Next Article in Journal
Instance Segmentation of Lotus Pods and Stalks in Unstructured Planting Environment Based on Improved YOLOv5
Next Article in Special Issue
Income and Asset Situation of Companies Producing Arable Crops in the Visegrad Countries
Previous Article in Journal
Animal Hygiene on Farms—More Important than Ever Before
Previous Article in Special Issue
Effects of Aging on Labor-Intensive Crop Production from the Perspectives of Landform and Life Cycle Labor Supply: Evidence from Chinese Apple Growers
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Plant Protection and Fertilizer Use Efficiency in Farms in a Context of Overinvestment: A Case Study from Poland

Faculty of Economics, Department of Economics and Economic Policy in Agribusiness, Poznan University of Life Sciences, 60-637 Poznan, Poland
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Agriculture 2023, 13(8), 1567; https://doi.org/10.3390/agriculture13081567
Submission received: 10 July 2023 / Revised: 30 July 2023 / Accepted: 4 August 2023 / Published: 6 August 2023

Abstract

:
The purpose of this study was to determine the relationship between plant protection and fertilizer use efficiency, on one side, and overinvestment in Polish agriculture, on the other. This is an important topic because of a number of essential issues, such as the concern for the environment, the development of sustainable agriculture, or the need to ensure food security which can only be achieved by keeping production volumes at least at the same level. Reconciling these goals often requires investment which, however, involves the risk of overinvesting, i.e., a situation where the value of assets grows without a proportional increment in labor productivity. This paper uses the author’s own method of farm classification by overinvestment level. The study revealed some differences in the cost intensity of fertilizing and using plant-protection products between investment levels. The most rational results were found in farms at optimum investment levels, whereas the greatest cost intensity was recorded in farms affected by overinvestment.

1. Introduction

Meeting the need for food remains the basic human need [1,2,3]. The growing population made it necessary to intensify agriculture, which largely means an increased use of fertilizers and plant-protection products [4,5,6,7]. According to the Fertilizers Europe report [8], as much as 50% of the world’s population is provided with food produced with the use of agricultural fertilizers. The above makes fertilizers an essential part of ensuring food security, and a crucial yield booster [9]. A specific feedback loop exists in that context—the use of industrial yield boosters contributes to population growth which, in turn, makes it necessary to increase production, mostly by using these very industrial products [10]. The whole process has an impact on the climate and the environment [11,12,13].
The climate is threatened by greenhouse-gas emissions, one of which is nitrous oxide [14], whose calorific potential is more than 300 times that of carbon dioxide [15]. It is released into the atmosphere either directly or through denitrification, a process resulting from improper agricultural practices and excessive fertilization rates [16,17]. Equally important is the aspect related to surface and groundwater pollution, which has an adverse effect on biodiversity [18]. Also, it impacts the chemical composition of potable water which, in view of its shrinking resources, represents a major problem [19,20]. Moreover, improper fertilization may reduce soil fertility, i.e., become counterproductive [20,21]. That problem is noticeable in Europe, where plow tillage plays a dominant role, and agricultural land accounts for nearly half of most countries’ landmass. Hence, a conflict arises between the irreducible need to ensure food security for the growing population and the equally important environmental and climate goals [22,23]. As the main carbon sink, soils play an important role in reducing greenhouse-gas emissions [24] by providing and regulating key ecosystem services and ensuring biodiversity protection [25]. However, in Europe, the soil-loss rate is almost twice the soil-formation rate [26,27]. It should be noted that, of course, agriculture is not the only sector contributing to climate change. Nevertheless, its contribution to greenhouse-gas emissions is around 22% (together with forestry and other land use) [28]. In the context of the use of fertilizers and plant protection, it is also important to mention their impact on the local environment, mainly on soil quality [11]. It can be both positive and negative, depending on the rationality of the application [4]. The implementation of good practices can even improve soil quality relative to its natural state [29]. The subject is particularly important in the case of Polish agriculture, which is characterized, compared to the EU countries, by a relatively high cost of fertilization and plant protection in relation to the volume of production. This is because the use of a chemical yield booster is a kind of substitute for failure in other agrotechnical practices (such as the use of certified seed) [9].
That issue could be solved by rationalized fertilizer use, so as to address the need for food while minimizing the adverse environmental impacts [30]. A similar problem arises with respect to plant-protection products. Finally, the use of yield boosters also has an economic dimension. Indeed, the farms struggle with what is referred to as “margin squeeze”: the price relationship between agricultural raw materials and productive inputs such as seed, seedlings, energy, fertilizers, plant-protection products, or feedingstuffs [31]. During extreme price surges, the farmers must sometimes decide to discontinue using some productive inputs. But on the other hand, the growing population means that agricultural production must grow.
The above has become even more important due to the Russian attack on Ukraine [32]. On the one hand, this makes the ever-existing problem of food security even more alarming [32,33], but, on the other, the rising prices make it even more imperative to seek rationalization of pesticide and fertilizer use. As regards the latter, note the convergence between environmental requirements and microeconomic goals of agricultural producers who seek maximization of economic results.
In an attempt to solve the conflicts between the need to produce food and the need to protect the environment [11], European Union countries came up with the European Green Deal (EGD) [34] concept, which is supposed to make the EU a modern, resource-efficient, competitive economy, so as to reduce net greenhouse-gas emissions to zero by 2050 [24,35]. It spans all sectors, including agriculture, which is particularly addressed in the “Farm to Fork” and “Biodiversity” strategies [36]. In the latter, soil plays a key role in meeting the goals of sustainable development [37]. The EGD assumes a 50% reduction in the use of chemical plant-protection products (and related risks), a 20% or greater reduction in the use of artificial fertilizers, and a 50% reduction in the use of antibiotics by 2030 [38]. Also, organic production is expected to grow and is supposed to account for 25% of agricultural land. The EGD sets objectives for biodiversity, climate change, sustainable agriculture, and rural development [39]. It emphasizes the importance of reducing soil pollution [40,41] caused by large quantities of fertilizers being used in agriculture [42]. As regards agriculture, the essential shortcoming of the EGD is the absence of clearly defined methods for seeking these goals and its failure to address the need for ensuring food security. The problem is mostly about reducing the use of industrial yield boosters; counteracting climate change cannot become a growth barrier for food production [43]. According to a number of studies [9,44,45], the reduction in the use of nitrogenous fertilizers is particularly likely to contribute to a reduction in agricultural production volumes. Hence, EGD assumptions make it necessary once again to rationalize the use of industrial yield boosters. In order to reduce their use with no adverse effect on yields, it is essential to employ adequate agrotechnical measures, on the one hand, and to invest.
Investments can be economically unviable, which means the economic operator suffers a loss in the long term. This process can also be noticed in the agricultural sector and affects specific groups of farms to various degrees. This results in the emergence of what is referred to as overinvestment, i.e., a condition where long-term investments are excessively high compared to the production potential (mainly land resources) and, ultimately, become economically unviable [46]. Optimum investment means a situation where the assets-to-labor ratio (ALR) of a farm grows at the same pace as labor productivity (LP) [47]. In turn, overinvestment takes place when the assets-to-labor ratio grows while labor productivity declines or remains constant [46]. The inefficiency of investments brings many negative effects to farms. In addition to achieving worse economic results, we can observe behaviors in the very decision-making processes regarding the optimization of the production path, including the efficiency of the use of fertilizers and plant protection products.
Investigating the relationship between overinvestment and the use efficiency of fertilizers and plant-production products is all the more important since—as mentioned earlier in this paper—investments are necessary (in addition to agrotechnical measures and agricultural knowledge) in order to rationalize fertilization. As demonstrated by Wei et al. [48], the larger the farm, the better the fertilizer use efficiency. Yang and Lin [49] pointed to the rationale of subsidizing investments in the agricultural sector as more efficient for farms and the environment than subsidies for fertilizer application. In addition, climate variability means that investments in fertilizers and crop-protection products alone may not yield the expected results [50]. This results from optimum fertilization levels which, in practice, means minimizing the fertilizer-to-yields ratio (while reducing environmental pollution). Indeed, the owners of larger farms are more aware of how to use fertilizers and rely on more sophisticated technical equipment [51]. Therefore, Stoicea et al. [52] suggest that reduction rates should be set on a per-country basis because of differences in development levels. Nevertheless, the investments themselves are important in achieving optimal levels of fertilizer and crop protection-product use. At the same time, however, there is the problem of hasty investments leading to overinvestment, which interferes with optimal decision-making, including in the area of fertilizer and pesticide application.
As a consequence, having in mind the future challenges and problems involved in the implementation of the assumptions behind the European Green Deal, as described above, the purpose of this study was to determine the relationship between plant protection and fertilizer use efficiency, on one side, and overinvestment in Polish agriculture, on the other.
As agriculture is a high-emission sector, the environmental efficiency of food production should be a major element of the policy designed to counteract climate change [53]. Thus, investment subsidies should also contribute to the general social goal of protecting the environment and climate [54].

2. Materials and Methods

The research materials were unpublished 2010–2019 accounting data for 3273 Polish farms, retrieved from the FADN. (FADN is a farming accountancy system used in all EU member countries. It covers commercial farms which jointly account for 90% of a country’s standard output and is mostly used to monitor the effects of the Common Agricultural Policy and to develop its future assumptions) database. Farms were divided into investing farms (investing with investment support and investing without investment support) and noninvesting farms. For this purpose, those farms for which the sum of investments in 2010–2019 was less than PLN 10,000 were considered noninvesting. According to accounting records on fixed assets, depreciation is made on assets above the value of PLN 10,000. On the other hand, farms using investment support were considered those for which the sum of investment support for the surveyed 10 years was greater than PLN 0. All others were considered nonusers of investment support. The research diagram is shown in Figure 1.
In order to enable a more precise comparison, the farms were divided into noninvesting and investing ones, which, in turn, were grouped as users and nonusers of EU investment support (Figure 1).
This paper assumes that increasing the value of farm assets through investments is a reasonable thing to do if it results in a proportional growth in labor productivity. Therefore, overinvestment is defined as a situation where:
  • The increase in the value of assets results in a decline or stagnation in labor productivity, which may be due to the high maintenance costs of particular assets (e.g., depreciation, insurance, and repairs). The above is defined as absolute overinvestment;
  • Labor productivity grows at a lower rate than the value of assets. This is referred to as relative overinvestment.
The study period spanned from 2010 to 2019; the growth rates for asset amounts and labor productivity (of essential importance for the goal of this study) were determined for the final year.
The noninvesting farms were only split into underinvested and other holdings because farms that did not make any investments over a 10-year period cannot find themselves at excessive or optimum investment levels. Average values could be calculated by creating panel data based on microdata. Thus, it was possible to initially identify a single type of overinvestment for the whole group of farms covered by the study, based on whether or not they accessed investment subsidies. Also, overinvestment levels were calculated separately for each farm. It turned out that the database included farms that shifted between overinvestment levels over the study years. Therefore, it was decided that the best way to determine their overinvestment status would be to identify five separate 2-year periods and to compare the last period against the baseline. This resulted in attributing a specific overinvestment level to each farm based on the last period covered by the study (2018–2019). Also, using two-year average figures allowed for the avoidance of price fluctuations.
The study used a previously employed method [55]. Labor productivity was calculated as gross value added less depreciation, less investment subsidy installments, and less operating subsidies per employee:
L P t = t t + 1 ( S E 410 S E 360 S E 406 S E 605 S E 010 ) 2
Δ L P = ( L P t 5 L P t 0 L P t 0 ) 100 %
where:
LP: labor productivity;
SE410: gross value added;
SE360: depreciation;
SE406: investment subsidy installments;
SE605: operating subsidies;
SE010: total labor inputs (AWU).
As the next step, the assets-to-labor ratio was calculated as per the following formula:
A L R t = t t + 1 ( S E 441 S E 446 S E 010 ) 2
Δ A L R = ( A L R t 5 A L R t 0 A L R t 0 ) 100 %
where:
ALR: assets-to-labor ratio;
SE441: fixed assets;
SE446: land, permanent crops, and production quotas;
SE010: total labor inputs (AWU).
After calculating the two parameters necessary to determine investment levels, the farm data was distributed between the groups in accordance with the author’s own methodology:
I. Absolute overinvestment: this is the case for farms where labor productivity drops while the assets-to-labor ratio grows:
ΔLP < 0    ∧    ΔALR > 0
II. Relative overinvestment: this is the case for farms where both labor productivity and the assets-to-labor ratio are on an increase but the increase in the assets-to-labor ratio is greater than the increase in labor productivity:
ΔLP > 0    ∧    ΔALR > 0    ∧    ΔLP < ΔALR
III. Underinvestment: this is the case for farms where both labor productivity and the assets-to-labor ratio are on a decline:
ΔLP < 0    ∧    ΔALR < 0
IV. Optimum investments: this is the case for farms where both labor productivity and the assets-to-labor ratio are on an increase, and labor productivity grows faster than the assets-to-labor ratio:
ΔLP > 0    ∧    ΔALR > 0    ∧    ΔLP > ΔALR
V. Optimum investments with no increase in the assets-to-labor ratio: this is the case for farms where labor productivity grows while the assets-to-labor ratio neither grows nor declines:
ΔLP > 0    ∧    ΔALR < 0    ∧    ΔLP > ΔALR
The next step consisted of calculating the average consumption level of fertilizers and plant-protection products for each overinvestment level in each investment group. This allowed for the determination of the environmental efficiency of using fertilizers and plant-protection products in the farms covered by the study. The quantity and efficiency of fertilizer use was calculated as per the following formulas:
F C = F L
F E = F P
where:
FC: fertilization costs;
FE: fertilization efficiency;
F: fertilization costs (PLN);
P: production value (PLN);
L: farmland area (ha of agricultural land).
The amount and efficiency of plant-protection products used were calculated in a similar way:
P P C = S C P P L
E E P P = S C P P P
where:
PPC: plant-protection costs;
EEPP: environmental efficiency of plant-protection products used;
SCPP: consumption scale of plant-protection products (PLN);
P: output (PLN);
L: farmland area (ha).
The analysis of results made it possible to indicate the optimum development path for farm investments while taking their environmental impact into account.

3. Results and Discussion

In order to determine the changes in the use of fertilizers and plant-protection products, it is necessary to identify the changes in average land resources (Table 1). This is because the use and efficiency of industrial productive inputs depend on a number of factors, including the farms’ technical equipment, which, in turn, varies in function of farm size.
Land resources owned by a farm are largely decisive for its competitive position and capacity to generate incomes. Changes in land resources can be found in farms grouped by investment amount and by overinvestment level. In each group, underinvested farms and those which make optimum investments with no increase in the assets-to-labor ratio were found to have the smallest area. Conversely, the physically largest farms form part of the absolute and relative overinvestment groups. In general, the noninvesting group saw a decline in their average farm area. However, land resources of the “other” group decreased at a faster rate. These trends could be indicative of the smallest farmers believing that they have no competitive advantages. Such a relationship is probably due to the farms gradually discontinuing their agricultural production activities and making more and more divestments [56].
In the group of investing farms that access investment support, members of the “absolute overinvestment” subgroup saw their land resources growing at a rate comparable to that of farms at optimum investment levels. In turn, the slowest growth was recorded in farms classified as “relative overinvestment”. As regards the investing farms which do not access investment support, the fastest growth in land resources was witnessed in holdings which recorded an increase in the assets-to-labor ratio while being at optimum investment levels. Conversely, a decline in land area was found in members of the “absolute overinvestment” subgroup and, though to a minimum extent, in underinvested farms. A small growth or decline in the land area of investing farms could mean they made excessive investments in fixed assets and therefore did not have the financial capacity to increase their land resources, or that no one offered land for sale. Also, they predominantly followed a capital-intensive development path.
The cost intensity of fertilization was found to grow considerably in underinvested farms but remained constant in other holdings (Table 2). As a consequence, the fertilization efficiency varied quite strongly in the final years of the study, which may indirectly result from the lack of technical equipment and from an improper use of fertilizers. In 2019, underinvested farms incurred a cost of PLN 0.14 per PLN 1 worth of production, compared to as little as PLN 0.10 in other holdings.
Environmental efficiency of plant protection use remained at a constant level in both underinvested and other farms. They were quite small and similar in both groups.
Despite fertilization being less cost intensive in the “other” group, the amount of the costs per area unit (Table 3) was higher in all years. This could be an indirect indication that relatively high (though rational from an economic and environmental perspective) fertilization rates can be closer to an optimum relationship between inputs and outputs. Over subsequent years of the study, both groups experienced a certain increase in fertilization costs per hectare of agricultural land (33% for underinvested and 18% for other farms). Similarly, plant-protection costs per hectare were higher in other farms throughout the study period but followed a downward trend (a decline of more than 20% between 2020 and 2019). The cost intensity of plant protection was smaller in underinvested farms each year but remained at a near-constant level during the whole study period.
As regards users of investment support (Table 4), fertilization efficiency and environmental efficiency of plant protection use were found to have decreased (by 19% and 24%, respectively) in farms at optimum investment levels. Conversely, an increase in these costs was recorded in members of the “absolute overinvestment” group and in underinvested holdings. As shown by previous research [55], farms that demonstrate absolute overinvestment also prove to be the least technically efficient ones. It is particularly interesting that the differences in fertilization efficiency and environmental efficiency of plant protection use between groups grow over the years. In 2019, the highest levels were recorded both in underinvested farms and in members of the “absolute overinvestment” group. Conversely, the most beneficial values are found on farms at optimum investment levels with no increase in the assets-to-labor ratio, and in optimum holdings. It can therefore be seen that (just like in Table 2) rational investment goes hand in hand with rational production. This may be due to several reasons. First, it could be the consequence of the owners having generally greater economic and agricultural knowledge and being able to concurrently invest and run production processes in a skillful way. As regards underinvested farms, that condition can also result from the absence of adequate equipment. The above is not true for members of the “absolute overinvestment” group which, by definition, have access to equipment. However, they make inefficient use of it, at least when it comes to plant fertilization and protection.
As regards investment-support users, fertilization costs follow a clear upward trend at each investment level (Table 5). However, there were quite considerable differences between them every year. Each time, the highest values were found in the “relative overinvestment” group, and the lowest in farms at optimum investment levels with no increase in the assets-to-labor ratio. In the latter case, however, low cost-intensity levels go hand in hand with the smallest fertilization value per hectare.
Plant-protection costs grow at all levels considered in this study (with the fastest rates being recorded in the “absolute overinvestment” and “underinvestment” groups) and differ between the levels. Just like in the case of fertilization, the greatest plant-protection costs per hectare are borne by members of the relative overinvestment group and the smallest by holdings at optimum investment levels with no increase in the assets-to-labor ratio.
As regards nonusers of investment support, fertilization efficiency, that is the ratio between fertilization costs and production (Table 6), grows only in members of the “absolute overinvestment” group (by 36%) and in underinvested farms (by 44%). In the “relative overinvestment” class, it dropped by 14% and remained unchanged in other groups. Nevertheless, throughout the study period, the greatest cost intensity was found in members of the absolute and relative overinvestment groups, and the smallest in optimum farms (whether with or without an increase in the assets-to-labor ratio). This is similar to what was witnessed in users of investment support. Once again, there is a noticeable correlation between strategic and ongoing rationality. Holdings that invest either too little or too much demonstrate the highest—and consistently growing—ratio between fertilization costs and production value. In turn, optimum investors know how to optimize that variable (at least compared to what is seen in other farms covered by this study) and keep it at low levels. Moreover, just like in users of investment support, optimum farms (whether with or without an increase in the assets-to-labor ratio) attained high levels of fertilization efficiency at the relatively lowest costs per hectare of agricultural land (Table 7). While a similar pattern is true for the environmental efficiency of plant protection use, that is a relationship between plant-protection costs and production value, and only members of the “absolute overinvestment” group saw a growth rate of 17%. However, in this case, the highest costs are incurred in the absolute and relative overinvestment groups and the smallest (around half smaller) in farms at optimum investment levels. Hence, this is yet another example of a correlation between strategic and operational rationality.
The analysis of nonusers of investment support (Table 7) showed that their fertilization costs per hectare of land follow a pattern similar to that of investment-support users. The greatest increase was recorded in members of the “absolute overinvestment” group (but also in farms at optimum investment levels), and the smallest in the “relative overinvestment” class. Also, just like in other cases, members of the absolute and relative overinvestment groups incurred the greatest costs each year, with the former experiencing much higher growth (54% and 10%, respectively). Nevertheless, an increase in fertilization costs per hectare was recorded in all groups covered by this study in 2010–2019.
Even though the increase in the consumption of plant-protection products is less significant, it follows the same trend as fertilizer use. Therefore, the greatest growth was recorded in members of the “absolute overinvestment” group, and the smallest in the “relative overinvestment” group. Just like in the case of fertilization, the greatest plant-protection costs per hectare are borne by members of the absolute and relative overinvestment groups, which, at the same time (especially in the initial years of the analysis), demonstrate the highest cost intensity of plant protection (Table 6). In turn, the lowest costs per hectare are reported by optimum holdings and go hand in hand with the smallest cost intensity.

4. Conclusions

Poland’s accession to the EU in 2004 enabled the farms to access a series of support programs under the CAP. The agricultural sector’s development capacity mostly relied on those focused on modernization. One of the social and microeconomic goals of support was to make state-of-the-art equipment an enabler of rationalized use of industrial productive inputs. For society, it was important to reduce ground and surface water pollution, adverse impacts on biodiversity, and, last but not least, greenhouse-gas emissions. In turn, the farmers sought the maximization of economic effects (mainly incomes), including by minimizing the cost intensity of production. However, in some cases, the nonrepayable nature of aid contributed to overinvestment, defined as an increase in the assets-to-labor ratio in a situation where the related growth in labor productivity is either absent (absolute overinvestment) or disproportionately small (relative overinvestment). Also, there were farms that did not make any investments, mostly because of their small area and due to the owners’ sense of being uncompetitive. Only the situations where the increase in labor productivity was accompanied by growth in the value of assets can be referred to as optimum investment. Therefore, a research project was launched to show the relationship between strategic rationality (reflected by specific investment levels) and operational rationality, represented as the amount of plant fertilization and protection costs per hectare and per PLN 1 worth of production. In all cases covered by this study, i.e., in both users and nonusers of support, the lowest costs intensity of both fertilization and plant protection were recorded by optimum farms, irrespective of whether they did or did not witness an increase in the assets-to-labor ratio. A similar pattern was also found in members of the “relative overinvestment” group, which can be explained by a large scale of investments made within a short time frame. Furthermore, as shown by previous research [57], these farms demonstrate good economic performance. The methodology used in this study to determine the investment levels indicates that they will shift to optimum investment levels in the near future. It is the opposite for members of the “absolute overinvestment” group, although underinvested farms also demonstrated poor performance in that respect. As an equally important aspect from an economic and environmental point of view, high efficiency of plant fertilization and protection usually involved low costs per hectare of agricultural land. A different situation was only found in noninvesting farms. The above means that strategic management (investment) skills go hand in hand with competent operational management (cost optimization). It cannot be fully explained by the fact that state-of-the-art equipment enables a more technologically precise (i.e., more cost effective) use of industrial yield boosters. Indeed, members of the “absolute overinvestment” group also own such equipment but demonstrate the lowest efficiency of all groups covered by the analysis. Hence, the ultimate reason could be the difference in economic knowledge and farming skills, as mentioned above. This, in turn, provides grounds for certain recommendations for agricultural policy at both the national and EU levels. Even though the patterns analyzed in this paper are found in both users and nonusers of investment support, the grant of that kind of aid should be preceded by a more restrictive analysis of investment efficiency, including in terms of the farm’s ability to optimize future operating costs. Moreover, advisory (mostly delivered by public operators) should focus more on the capacity to reduce the costs of using industrial yield boosters with no detriment to yields and production value. The above is an issue of microeconomic importance to producers and of environmental importance to society. The importance of advisory is particularly relevant today when changes are occurring particularly rapidly (many times in the life of one generation), which makes school education insufficient [58]. In the context of the research conducted, attention should be paid to the development of new production technologies (including precision agriculture), which can help in the rational use of yield factors but require large investments. Hence, education and counseling should be comprehensive, covering both agricultural issues (use of yield boosters) and economic issues (appropriate level of investment) in their relationship.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, J.Z., A.S. and N.G.; methodology, J.Z. and A.S.; software, J.Z.; validation, J.Z., A.S. and N.G.; formal analysis, J.Z., A.S. and N.G.; investigation, J.Z., A.S. and N.G.; resources, J.Z.; data curation, J.Z.; writing—original draft preparation, J.Z., A.S. and N.G.; writing—review and editing, J.Z. and N.G.; visualization, J.Z.; supervision, J.Z.; project administration, J.Z.; funding acquisition, J.Z. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research was funded by the National Science Centre, Poland, grant number 2021/41/N/HS4/00443.

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

Not applicable.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Abbreviations

ALR: assets-to-labor ratio; AWU: total labor inputs; EGD: European Green Deal; EEPP: environmental efficiency of plant-protection products use; FC: fertilization costs; FE: fertilization efficiency; LP: labor productivity; PLN: polish zloty; PPC: plant-protection costs; SCPP: consumption scale of plant-protection products.

References

  1. Caparrós, M. El Hambre; Editorial Anagrama; Random House: Barcelona, Spain, 2014; pp. 324–350. [Google Scholar]
  2. Mrówczyńska-Kamińska, A. The direction of agribusiness development in the European Union countries (Kierunek rozwoju agrobiznesu w krajach Unii Europejskiej). Ann. Pol. Assoc. Agric. Agribus. Econ. 2017, 19, 182–189. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  3. Ziegler, J. Destruction Massive; Geopolitique de la Faim; Contemporary French Fiction; SEUIL: Paris, France, 2011; pp. 51–130. [Google Scholar]
  4. Alexandratos, N.; Bruinsma, J. World Agriculture towards 2030/2050: The 2012 Revision; ESA Working Paper No. 12-03; FAO: Rome, Italy, 2012; pp. 94–131. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Van Kernebeek, H.R.; Oosting, S.J.; Van Ittersum, M.K.; Bikker, P.; De Boer, I.J. Saving land to feed a growing population: Consequences for consumption of crop and livestock products. Int. J. Life Cycle Assess. 2016, 21, 677–687. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  6. Savci, S. Investigation of effect of chemical fertilizers on environment. Apcbee Procedia 2012, 1, 287–292. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  7. Abdulai, A.N.; Abdulai, A. Examining the impact of conservation agriculture on environmental efficiency among maize farmers in Zambia. Environ. Dev. Econ. 2017, 22, 177–201. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  8. Feltirizers Europe. Fertilizer Industry Facts & Figures. 2022. Available online: https://www.fertilizerseurope.com/wp-content/uploads/2022/09/Industry-Facts-and-Figures-2022.pdf (accessed on 11 November 2022).
  9. Polityka Insight. Impact of the European Green Deal on Polish Agriculture Report; Polityka Insight: Warsaw, Poland, 2021. [Google Scholar]
  10. Carvalho, F.P. Pesticides, environment, and food safety. Food and energy security. Food Energy Secur. 2017, 6, 48–60. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Eliasson, K.; West, C.D.; Croft, S.A.; Green, J.M. A spatially explicit approach to assessing commodity-driven fertilizer use and its impact on biodiversity. J. Clean. Prod. 2023, 382, 135195. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Arslan, A.; McCarthy, N.; Lipper, L.; Asfaw, S.; Cattaneo, A.; Kokwe, M. Climate smart agriculture? Assessing the adaptation implications in Zambia. J. Agric. Econ. 2015, 66, 753–780. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Feltirizers Europe. Overwiew 2021/22. Available online: https://www.fertilizerseurope.com/wp-content/uploads/2022/06/FER-AR22-web-Single.pdf (accessed on 11 November 2022).
  14. Bashir, M.; Ali, S.; Ghauri, M.; Adris, A.; Harun, R. Impact of excessive nitrogen fertilizers on the environment and associated mitigation strategies. Asian J. Microbiol. Biotechnol. Environ. Sci. 2013, 15, 213–221. [Google Scholar]
  15. Ramaswamy, V.; Boucher, O.; Haigh, J.; Hauglustaine, D.; Haywood, J.; Myhre, G.; Nakajima, T.; Shi, G.Y.; Solomon, S. Radiative forcing of climate change. In Climate Change 2001: The Scientific Basis; Houghton, J.T., Ding, Y., Griggs, D.J., Noguer, M., van der Linden, P.J., Dai, X., Maskell, K., Johnson, C.A., Eds.; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 2021; pp. 349–416. [Google Scholar]
  16. Parkin, T.B.; Kaspar, T.C. Nitrous oxide emissions from corn–soybean systems in the Midwest. J. Environ. Qual. 2006, 35, 1496–1506. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
  17. Schlesinger, W.H. On the fate of anthropogenic nitrogen. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2009, 106, 203–208. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Craswell, E. Fertilizers and nitrate pollution of surface and ground water: An increasingly pervasive global problem. SN Appl. Sci. 2021, 3, 1–24. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Camargo, J.A.; Alonso, Á. Ecological and toxicological effects of inorganic nitrogen pollution in aquatic ecosystems: A global assessment. Environ. Int. 2006, 32, 831–849. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Mulvaney, R.L.; Khan, S.A.; Ellsworth, T.R. Synthetic nitrogen fertilizers deplete soil nitrogen: A global dilemma for sustainable cereal production. J. Environ. Qual. 2009, 38, 2295–2314. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  21. Pahalvi, H.N.; Rafiya, L.; Rashid, S.; Nisar, B.; Kamili, A.N. Chemical Fertilizers and Their Impact on Soil Health. In Microbiota and Biofertilizers, Vol 2: Ecofriendly Tools for Reclamation of Degraded Soil Environs; Dar, G.H., Bhat, R.A., Mehmood, M.A., Hakeem, K.R., Eds.; Springer International Publishing: Cham, Switzerland, 2021; pp. 1–20. [Google Scholar]
  22. Gottlieb, R.; Fisher, A. Community food security and environmental justice: Searching for a common discourse. Agric. Hum. Values 1996, 13, 23–32. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Zhang, F.; Cui, Z.; Chen, X.; Ju, X.; Shen, J.; Chen, Q.; Liu, X.; Zhang, W.; Mi, G.; Fan, M.; et al. Integrated nutrient management for food security and environmental quality in China. Adv. Agron. 2012, 116, 1–40. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Montanarella, L.; Panagos, P. The relevance of sustainable soil management within the European Green Deal. Land Use Policy 2021, 100, 104950. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Hannam, I.; Boer, B. Legal and Institutional Frameworks for Sustainable Soils: A Preliminary Report (No. 45); IUCN: GeIUCN, Gland, Switzerland and Cambridge, UK in Collaboration with IUCN Environmental Law Centre, Bonn, Germany” 2002; pp. 9–40. Available online: https://www.iucn.org/resources/publication/legal-and-institutional-frameworks-sustainable-soils-preliminary-report (accessed on 9 July 2023).
  26. Panagos, P.; Borrelli, P.; Poesen, J.; Ballabio, C.; Lugato, E.; Meusburger, K.; Montanarella, L.; Alewell, C. The new assessment of soil loss by water erosion in Europe. Environ. Sci. Policy 2015, 54, 438–447. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Panagos, P.; Imeson, A.; Meusburger, K.; Borrelli, P.; Poesen, J.; Alewell, C. Soil conservation in Europe: Wish or reality? Land Degrad. Dev. 2016, 27, 1547–1551. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  28. IPCC. Climate Change 2022. Mitigation of Climate Change. Available online: https://www.ipcc.ch/report/ar6/wg3/downloads/report/IPCC_AR6_WGIII_FullReport.pdf (accessed on 27 July 2023).
  29. Idowu, J.; Ghimire, R.; Flynn, R.; Ganguli, A. Soil Health: Importance, Assessment, and Management; College of Agricultural, Consumer and Environmental Sciences: Urbana, IL, USA, 2019. [Google Scholar]
  30. Zulfiqar, F.; Navarro, M.; Ashraf, M.; Akram, N.A.; Munné-Bosch, S. Nanofertilizer use for sustainable agriculture: Advantages and limitations. Plant Sci. 2019, 289, 110270. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Czyżewski, B.; Matuszczak, A. Determinants of price scissors in agriculture of the European Union countries with different agrarian structure (Determinanty nożyc cen w rolnictwie krajów Unii Europejskiej o zróżnicowanej strukturze agrarnej). Village Agric. 2016, 3, 7–40. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Ben Hassen, T.; El Bilali, H. Impacts of the Russia-Ukraine war on global food security: Towards more sustainable and resilient food systems? Foods 2022, 11, 2301. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Mottaleb, K.A.; Kruseman, G.; Snapp, S. Potential impacts of Ukraine-Russia armed conflict on global wheat food security: A quantitative exploration. Glob. Food Secur. 2022, 35, 100659. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Cillero, M.M.; Reaños, M.T. Farm technical and environmental efficiency and subsidy redistribution in Ireland: A simulation approach of possible performance and equity effects. J. Agric. Econ. 2022, 74, 394–412. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Johnson, C.; Sierra, A.R.; Dettmer, J.; Sidiropoulou, K.; Zicmane, E.; Canalis, A.; Llorente, P.; Paiano, P.; Mengal, P.; Puzzolo, V. The Bio-Based Industries Joint Undertaking as a catalyst for a green transition in Europe under the European Green Deal. EFB Bioeconomy J. 2021, 1, 100014. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Bieroza, M.Z.; Bol, R.; Glendell, M. What is the deal with the Green Deal: Will the new strategy help to improve European freshwater quality beyond the Water Framework Directive? Sci. Total Environ. 2021, 791, 148080. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  37. Di Stefano, C.; Nicosia, A.; Pampalone, V.; Ferro, V. Soil loss tolerance in the context of the European Green Deal. Heliyon 2023, 9, e12869. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Wrzaszcz, W.; Prandecki, K. Agriculture and the European Green Deal (Rolnictwo a Europejski Zielony Ład). Probl. Agric. Econ. 2020, 365, 156–179. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Fayet, C.M.; Reilly, K.H.; Van Ham, C.; Verburg, P.H. The potential of European abandoned agricultural lands to contribute to the Green Deal objectives: Policy perspectives. Environ. Sci. Policy 2022, 133, 44–53. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Farm to Fork Strategy. Available online: https://food.ec.europa.eu/horizontal-topics/farm-fork-strategy_en (accessed on 24 March 2023).
  41. Heuser, I. Soil Governance in current European Union Law and in the European Green Deal. Soil Secur. 2022, 6, 100053. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Arias-Estévez, M.; López-Periago, E.; Martínez-Carballo, E.; Simal-Gándara, J.; Mejuto, J.C.; García-Río, L. The mobility and degradation of pesticides in soils and the pollution of groundwater resources. Agric. Ecosyst. Environ. 2008, 123, 247–260. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Hasegawa, T.; Fujimori, S.; Shin, Y.; Tanaka, A.; Takahashi, K.; Masui, T. Consequence of climate mitigation on the risk of hunger. Environ. Sci. Technol. 2015, 49, 7245–7253. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  44. Baldock, D.; Buckwell, A. Just Transition in the EU Agriculture and Land Use Sector, Institute for European Environmental Policy. 2021. Available online: https://ieep.eu/publications/just-transition-in-the-eu-agriculture-and-land-use-sector/ (accessed on 15 December 2022).
  45. Henning, H.; Witzke, P. Economic and Environmental impacts of the Green Deal on the Agricultural Economy: A Simulation Study of the Impact of the F2F-Strategy on Production, Trade, Welfare and the Environment based on the CAPRI-Model. 2021. Available online: https://grain-club.de/fileadmin/user_upload/Dokumente/Farm_to_fork_Studie_Executive_Summary_EN.pdf (accessed on 24 April 2023).
  46. Zmyślona, J.; Sadowski, A. Overinvestment in polish agriculture. In Proceedings of the 2019 International Scientific Conference ‘Economic Sciences for Agribusiness and Rural Economy, Warsaw, Poland, 5–7 June 2019; Warsaw University of Life Sciences Press: Warsaw, Poland, 2019; Volume 3, pp. 152–154. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  47. Bezat-Jarzębowska, A.; Rembisz, W. Introduction to the Analysis of Investment, Productivity, Efficiency and Technical Change in Agriculture (Wprowadzenie do Analizy Inwestycji, Produktywności, Efektywności i Zmian Technicznych w Rolnictwie); Instytut Ekonomiki Rolnictwa i Gospodarki Żywnościowej-Państwowy Instytut Badawczy: Warsaw, Poland, 2015. [Google Scholar]
  48. Wei ZH, U.; Qi, L.X.; Wang, R.M. The relationship between farm size and fertilizer use efficiency: Evidence from China. J. Integr. Agric. 2022, 21, 273–281. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Yang, J.; Lin, Y. Driving factors of total-factor substitution efficiency of chemical fertilizer input and related environmental regulation policy: A case study of Zhejiang Province. Environ. Pollut. 2020, 263, 114541. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  50. Johnson, J.M.; Ibrahim, A.; Dossou-Yovo, E.R.; Senthilkumar, K.; Tsujimoto, Y.; Asai, H.; Saito, K. Inorganic fertilizer use and its association with rice yield gaps in sub-Saharan Africa. Glob. Food Secur. 2023, 38, 100708. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Yu, X.; Schweikert, K.; Li, Y.; Ma, J.; Doluschitz, R. Farm size, farmers’ perceptions and chemical fertilizer overuse in grain production: Evidence from maize farmers in northern China. J. Environ. Manag. 2023, 325, 116347. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Stoicea, P.; Chiurciu, I.A.; Soare, E.; Iorga, A.M.; Dinu, T.A.; Tudor, V.C.; Gîdea, M.; David, L. Impact of reducing fertilizers and pesticides on sunflower production in Romania versus EU countries. Sustainability 2022, 14, 8334. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Frank, S.; Havlík, P.; Soussana, J.F.; Levesque, A.; Valin, H.; Wollenberg, E.; Kleinwechter, U.; Fricko, O.; Gusti, M.; Herrero, M. Reducing greenhouse gas emissions in agriculture without compromising food security? Environ. Res. Lett. 2017, 12, 105004. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Khanal, U.; Wilson, C.; Rahman, S.; Lee, B.L.; Hoang, V.N. Smallholder farmers’ adaptation to climate change and its potential contribution to UN’s sustainable development goals of zero hunger and no poverty. J. Clean. Prod. 2021, 281, 124999. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Pawłowski, K.P.; Czubak, W.; Zmyślona, J.; Sadowski, A. Overinvestment in selected Central and Eastern European countries: Production and economic effects. PLoS ONE 2021, 16, e0251394. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Wojewodzic, T. Divestments in farms—Essence, definitions, division (Dywestycje w gospodarstwach rolnych–istota, definicje, podział). Village Agric. 2010, 2, 96–108. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Pawłowski, K.P.; Czubak, W.; Zmyślona, J. Regional Diversity of Technical Efficiency in Agriculture as a Results of an Overinvestment: A Case Study from Poland. Energies 2021, 14, 3357. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Sadowski, A. Agriculture in the world of change—Challenges for advice. Zagadnienia Doradz. Rol. 2020, 4, 7–19. [Google Scholar]
Figure 1. Conceptual Framework (the number of farms covered by the analysis is specified in brackets). Source: own compilation.
Figure 1. Conceptual Framework (the number of farms covered by the analysis is specified in brackets). Source: own compilation.
Agriculture 13 01567 g001
Table 1. Average farm area (ha per farm) grouped by overinvestment level and propensity to invest in 2010–2019.
Table 1. Average farm area (ha per farm) grouped by overinvestment level and propensity to invest in 2010–2019.
PeriodT0T1T2T3T4T4 − T0T0 = 100%
noninvesting farms
underinvested21.3320.9120.1819.9219.07−2.26−11%
other26.9822.3721.7020.9120.10−6.88−26%
farms that invest and access investment support
underinvested49.8251.7853.1653.5253.854.038%
optimum investment, no increase in ALR35.2737.5239.4942.0742.897.6222%
optimum investment, increase in LP and ALR64.863.8466.0369.4171.847.0411%
absolute55.4557.5059.3461.6763.287.8314%
relative67.9769.468.3968.8370.342.373%
farms which do not access investment support
underinvested33.8733.7133.7633.9233.82−0.050%
optimum investment, no increase in ALR30.3530.5931.5133.0334.253.9013%
optimum investment, increase in LP and ALR28.4430.1231.2433.4035.777.3326%
absolute52.3152.8551.3051.2250.81−1.50−3%
relative82.6783.9284.2485.4487.424.756%
Source: own compilation based on the FADN microdata base, n = 3273.
Table 2. Relationship between plant fertilization and protection costs, and production value (FE and EEPP) in noninvesting farms in 2010–2019 (PLN).
Table 2. Relationship between plant fertilization and protection costs, and production value (FE and EEPP) in noninvesting farms in 2010–2019 (PLN).
Fertilization
YearUnderinvestedOther
20100.090.09
20110.090.11
20120.100.09
20130.110.11
20140.120.10
20150.140.12
20160.130.10
20170.120.09
20180.130.10
20190.140.10
2010 = 100152110
Plant Protection
YearUnderinvestedOther
20100.040.05
20110.040.05
20120.040.04
20130.040.04
20140.050.05
20150.050.04
20160.050.04
20170.040.04
20180.050.04
20190.050.04
2019 = 10011873
Source: own compilation based on the FADN microdata base, n = 3273.
Table 3. Average plant fertilization and protection costs in relation to land area owned (FC and PPC) by noninvesting farms in 2010–2019 (PLN/ha).
Table 3. Average plant fertilization and protection costs in relation to land area owned (FC and PPC) by noninvesting farms in 2010–2019 (PLN/ha).
Fertilization
YearUnderinvestedOther
2010433534
2011503639
2012576616
2013597660
2014616618
2015626652
2016568617
2017566590
2018573597
2019578633
2010 = 100133118
Plant Protection
YearUnderinvestedOther
2010187305
2011205304
2012213250
2013229272
2014246269
2015214243
2016213234
2017211245
2018201220
2019193240
2010 = 10010379
Source: own compilation based on the FADN microdata base, n = 3273.
Table 4. Relationship between plant fertilization and protection costs and production value (FE and EEPP in investing farms that accessed investment support in 2010–2019 (PLN).
Table 4. Relationship between plant fertilization and protection costs and production value (FE and EEPP in investing farms that accessed investment support in 2010–2019 (PLN).
Fertilization
YearUnderinvestedOptimumOptimum Investment with No Increase in ALRAbsoluteRelative
20100.10 0.10 0.06 0.11 0.10
20110.10 0.10 0.07 0.11 0.12
20120.11 0.10 0.07 0.12 0.11
20130.12 0.10 0.07 0.12 0.12
20140.13 0.10 0.08 0.14 0.13
20150.13 0.11 0.08 0.15 0.13
20160.14 0.10 0.08 0.15 0.14
20170.12 0.09 0.07 0.13 0.11
20180.13 0.08 0.07 0.14 0.10
20190.13 0.08 0.07 0.14 0.10
2010 = 1001358111412196
Plant Protection
YearUnderinvestedOptimumOptimum Investment with No Increase in ALRAbsoluteRelative
20100.05 0.05 0.03 0.05 0.07
20110.04 0.05 0.03 0.05 0.07
20120.04 0.04 0.03 0.05 0.06
20130.05 0.04 0.03 0.06 0.06
20140.06 0.04 0.03 0.06 0.07
20150.06 0.04 0.03 0.06 0.08
20160.06 0.04 0.03 0.07 0.07
20170.06 0.04 0.03 0.06 0.07
20180.06 0.03 0.03 0.07 0.05
20190.06 0.04 0.03 0.06 0.05
2010 = 100123749511878
Source: own compilation based on the FADN microdata base, n = 3273.
Table 5. Average plant fertilization and protection costs in relation to land area owned (FC and PPC) by investing farms that accessed investment support in 2010–2019 (PLN/ha).
Table 5. Average plant fertilization and protection costs in relation to land area owned (FC and PPC) by investing farms that accessed investment support in 2010–2019 (PLN/ha).
Fertilization
YearUnderinvestedOptimumOptimum Investment with No Increase in ALRAbsoluteRelative
2010557 648 496 625 713
2011665 759 586 714 843
2012804 928 657 872 938
2013838 1005 745 846 1070
2014859 941 741 919 1087
2015830 976 739 911 1078
2016849 912 673 908 1078
2017802 872 707 838 965
2018783 859 697 823 929
2019832 914 766 860 966
2010 = 100149141154138135
Plant Protection
YearUnderinvestedOptimumOptimum Investment with No Increase in ALRAbsoluteRelative
2010279 322 230 296 469
2011287 362 249 335 490
2012315 399 251 347 509
2013342 393 279 388 547
2014376 419 289 407 600
2015343 381 273 373 609
2016375 382 259 403 558
2017384 389 257 408 567
2018355 351 264 400 472
2019379 412 295 395 514
2010 = 100136128129133109
Source: own compilation based on the FADN microdata base, n = 3273.
Table 6. Relationship between plant fertilization and protection costs and production value (FE and EEPP), in investing farms that did not access investment support in 2010–2019 (PLN).
Table 6. Relationship between plant fertilization and protection costs and production value (FE and EEPP), in investing farms that did not access investment support in 2010–2019 (PLN).
Fertilization
YearUnderinvestedOptimumOptimum Investment with No Increase in ALRAbsoluteRelative
20100.09 0.08 0.08 0.11 0.14
20110.09 0.08 0.08 0.12 0.15
20120.09 0.08 0.09 0.13 0.18
20130.10 0.09 0.09 0.14 0.18
20140.11 0.09 0.10 0.14 0.14
20150.11 0.09 0.10 0.16 0.14
20160.11 0.09 0.09 0.15 0.11
20170.10 0.08 0.08 0.14 0.12
20180.11 0.08 0.08 0.15 0.10
20190.13 0.08 0.08 0.15 0.12
2010 = 10014410010013686
Plant Protection
YearUnderinvestedOptimumOptimum Investment with No Increase in ALRAbsoluteRelative
20100.05 0.03 0.04 0.06 0.06
20110.04 0.03 0.04 0.06 0.06
20120.04 0.03 0.04 0.06 0.05
20130.04 0.03 0.04 0.06 0.06
20140.05 0.03 0.05 0.07 0.05
20150.05 0.03 0.04 0.07 0.05
20160.05 0.03 0.04 0.07 0.04
20170.04 0.03 0.04 0.07 0.05
20180.05 0.03 0.04 0.07 0.04
20190.05 0.03 0.04 0.07 0.05
2010 = 10010010010011783
Source: own compilation based on the FADN microdata base, n = 3273.
Table 7. Average plant fertilization and protection costs in relation to land area owned (FC and PPC) by investing farms that did not access investment support in 2010–2019 (PLN/ha).
Table 7. Average plant fertilization and protection costs in relation to land area owned (FC and PPC) by investing farms that did not access investment support in 2010–2019 (PLN/ha).
Fertilization
YearUnderinvestedOptimumOptimum Investment with No Increase in ALRAbsoluteRelative
2010502 522 490 584 692
2011573 586 574 702 933
2012658 695 681 862 1114
2013711 781 733 876 1086
2014705 747 743 845 915
2015691 771 691 917 850
2016653 713 662 884 749
2017642 697 660 866 756
2018670 726 624 844 730
2019745 826 689 901 762
2010 = 100148158141154110
Plant Protection
YearUnderinvestedOptimumOptimum Investment with No Increase in ALRAbsoluteRelative
2010251 209 256 293 315
2011259 227 272 335 374
2012286 254 271 383 338
2013305 264 294 398 337
2014305 276 347 423 347
2015295 263 294 411 329
2016287 273 275 394 276
2017286 282 320 405 333
2018292 261 289 365 287
2019291 266 295 381 325
2010 = 100116128115130103
Source: own compilation based on the FADN microdata base, n = 3273.
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Zmyślona, J.; Sadowski, A.; Genstwa, N. Plant Protection and Fertilizer Use Efficiency in Farms in a Context of Overinvestment: A Case Study from Poland. Agriculture 2023, 13, 1567. https://doi.org/10.3390/agriculture13081567

AMA Style

Zmyślona J, Sadowski A, Genstwa N. Plant Protection and Fertilizer Use Efficiency in Farms in a Context of Overinvestment: A Case Study from Poland. Agriculture. 2023; 13(8):1567. https://doi.org/10.3390/agriculture13081567

Chicago/Turabian Style

Zmyślona, Jagoda, Arkadiusz Sadowski, and Natalia Genstwa. 2023. "Plant Protection and Fertilizer Use Efficiency in Farms in a Context of Overinvestment: A Case Study from Poland" Agriculture 13, no. 8: 1567. https://doi.org/10.3390/agriculture13081567

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop