by Arne L. Kalleberg and Steven P. Vallas. Volume 31 of Research in the Sociology of Work. Bingley: Emerald, pp. 1–30. [Google Scholar]
- Kerr, Clark, John T. Dunlop, Frederick H. Harbison, and Charles A. Myers. 1960. Industrialism and Industrial Man. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. [Google Scholar]
- Korpi, Walter. 1985. Developments in the Theory of Power and Exchange. Sociological Theory 3: 31–45. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Lam, Jack, Wen Fan, and Phyllis Moen. 2014. Is insecurity worse for well-being in turbulent times? Society and Mental Health 4: 55–73. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
- Lűbke, Christiane, and Marcel Erlinghagen. 2014. Self-perceived Job insecurity Across Europe over Time: Does Changing Context Matter? Journal of European Social Policy 24: 319–36. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Manski, Charles, and John D. Straub. 2000. Worker perceptions of job insecurity in the mid-1990s: Evidence from the survey of economic expectations. Journal of Human Resources 35: 447–79. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- OECD. 2011. Economic Policy Reforms 2011: Going for Growth. Chapter 3 Structural policy indicators. Paris: OECD Publishing. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- OECD. 2012. Economic Policy Reforms 2012: Going for Growth. Chapter 3 Structural policy indicators. Paris: OECD Publishing. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- OECD. 2013a. “Strictness of Employment Protection” Employment Protection Database. Available online: https://stats.oecd.org/Index.aspx?DataSetCode=EPL_OV (accessed on 26 April 2019).
- OECD. 2013b. Economic Policy Reforms 2013: Going for Growth. Chapter 4 Structural Policy Indicators. Paris: OECD Publishing. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- OECD. 2013c. OECD Guidelines on Measuring Subjective Well-Being. Paris: OECD Publishing. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- OECD. 2015. Unemployment as a percentage of civilian labour force. In OECD Labour Force Statistics 2014. Paris: OECD Publishing. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- OECD. 2016. “Key Indicators” Benefits, Taxes, and Wages Database. Available online: https://stats.oecd.org/Index.aspx?DataSetCode=TAXBEN (accessed on 14 March 2019).
- OECD. 2017a. “Public Expenditure and Participant Stocks on LMP” Labour Market Programmes Database. Available online: https://stats.oecd.org/index.aspx?DataSetCode=LMPEXP (accessed on 30 September 2019).
- OECD. 2017b. “P90/P10 Income Decile Ratio”. OECD Income Distribution Database (IDD). Available online: http://stats.oecd.org/Index.aspx?DataSetCode=IDD (accessed on 20 January 2019).
- Oishi, Shigehiro, Selin Kesebir, and Ed Diener. 2011. Income inequality and happiness. Psychological Science 22: 1095–100. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Osberg, Lars, and A. Sharpe. 2014. Measuring Economic Insecurity in Rich and Poor Nations. Review of Income and Wealth Series 60: S53–S76. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Pichler, Florian. 2006. Subjective Quality of Life Among Young Europeans. Feeling Happy but Who Knows Why? Social Indicators Research 75: 419–44. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Polavieja, Javier G. 2003. Temporary Contracts and Labour Market Segmentation in Spain: An Employment-Rent Approach. European Sociological Review 19: 501–17. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Scherer, Stefani. 2009. The Social Consequences of Insecure Jobs. Social Indicators Research 93: 527–47. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sjöberg, Ola. 2010. Social Insurance as a Collective Resource: Unemployment Benefits, Job Insecurity and Subjective Well-being in a Comparative Perspective. Social Forces 88: 1281–304. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Standing, Guy. 2011. The Precariat: The New Dangerous Class. New York: Bloomsbury. [Google Scholar]
- Sverke, Magnus, and Johnny Hellgren. 2002. The nature of job insecurity: Understanding employment uncertainty on the brink of a new millennium. Applied Psychology: An International Review 51: 23–42. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Tegund, Alina. 2014. Uncertainty about Jobs Has a Ripple Effect. New York Times. May 16. Available online: https://www.nytimes.com/2014/05/17/your-money/uncertainty-about-jobs-has-a-ripple-effect.html?_r=0 (accessed on 27 December 2020).
- Venn, Danielle. 2009. Legislation, Collective Bargaining and Enforcement: Updating the OECD Employment Protection Indicators. Paris: OECD Publishing. Available online: http://www.oecd.org/employment/emp/43116624.pdf (accessed on 2 October 2020).
- Viebrock, Elke, and Jochen Clasen. 2009. Flexicurity and Welfare Reform: A Review. Socio-Economic Review 7: 305–31. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Vosko, Leah F. 2010. Managing the Margins: Gender, Citizenship, and the International Regulation of Precarious Work. Oxford: Oxford University Press. [Google Scholar]
1a | 1b | 1c | 1d | 1e | 1f | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Precarious work | ||||||
Temporary contract | 1.06 *** | 1.06 *** | 1.06 *** | 1.05 *** | 1.06 *** | 1.06 *** |
(0.05) | (0.05) | (0.05) | (0.05) | (0.05) | (0.05) | |
Tenure with current employer | −0.02 *** | −0.02 *** | −0.02 *** | −0.02 *** | −0.02 *** | −0.02 *** |
(0.00) | (0.00) | (0.00) | (0.00) | (0.00) | (0.00) | |
Unemployment experience | 0.33 *** | 0.33 *** | 0.33 *** | 0.33 *** | 0.33 *** | 0.33 *** |
(0.05) | (0.05) | (0.05) | (0.05) | (0.05) | (0.05) | |
Other L1 controls | YES | YES | YES | YES | YES | YES |
Macroeconomic indicators | ||||||
Income inequality | −0.11 | −0.11 | −0.17 | −0.10 | −0.18 | |
(0.13) | (0.13) | (0.11) | (0.13) | (0.13) | ||
Unemployment rate | 0.25 * | 0.34 *** | 0.23 * | |||
(0.13) | (0.11) | (0.12) | ||||
Labor market institutions and welfare systems | ||||||
ALMP + | −0.26 ** | |||||
(0.13) | ||||||
EPRC | 0.36 *** | |||||
(0.11) | ||||||
EPT | −0.27 ** | |||||
(0.11) | ||||||
Temporary contract × EPRC | −0.02 | |||||
(0.05) | ||||||
Temporary contract × EPT | 0.27 *** | |||||
(0.05) | ||||||
NRR + | −0.23 * | |||||
(0.13) | ||||||
CBC rate | −0.22 * | |||||
(0.12) | ||||||
AIC | 15,478.3 | 15,477.7 | 15,468.3 | 15,477.3 | 15,459.6 | 15,477.7 |
BIC | 15,739.1 | 15,754.4 | 15,776.6 | 15,753.9 | 15,767.9 | 15,754.3 |
VPC | 0.13 | 0.12 | 0.12 | 0.09 | 0.12 | 0.11 |
Reduction in VPC (vs. null model) | 0.0% | 7.7% | 7.7% | 30.8% | 7.7% | 15.4% |
Reduction in VPC (vs. Model 1b) | N/A | N/A | 0.0% | 25.0% | 0.0% | 8.3% |
2a | 2b | 2c | 2d | 2e | 2f | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Precarious work | ||||||
Temporary contract | 0.01 | 0.01 | 0.01 | 0.01 | 0.01 | 0.01 |
(0.06) | (0.06) | (0.06) | (0.06) | (0.06) | (0.06) | |
Tenure with current employer | 0.02 *** | 0.02 *** | 0.02 *** | 0.02 *** | 0.02 *** | 0.03 *** |
(0.00) | (0.00) | (0.00) | (0.00) | (0.00) | (0.00) | |
Unemployment experience | 0.45 *** | 0.44 *** | 0.44 *** | 0.44 *** | 0.44 *** | 0.44 *** |
(0.06) | (0.06) | (0.06) | (0.06) | (0.06) | (0.06) | |
Job insecurity | 0.59 *** | 0.59 *** | 0.59 *** | 0.59 *** | 0.59 *** | 0.59 *** |
(0.04) | (0.04) | (0.04) | (0.04) | (0.04) | (0.04) | |
Other L1 controls | YES | YES | YES | YES | YES | YES |
Macroeconomic indicators | ||||||
Income inequality | 0.21 | 0.18 | 0.18 | 0.24 * | 0.10 | |
(0.14) | (0.13) | (0.13) | (0.14) | (0.13) | ||
Unemployment rate | 0.26 * | 0.33 ** | 0.23 * | |||
(0.14) | (0.13) | (0.13) | ||||
Labor market institutions and welfare systems | ||||||
ALMP + | −0.32 ** | |||||
(0.14) | ||||||
EPRC | 0.25 * | |||||
(0.13) | ||||||
EPT | −0.20 | |||||
(0.13) | ||||||
Temporary contract × EPRC | −0.03 | |||||
(0.06) | ||||||
Temporary contract × EPT | −0.04 | |||||
(0.06) | ||||||
NRR + | −0.20 | |||||
(0.14) | ||||||
CBC rate | −0.32 ** | |||||
(0.13) | ||||||
AIC | 94,764.8 | 94,759.7 | 94,757.9 | 94,762.4 | 94,761.0 | 94,755.8 |
BIC | 95,041.4 | 95,052.1 | 95,050.4 | 95,086.5 | 95,053.5 | 95,056.2 |
VPC | 9% | 7% | 7% | 6% | 7% | 6% |
Reduction in VPC (vs. null model) | 0.0% | 22.2% | 22.2% | 33.3% | 22.2% | 33.3% |
Reduction in VPC (vs. Model 2b) | N/A | N/A | 0.0% | 14.3% | 0.0% | 14.3% |
3a | 3b | 3c | 3d | 3e | 3f | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Precarious work | ||||||
Temporary contract | −0.03 | −0.03 | −0.03 | −0.02 | −0.03 | −0.03 |
(0.07) | (0.07) | (0.07) | (0.07) | (0.07) | (0.07) | |
Tenure with current employer | 0.02 *** | 0.02 *** | 0.02 *** | 0.02 *** | 0.02 *** | 0.02 *** |
(0.00) | (0.00) | (0.00) | (0.00) | (0.00) | (0.00) | |
Unemployment experience | −0.38 *** | −0.37 *** | −0.37 *** | −0.37 *** | −0.37 *** | −0.38 *** |
(0.07) | (0.07) | (0.07) | (0.07) | (0.07) | (0.07) | |
Job insecurity | −0.42 *** | −0.42 *** | −0.42 *** | −0.42 *** | −0.42 *** | −0.42 *** |
(0.05) | (0.05) | (0.05) | (0.05) | (0.05) | (0.05) | |
Employment insecurity | −0.05 *** | −0.05 *** | −0.05 *** | −0.05 *** | −0.05 *** | −0.05 *** |
(0.01) | (0.01) | (0.01) | (0.01) | (0.01) | (0.01) | |
Other L1 controls | YES | YES | YES | YES | YES | YES |
Macroeconomic indicators | ||||||
Income inequality | −0.30 ** | −0.09 | −0.28 * | −0.24 * | −0.12 | |
(0.15) | (0.10) | (0.15) | (0.14) | (0.13) | ||
Unemployment rate | −0.24 | −0.30 ** | −0.19 | |||
(0.15) | (0.15) | (0.12) | ||||
Labor market institutions and welfare systems | ||||||
ALMP + | 0.67 *** | |||||
(0.10) | ||||||
EPRC | −0.17 | |||||
(0.14) | ||||||
EPT | 0.21 | |||||
(0.14) | ||||||
Temporary contract × EPRC | −0.12 ** | |||||
(0.06) | ||||||
Temporary contract × EPT | 0.00 | |||||
(0.06) | ||||||
NRR + | 0.36 ** | |||||
(0.14) | ||||||
CBC rate | 0.50 *** | |||||
(0.12) | ||||||
AIC | 13,845.4 | 13,838.7 | 13,813.3 | 13,826.12 | 13,835.2 | 13,826.1 |
BIC | 14,122.1 | 14,131.2 | 14,105.7 | 14,126.51 | 14,127.7 | 14,126.5 |
VPC | 0.20 | 0.15 | 0.07 | 0.14 | 0.14 | 0.10 |
Reduction in VPC (vs. null model) | 4.8% | 28.6% | 66.7% | 33.3% | 33.3% | 52.4% |
Reduction in VPC (vs. Model 3b) | N/A | N/A | 53.3% | 6.7% | 6.7% | 33.3% |
4a | 4b | 4c | 4d | 4e | 4f | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Precarious work | ||||||
Temporary contract | −0.02 | −0.02 | −0.02 | −0.02 | −0.02 | −0.02 |
(0.03) | (0.03) | (0.03) | (0.03) | (0.03) | (0.03) | |
Tenure with current employer | 0.00 *** | 0.00 *** | 0.00 *** | 0.00 *** | 0.00 *** | 0.00 *** |
(0.00) | (0.00) | (0.00) | (0.00) | (0.00) | (0.00) | |
Unemployment experience | −0.18 *** | −0.18 *** | −0.18 *** | −0.18 *** | −0.18 *** | −0.18 *** |
(0.04) | (0.04) | (0.04) | (0.04) | (0.04) | (0.04) | |
Job insecurity | −0.27 *** | −0.27 *** | −0.27 *** | −0.27 *** | −0.27 *** | −0.27 *** |
(0.02) | (0.02) | (0.02) | (0.02) | (0.02) | (0.02) | |
Employment insecurity | −0.03 *** | −0.03 *** | −0.03 *** | −0.03 *** | −0.03 *** | −0.03 *** |
(0.00) | (0.00) | (0.00) | (0.00) | (0.00) | (0.00) | |
Economic security | 0.87 *** | 0.87 *** | 0.87 *** | 0.87 *** | 0.87 *** | −0.87 *** |
(0.03) | (0.03) | (0.03) | (0.03) | (0.03) | (0.03) | |
Other L1 controls | YES | YES | YES | YES | YES | YES |
Macroeconomic indicators | ||||||
Income inequality | −0.25 *** | −0.15 * | −0.23 *** | −0.22 ** | −0.15 * | |
(0.09) | (0.08) | (0.09) | (0.09) | (0.08) | ||
Unemployment rate | −0.06 | −0.10 | −0.04 | |||
(0.09) | (0.09) | (0.07) | ||||
Labor market institutions and welfare systems | ||||||
ALMP + | 0.28 *** | |||||
(0.08) | ||||||
EPRC | −0.14 * | |||||
(0.08) | ||||||
EPT | 0.12 | |||||
(0.09) | ||||||
Temporary contract × EPRC | 0.04 | |||||
(0.04) | ||||||
Temporary contract × EPT | −0.01 | |||||
(0.03) | ||||||
NRR + | 0.14 | |||||
(0.09) | ||||||
CBC rate | 0.29 *** | |||||
(0.07) | ||||||
AIC | 71,805.5 | 71,798.1 | 71787.1 | 71801.3 | 71,796.1 | 71,786.4 |
BIC | 72,098.0 | 72,106.4 | 72,095.4 | 72,141.3 | 72,104.4 | 72,102.6 |
VPC | 0.13 | 0.09 | 0.07 | 0.09 | 0.09 | 0.06 |
Reduction in VPC (vs. null model) | 23.5% | 47.1% | 58.8% | 47.1% | 47.1% | 64.7% |
Reduction in VPC (vs. Model 4b) | N/A | N/A | 22.2% | 0.0% | 0.0% | 33.3% |
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations. |
© 2022 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Inanc, H.; Kalleberg, A.L. Institutions, Labor Market Insecurity, and Well-Being in Europe. Soc. Sci. 2022, 11, 245. https://doi.org/10.3390/socsci11060245
Inanc H, Kalleberg AL. Institutions, Labor Market Insecurity, and Well-Being in Europe. Social Sciences. 2022; 11(6):245. https://doi.org/10.3390/socsci11060245
Chicago/Turabian StyleInanc, Hande, and Arne L. Kalleberg. 2022. "Institutions, Labor Market Insecurity, and Well-Being in Europe" Social Sciences 11, no. 6: 245. https://doi.org/10.3390/socsci11060245
APA StyleInanc, H., & Kalleberg, A. L. (2022). Institutions, Labor Market Insecurity, and Well-Being in Europe. Social Sciences, 11(6), 245. https://doi.org/10.3390/socsci11060245