Next Article in Journal
NATCA YOLO-Based Small Object Detection for Aerial Images
Previous Article in Journal
Exploring the Factors in the Discontinuation of a Talent Pool Information System: A Case Study of an EduTech Startup in Indonesia
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

The Physics of Preference: Unravelling Imprecision of Human Preferences through Magnetisation Dynamics

by
Ivan S. Maksymov
1,* and
Ganna Pogrebna
1,2,3
1
Artificial Intelligence and Cyber Futures Institute, Charles Sturt University, Bathurst, NSW 2795, Australia
2
The Alan Turing Institute, British Library, London NW1 2DB, UK
3
The University of Sydney Business School, University of Sydney, Darlington, NSW 2006, Australia
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Information 2024, 15(7), 413; https://doi.org/10.3390/info15070413
Submission received: 12 June 2024 / Revised: 13 July 2024 / Accepted: 14 July 2024 / Published: 18 July 2024

Abstract

:
Paradoxical decision-making behaviours such as preference reversal often arise from imprecise or noisy human preferences. Harnessing the physical principle of magnetisation reversal in ferromagnetic nanostructures, we developed a model that closely reflects human decision-making dynamics. Tested against a spectrum of psychological data, our model adeptly captures the complexities inherent in individual choices. This blend of physics and psychology paves the way for fresh perspectives on understanding the imprecision of human decision-making processes, extending the reach of the current classical and quantum physical models of human behaviour and decision making.

1. Introduction

Theoretical and experimental research in economics and psychology posits that human preferences are inherently noisy and imprecise [1] (see [2,3,4,5,6] for definitions of noise and imprecision as well as detailed reviews of the relevant literature). For example, such phenomena as Allais paradox, Ellsberg paradox, endowment effect and preference reversal (PR) demonstrate that human decisions deviate from the predictions of traditional rational models [7]. These deviations follow certain patterns [3]. While the classical theory suggests that individuals consistently maximise their utility based on stable preferences, experiments present robust evidence that human choices under risk and uncertainty are often inconsistent or even contradictory [8,9,10].
The PR phenomenon is a robust behavioural regularity [10] observed in a variety of domains. PR was first observed in the gambling studies involving [11]: (i) a choice task, where people were asked to decide between a relatively safe lottery with a low payoff (probability- or P-bet) and a relatively risky lottery with a high payoff (dollar- or $-bet) as well as (ii) a valuation task, where the same people were asked to indicate lottery prices if they were to sell P-bet and $-bet. The observed people’s preferences were often paradoxical: while opting for the P-bet in the binary choice, they were putting a higher price on the $-bet, thereby indicating a preference for P-bet in a simple two-option choice, but preference for $-bet when stating their certainty equivalents for both options.
Alongside other behavioural regularities (see, e.g., [10,12]), PR has reshaped contemporary discourse in both economics and psychology. Traditional deterministic models such as expected utility theory (EUT), which held that individual choices were reflective of consistent and stable preferences, have been challenged by empirical findings [3,13]. Furthermore, recent research demonstrated that preference reversals constitute a challenge for many stochastic decision theories (e.g., when decision theories such as expected utility theory or cumulative prospect theory are embedded into models of stochastic choice such as the Fechner model) [3,14]. The latter approach has demonstrated that individual choices under risk are probabilistic rather than deterministic, i.e., the same person may make different choices when presented with the same problem multiple times. Experiments show that people’s decisions to accept or reject sure payoff amounts in exchange for a risky lottery varies from consistently selecting bet over cash (when the sure payoff amounts offered against the lottery are not sufficiently attractive) to consistently selecting cash over bet (when the sure payoff amounts increase) with some imprecision interval in-between, when individuals make probabilistic choices between cash and the bet [3,14,15,16]. The existence of such paradoxes implied that human decision making was more multifaceted than previously assumed.
Understanding and accurately predicting these anomalies is not merely an academic exercise. As policy makers strive to devise strategies and interventions that depend on opinion polls, the need for models predicting human behaviour is pressing. Yet, capturing the essence of phenomena like PR within traditional deterministic and stochastic models remains a challenge. For example, many deterministic and stochastic decision theories honour the transitivity axiom, which posits that, if an individual prefers A to B and B to C, then they should prefer A to C. However, PR defies the transitivity, suggesting that human preferences might be imprecise [14,17].
This instigates debates on the need to (i) reconsider some axioms of decision theory [4,17]; (ii) devise theories relaxing transitivity assumption [18]; (iii) embed decision theories into models of noise-synthesising stochastic versions of known theories [9]; and (iv) develop further models that assume inherently imprecise human preferences [3].
While these debates are ongoing, it has been noticed that physical processes can adequately describe many psychological effects and decision-making phenomena (e.g., quantum logic has been previously applied by social psychologists to model decision making under risk and uncertainty using the models of quantum cognition [5,19]). Furthermore, there exist classical physical models of confirmation bias [20], public opinion formation [21,22,23], preference [24,25], and backfire effect [26]. Thermodynamic models of decision-making where information processing is represented as changes in the states of a thermodynamical system and quantified by differences in free energy have also been proposed [27,28,29,30].
The quantum-mechanical models of decision-making [31,32,33,34] that originate from the quantum mind hypothesis [35,36] have been developed following a suggestion that the human mental states can be represented as a combination of two binary states ‘0’ and ‘1’ [31,33,37]. Mathematically and physically, such a representation corresponds to a superposition of the basis quantum-mechanical states | 0 and | 1 employed in quantum computers.
Instead of binary bits, a quantum computer uses a quantum bit (qubit) that corresponds to the states | 0 = 1 0 and | 1 = 0 1 . Unlike the ‘0’ and ‘1’ binary states of a classical digital computer, the states of a qubit are a superposition | ψ = α | 0 + β | 1 with | α | 2 + | β | 2 = 1 . As part of a quantum measurement, a qubit interacts in a controlled way with an external system from which the state of the qubit under measurement can be obtained. For instance, using the projective measurement operators M 0 = | 0 0 | and M 1 = | 1 1 | [38], the measurement probabilities for | ψ = α | 0 + β | 1 become P | 0 = | α | 2 and P | 1 = | β | 2 . This measurement outcome means that the qubit will be in one of its basis states.
Quantum computational algorithms are exponentially faster than any possible classical computational algorithm [38]. Therefore, it has been shown that quantum mechanics can explain certain psychological and decision-making processes better than any classical model [33,37,39]. Those theoretical findings have been convincingly supported by a large and growing body of experimental research works that have examined diverse paradoxical phenomena of human behaviour such as the Allais Paradox and Ellsberg Paradox [40,41,42,43,44,45,46].
In this paper, we further extend the ability of physical models of decision making to capture the effect of preference imprecision, which often results in the preference reversals. In this pursuit, our paper not only strengthens the connection between the physics of magnetism and decision theory [23,47,48,49,50], but also provides a comprehensive evaluation of a real-life physical model against rich empirical datasets. In particular, apart from several traditionally designed decision-theoretic laboratory experiments involving lotteries, we validate our model using a dataset obtained from the “Deal or No Deal” video game based on the famous TV show.
As shown in Figure 1, while our Magnetisation Reversal model is capable of explaining phenomena previously discussed in decision-theoretic literature, it makes a novel contribution and is based on a completely different core principle contrasting with other theories. Given the novelty of our approach, the whole Figure 1 should be viewed mostly as an attempt to find a tentative place for our model in a general taxonomy of the existing decision theory models. For instance, although in Figure 1, we place our model near the quantum models of decision making, strictly speaking, our model is classical since the main equation of our model—the Landau–Lifshitz–Gilbert equation—is a classical phenomenological model that describes the quantum-mechanical phenomenon of magnetisation [51].
By definition, a phenomenological model seeks to represent the essential behaviour observed in the experiment not necessarily attempting to elucidate the origin of the effect using the existing theories [52]. Hence, our phenomenological model is concerned with reproducing certain decision-making data as they appear in our experience (e.g., visually) using the physical effect of magnetisation reversal. Specifically, we choose this effect because the magnetisation reversal curves closely resemble the empirical decision-making data discussed in this paper (e.g., compare the shapes of the probabilistic curve in Figure 2a and the magnetisation curves in Figure 2b).
Figure 1. Location of the proposed physical magnetisation reversal model on a diagram that evaluates the existing decision theory models using a 1–5 scale applied to such model characteristics as predictive capability, applicability, complexity, and interpretation, preference reversal explanation, and empirical validation. To obtain the relative scoring, we first compiled a detailed table of decision theories based on the comprehensive literature review and the content of the relevant papers. We then assigned a score based on table entries and plotted the resulting diagram based on the obtained scores. This diagram does not reflect the fact that the magnetisation reversal model is physically phenomenological, was developed independently of any other decision theory model, and is, de facto, unique, as further demonstrated in Figure 3. The software and raw data used to prepare Figure 1 can be accessed following the instructions given in the data availability section.
Figure 1. Location of the proposed physical magnetisation reversal model on a diagram that evaluates the existing decision theory models using a 1–5 scale applied to such model characteristics as predictive capability, applicability, complexity, and interpretation, preference reversal explanation, and empirical validation. To obtain the relative scoring, we first compiled a detailed table of decision theories based on the comprehensive literature review and the content of the relevant papers. We then assigned a score based on table entries and plotted the resulting diagram based on the obtained scores. This diagram does not reflect the fact that the magnetisation reversal model is physically phenomenological, was developed independently of any other decision theory model, and is, de facto, unique, as further demonstrated in Figure 3. The software and raw data used to prepare Figure 1 can be accessed following the instructions given in the data availability section.
Information 15 00413 g001
Figure 2. (a) Idealised deterministic (the dashed line) and probabilistic (the line with circular markers) PR curves. Examples of real-life data that resemble the shape of the idealised curve are given in Figure 4. (b) Representative simulated magnetisation reversal behaviour for different values of the static magnetic field H 0 . Additional physical details are presented in the main text and the caption to Figure 5. The shape of the probabilistic curve in panel (a) closely resembles the magnetisation curves in panel (b). Either a single magnetisation reversal curve or a judicious combination of several magnetisation reversal curves, as demonstrated in the main text, can approximate both the experimental curves in Figure 4 and a more complex dataset in Figure 6.
Figure 2. (a) Idealised deterministic (the dashed line) and probabilistic (the line with circular markers) PR curves. Examples of real-life data that resemble the shape of the idealised curve are given in Figure 4. (b) Representative simulated magnetisation reversal behaviour for different values of the static magnetic field H 0 . Additional physical details are presented in the main text and the caption to Figure 5. The shape of the probabilistic curve in panel (a) closely resembles the magnetisation curves in panel (b). Either a single magnetisation reversal curve or a judicious combination of several magnetisation reversal curves, as demonstrated in the main text, can approximate both the experimental curves in Figure 4 and a more complex dataset in Figure 6.
Information 15 00413 g002
Figure 3. Literature analysis-based taxonomy of decision making models complementing the data presented in Figure 1. The connection chart confirms the core-principle independence of our model (shown in red) of the previous theoretical approaches and establishes our model’s distinctiveness compared to other models. The graph demonstrates that while this paper deals with the same behavioural concepts as the previous literature (preference reversals), our approach is different from previously proposed in the literature. The network graph was produced in Python programming language by constructing a similarity index between the papers cited in this manuscript, based on keywords. To ensure robustness, results of our analysis for a subset of papers were cross-checked using the online Connected Papers tool. Our choice of a keyword-based similarity index over neural networks or machine learning models was driven by the need for transparency, interpretability and computational efficiency. While neural networks and machine learning offer advanced capabilities, their “black box” nature was not aligned with our study’s objectives. Our approach ensured clarity and reproducibility, effectively highlighting the distinctiveness of our model.
Figure 3. Literature analysis-based taxonomy of decision making models complementing the data presented in Figure 1. The connection chart confirms the core-principle independence of our model (shown in red) of the previous theoretical approaches and establishes our model’s distinctiveness compared to other models. The graph demonstrates that while this paper deals with the same behavioural concepts as the previous literature (preference reversals), our approach is different from previously proposed in the literature. The network graph was produced in Python programming language by constructing a similarity index between the papers cited in this manuscript, based on keywords. To ensure robustness, results of our analysis for a subset of papers were cross-checked using the online Connected Papers tool. Our choice of a keyword-based similarity index over neural networks or machine learning models was driven by the need for transparency, interpretability and computational efficiency. While neural networks and machine learning offer advanced capabilities, their “black box” nature was not aligned with our study’s objectives. Our approach ensured clarity and reproducibility, effectively highlighting the distinctiveness of our model.
Information 15 00413 g003
Figure 4. Experimental PR data of the five lotteries (each row of the figure corresponds to an independent dataset). The left column (panels (a.ie.i)) shows the median patterns, but the right column (panels (a.iie.ii)) presents the respective cumulative distributions. Cumulative probability is abbreviated as ’Cumul. Prob.’, and CDF stands for cumulative distribution function. The straight dashed lines are the prediction of EUT under the assumption that the participants are risk-neutral. The EUT predictions are provided for illustration only and are not used to validate the magnetisation reversal model. In each row, we first (a.ie.i) demonstrate the median propensity to stick to a lottery against a series of sure monetary amounts displayed on the horizontal axis (to that end, the number of choices to stick with the lottery was summed across four repetitions for the same subject and median probability to stick with the lottery was calculated across all subjects). On the right-hand side (a.iie.ii), we demonstrate the corresponding cumulative distribution functions reflective of the mean propensity to stick with the lottery against a series of stakes.
Figure 4. Experimental PR data of the five lotteries (each row of the figure corresponds to an independent dataset). The left column (panels (a.ie.i)) shows the median patterns, but the right column (panels (a.iie.ii)) presents the respective cumulative distributions. Cumulative probability is abbreviated as ’Cumul. Prob.’, and CDF stands for cumulative distribution function. The straight dashed lines are the prediction of EUT under the assumption that the participants are risk-neutral. The EUT predictions are provided for illustration only and are not used to validate the magnetisation reversal model. In each row, we first (a.ie.i) demonstrate the median propensity to stick to a lottery against a series of sure monetary amounts displayed on the horizontal axis (to that end, the number of choices to stick with the lottery was summed across four repetitions for the same subject and median probability to stick with the lottery was calculated across all subjects). On the right-hand side (a.iie.ii), we demonstrate the corresponding cumulative distribution functions reflective of the mean propensity to stick with the lottery against a series of stakes.
Information 15 00413 g004
Figure 5. (a) Sketch of the magnetisation vector M precession. Simulated results: (b) M spirals back toward the direction of H e f f due to the damping. (c) The spin transfer torque compensates the damping, resulting in a stable precession of M around H e f f . (d) Reversal of the direction of M . The applied field is H 0 = 8 kOe. The sphere is used for visualisation only.
Figure 5. (a) Sketch of the magnetisation vector M precession. Simulated results: (b) M spirals back toward the direction of H e f f due to the damping. (c) The spin transfer torque compensates the damping, resulting in a stable precession of M around H e f f . (d) Reversal of the direction of M . The applied field is H 0 = 8 kOe. The sphere is used for visualisation only.
Information 15 00413 g005
Figure 6. Top x and right y axes: Cumulative probability distribution function for sticking decisions in the video game. The dashed straight lines denote the EUT propensity to stick. The dotted curve corresponds to the experimental data. Bottom x and left y axes: The circular markers denote the simulated magnetisation reversal. The thin solid line is the guide to the eye only.
Figure 6. Top x and right y axes: Cumulative probability distribution function for sticking decisions in the video game. The dashed straight lines denote the EUT propensity to stick. The dotted curve corresponds to the experimental data. Bottom x and left y axes: The circular markers denote the simulated magnetisation reversal. The thin solid line is the guide to the eye only.
Information 15 00413 g006
Thus, our model contributes to the existing literature by introducing a new class of PR models. To help the readers in navigating the literature, in Figure 3, we visualise the links of our work to the previous relevant publications. We can see that our theoretical and computational approach stands out from the plethora of competing models reported in the literature.

2. Study 1: Preference Reversals and Imprecision Intervals in the Laboratory

2.1. Empirical Data and Experimental Procedures

In several relevant studies recording imprecision intervals [3,14,15], an individual is given a number of choices between a lottery B and a series of increasing sure payoff amounts A j , j = 0 , , 13 . Since each choice is made multiple times and independently of the previous ones, we model this individual’s preferences as a probability distribution.
Figure 2a shows two theoretically possible distributions. The dashed line denotes the deterministic preferences of an individual who chooses B when j < 6 , never chooses B when j > 6 , and is exactly indifferent between A and B when j = 6 . The curve with the circular markers denotes the probabilistic preferences. When the sure thing S T A 3 , the individual always chooses B. When S T A 10 , the individual never chooses B. For A 3 < A < A 10 there is an imprecision interval.
The probabilistic distribution in Figure 2a is drawn as a sigmoid-like curve since this function robustly fits many intuitions [3] and datasets [3,9,15,16,17]. To provide a specific example of data resulting in sigmoid-like functions, establishing the robustness of the observed behavioural patterns (sigmoid-shaped curves) in Figure 4, we present five examples of experimental curves plotted using the data obtained from the laboratory decision-making experiments with human subjects. We plot the median patterns in the left column of Figure 4 and present their respective cumulative distributions in the right column. The cumulative distribution function (CDF) represents the probability that a subject’s propensity to stick with a lottery is less than or equal to a certain level as the monetary stakes change, as described below.
All experiments were conducted at the University of Warwick using subject pools of undergraduate, postgraduate and executive students over the age of 18 (no minors participated in the experiments). Upon arrival to the laboratory, each participant was provided with the study information sheet and a consent form. Informed consent was obtained from all participants in this study.
In Figure 4a, 81 subjects were making a series of binary choices between a lottery which gave GBP 40 with a probability of 80% or 0 with probability of 20% and sure payoff amounts between GBP 16 and GBP 36 with a step of GBP 2. In Figure 4b, 101 subjects were offered a lottery which yielded GBP 40 with a probability of 30% or 0 with a probability of 70% versus sure amounts of money between GBP 4 and GBP 12 with a step of GBP 1. In Figure 4c, 101 experimental participants make choices between a lottery providing GBP 15 with a probability of 70% and 0 otherwise against sure amounts between GBP 4 and GBP 12 with a step of £1. In Figure 4d, 184 subjects face a choice between a chance of winning GBP 12 with a probability of 80% and sure amounts from GBP 3 to GBP 11 with a step of GBP 1. In Figure 4e, 184 people decide between GBP 15 with a probability of 25% and sure monetary amounts between GBP 3 and GBP 11 with a step of GBP 1. In all lotteries, each person made each of the binary choices four times. We can see that all five examples demonstrate robust evidence in favour of the existence of an imprecision interval, where people make probabilistic choices between a lottery and sure monetary amounts.
Thus, Figure 4 plots summary patterns for 81, 101, 101, 184, and 184 experimental participants, respectively. Considering that, in the panels (a)–(e) of Figure 4, each participant answered at least nine binary choice questions that were repeated four times (hence, we have at least 36 points per participant per case), we additionally plotted the response curves as well as the utility functions for each individual separately, also calculating the number of individuals in each of the cases (a)–(e), who demonstrated patterns consistent with having an imprecision interval according to our definition. Overall, our calculations reveal that, in each case, the majority of participants exhibited patterns consistent with having an imprecision interval. Importantly, 73% (59 out of 81), 73% (74 out of 101), 90% (91 out of 101), 98% (181 out of 184), and 93% (172 out of 184) of participants had patterns consistent with imprecision intervals in the cases labelled as (a), (b), (c), (d), and (e), correspondingly. Raw data relevant to Figure 4 can be accessed following the instruction given in the Data Availability section.

2.2. Magnetisation Reversal Model

To simulate the experimental decision-making behaviour, we employ magnetisation dynamics in ferromagnetic metal (FM) structures. In general, an electric current is unpolarised since it involves electrons with a random polarisation of spins. However, a current that passes through a thin FM film with a fixed magnetisation direction can become spin-polarised since spins become oriented predominantly in the same direction [53]. This physical effect is exploited in a spin transfer torque nano-oscillator (STNO), where a layer with a fixed direction of magnetisation M is separated from a thinner FM layer by a non-magnetic metal layer [54]. When a spin-polarised current is directed from the “fixed” magnetisation layer into the “free” magnetisation layer, the static equilibrium orientation of magnetisation in the “free” layer becomes destabilised. Depending on the strength of the electric current, the destabilisation of magnetisation can lead to either the stable precession of magnetisation of the “free” layer about the direction of the effective magnetic field or to a reversal of the magnetisation direction (Figure 5).
We model the dynamics of magnetisation using the Landau–Lifshitz–Gilbert Equation [55]:
M / t = γ H e f f × M + T G + T S B ,
where γ is the gyromagnetic ratio. The first term of the right-hand side of Equation (1) governs the precession of M (Figure 5a) about the direction of the effective magnetic field H e f f = H 0 e z + H + H e x , where H 0 is the external static magnetic field orientated along the z axis, H is the dynamic field due to currents and magnetic sources such as demagnetising field and eddy current fields, and H e x is the exchange field [56]. The dissipative torque is [55]
T G = α G M s 1 M × M / t ,
where M s is the saturation magnetisation of the “free” magnetisation layer and α G is Gilbert damping parameter [55,56]. The Slonczewski–Berger torque is
T S B = σ 0 I M s 1 M × M × e ^ p ,
where I is the strength and e ^ p is the direction of the spin polarisation of the current. The parameter σ 0 incorporates fundamental physical constants and the thickness of the “free” magnetisation layer [55].
Equation (1) is solved consistently with Maxwell’s equations using a finite-difference time-domain (FDTD) method and material parameters presented in [56]. We model a point-contact STNO structure experimentally studied in [54]. Since we employ a one-dimensional FDTD scheme, the strength of the current I required to produce a magnetisation reversal in our model, which is lower than that in [54].

2.3. Results

In Figure 2b, we plot the dynamics of the M z component of the magnetisation vector M in the “free” layer as a function of the electric current strength for different values of the applied magnetic field H 0 . The trajectories of M for H 0 = 8 kOe computed at the simulated time of 1 ns are shown in Figure 5b,c. Figure 2b demonstrates that the magnetisation dynamics correctly approximates the sigmoid probabilistic PR curve in Figure 2a but the strength of the driving electric current plays the role of parameter A.
The experimental curves in Figure 4 can be regarded as the particular cases of the sigmoid function and they can be simulated using the magnetisation reversal observed at different values of H 0 (for example, compare the experimental CDF curve in Figure 4c.ii with the magnetisation reversal curve for 9 kOe in Figure 2b). We also note that it is computationally straightforward to use our model to approximate curves whose shape deviates from a sigmoid function. To demonstrate this possibility, in Study 2, we unleash the potential of the magnetisation reversal model applying it to the analysis of a more complex experimental dataset.

3. Study 2: Field Experiments

We further validate our model using a dataset obtained from a “Deal or No Deal” video game based on a popular TV show, where contestants choose boxes with concealed cash amounts and negotiate with a banker to accept an offer or keep opening boxes. The aim is to secure the highest prize, avoiding smaller sums. Once a box is opened, its prize is shown and removed from potential winnings. Essentially, players choose between risky lotteries and certain cash offers. They may also exchange their box for any unopened one in the game. The decision to swap the box or to stick to the original one enables us to study whether the participants behave according to EUT or to cumulative prospect theory (CPT). A previous study [57] that used TV show data from three countries demonstrated that: (i) CPT players are more likely to stick to their original choice of the box due to the embedded assumption of loss aversion and (ii) EUT players are indifferent between swapping and sticking.
We recruited 78 study participants (members of the general public over 18 years of age, informed consent was obtained from all participants as per the procedure used in Study 1), who made a total of 1698 game decisions, including 486 swap or stick decisions. The fact that 63% of decisions were stick decisions and 37% were swap decisions demonstrated a higher consistency with EUT than with CPT. However, the cumulative distribution function (CDF) of swap or stick decisions revealed an intriguing result: while EUT (the straight dashed lines in Figure 6) predicts an approximately equal split between swapping or sticking decisions, the distribution of swap or stick decisions (the dotted curve in Figure 6) cannot be described by EUT.
Since the magnetisation dynamics depends on the static field H 0 (Figure 2b), in Figure 6, we plot a magnetisation reversal that is recast as ( M z / M s + 1 ) / 2 for the sake of comparison with the experimental data. The resulting curve satisfactorily reproduces the experimental decision-making behaviour demonstrated by the players of the game. The values of H 0 corresponding to the data points of this curve are, from left to right: 15, 6, 8.75, 9.6, 9.95, 10, 10, 10.75, 11, 11.52, 11.99, 12.1, and 12.5 kOe.

4. Discussion

The functions of a human brain underpinning the phenomena like PR can be comprehended in detail through neuroscience methods [58]. Nonetheless, understanding human behaviour is pivotal not just for neuroscience but also for fields of finance, politics, religion, and sociology. Thus, there is a demand for phenomenological models that can forecast decisions at both individual and societal levels quickly and efficiently.
These models should not necessarily be based on neurobiological insights, mirroring the human cognition (drawing parallels with biological brain processes might even be unhelpful [59]). The primary criterion for evaluating a model of decision making should be the ability of the model to accurately explain and predict imprecise and noisy decisions. The model we introduce in this paper follows this philosophy, aligning with the ongoing work in decision theory where models are not necessarily capturing human brain functions [60].
Importantly, our model is not driven by experimental datasets. In fact, the psychological data presented in this paper are only needed to validate the model. The validation process requires relatively compact datasets and its main aim is to establish a range of model parameters that can be used in further studies. Once suitable parameters have been established, the model can produce new results independently of experimental data.
Quantum decision theory (QDT) has been increasingly applied across various disciplines beyond traditional decision-making contexts, leveraging its ability to model complex, paradoxical human behaviours that classical models often fail to capture [33,35,61,62]. QDT provides a robust framework for understanding phenomena like the Allais and Ellsberg paradoxes, where human decisions deviate from the expected utility theory due to ambiguity and uncertainty [32,33,34]. These models use principles of superposition and interference to explain how people evaluate risks and uncertainties differently from traditional economic predictions [33,35]. In international relations, QDT has been employed to model the dynamics of decision making under the conditions of strategic ambiguity and uncertainty [63]. The probabilistic nature of QDT allows for the better predictions of state behaviours and negotiations outcomes, offering a nuanced perspective that incorporates both rational and irrational elements of decision making [33,35,40]. QDT has found applications in explaining cognitive processes, such as perception and memory, by modelling the probabilistic and non-deterministic nature of human thought [33,64,65]. Studies suggest that cognitive states can be represented similarly to quantum states [33,64,66], with decision-making being a process of resolving these states into definite outcomes based on observed probabilities.
In turn, magnetisation reversal is a foundational principle in developing spintronic devices, which are pivotal in neuromorphic computing systems [67,68,69,70,71,72]. These systems emulate neural architectures and functionalities [72,73], offering potential advancements in creating more efficient and powerful computational models that mimic human cognitive processes. Our approach contributes to the existing literature by showing the value of magnetisation principles in the application to preference reversals, offering a unique view on explaining and predicting a variety of behavioural phenomena observed across many applications.
Admittedly, our approach has several limitations, including the need to adjust the model parameters to analyse a previously unconsidered social or economical scenario (a more comprehensive discussion of the perceived limitations of the proposed model is given in Section 5). However, the adjustment process should be relatively simple since it requires one to validate the model against another compact set of experimental data. Overall, the results produced by a properly adjusted model can help reduce the need to conduct complex experiments involving many human participants.
STNO has been a foundational component in neuromorphic computing hardware systems that emulate the functions of the human brain [67,74]. The operational principles of STNO obey the laws of quantum mechanics [75], even though our model’s Equation (1) is classical. Quantum-mechanical models have demonstrated superior capacity in depicting decision making compared with classical models [33]. Therefore, leveraging a realistic STNO structure in our model hints at the potential of STNOs to act as a neuromorphic system for simulating human decision-making processes. The so-designed system can be integrated with a reservoir computing algorithm [76], resulting in a machine learning technique that has an enhanced learning efficacy compared with classical systems [71] and also can simulate the human decision making.
Other quantum-mechanical systems can replicate decision making [77]. However, the magnetisation reversal in STNO naturally extends important models of opinion shifts in social networks based on spin direction reversal [23]. Even though those models adopted the spin concept from physics, the processes causing the spin changes were largely synthetic. Thus, integrating a genuine model of magnetisation reversal into the opinion shift model [23] will enhance the efficacy of the latter, enabling it to analyse diverse decision-making scenarios.

5. Future Research

The current work is a plausible attempt to phenomenologically describe psychological and decision-making phenomena using a purely physical model. Although this approach is mathematically similar to models belonging to the quantum decision theory group, our model was developed independently, exploiting the ability of classical physics to successfully explain certain quantum-mechanical phenomena.
Admittedly, our model cannot capture the complexity of cognitive processes in full. However, creating such a model goes well beyond the scope of this paper. Yet, as famously written by Box and Draper, the approximate nature of the model must always be borne in mind [78]. In other words, any model has its advantages and disadvantages and its true performance can only be demonstrated in tests involving real-life data. Supporting this point of view and recognising the benefits of a comparison of different models [79], in this paper, we establish the ground truth by benchmarking our model against large datasets obtained in diverse experimental scenarios, which a standard research approach in the fields of physics and engineering. It is also likely that additional limitations of our model will be revealed at later stages, when the model will be used by different users. This process is natural and it will help us and other researchers following our work improve the model.
Importantly, since we aimed to make our model accessible to a broad range of non-experts in physics, we deliberately kept the model equations as simple as possible. Hence, future research could explore more intricate physical processes and more advanced quantum-physical models that may offer a closer analogue to the multifaceted nature of human cognition and decision making. Indeed, the experimental setups, such as those employed in our “Deal or No Deal” study, provide valuable insights but also come with limitations regarding, for example, the range of decision-making scenarios they can simulate. Further studies could employ more diverse and real-life decision-making contexts, enhancing the applicability and robustness of our findings.
This study predominantly focuses on an external, observable behaviour perspective. Integrating other kind of insights, especially from fields like macroeconomics, could provide a more holistic understanding of decision-making processes, bridging the gap between physical models and the neurological underpinnings of human behaviour. The inclusion of these factors in our model should not represent significant technical difficulties. Indeed, strictly speaking, if a decision-making process can be represented by a continuous function at least in principle, then our model or its modifications should be able to approximate it with reasonable accuracy. Yet, our physical model can naturally incorporate noise, interference and dissipation, all defined physically, which are the processes that were previously explored in models of cognition and decision making [35,80,81].
The computational models employed in psychology, while effective, may not fully capture the dynamism and adaptability of human decision making. Future research could incorporate machine learning and AI to develop more sophisticated models that can dynamically adapt and learn from new data, mirroring the evolving nature of human preferences. One example of a relevant study is our recent work on a quantum-inspired neural network model of optical illusions that exploits a chaotic physical system as a network [64]. The cited work aligns with a broader collective effort to create neural networks that could predict complex socio-economic processes using the laws of physics (for a review of methodological aspects see, e.g., [65,76,82]).
Our study primarily considers decision making from a psychological and physical perspective, potentially overlooking the influence of socio-cultural factors, which may be of interest. Subsequent research could integrate these variables, examining how cultural, social, and environmental factors interplay with the cognitive processes in decision making. We are currently working in this direction and the results of that project will be reported elsewhere.
By addressing these limitations, future research can not only refine and expand upon our current findings but also contribute to a more nuanced and comprehensive understanding of human decision-making processes. More specifically, the current research can lead to a deeper integration of physical sciences with behavioural economics and psychology. Future research could contribute by developing comprehensive models that further incorporate principles from quantum mechanics, statistical physics, and complexity science to capture the nuanced aspects of human decision-making, as exemplified by neural network models empowered by quantum technologies [64]. There is also an opportunity to explore the neurobiological underpinnings of the decision-making phenomena modelled by physical systems. Indeed, future studies could use neuroimaging techniques to validate the predictions of physical models against observed brain activity during decision-making tasks (see, e.g., the works on artificial neural network that mimic the operation of a biological brain [83] and relevant works on physics-informed machine learning models [76,84]).
Finally, advanced computational techniques like machine learning and AI could be employed to refine the models based on large datasets. In this context, future research could focus on the development of algorithms that learn from behavioural data to predict decision-making patterns and preference changes over time. A number of papers developing relevant ideas have already been published [85,86,87,88]. Future research could utilise such models to simulate the effects of policy changes on public behaviour: by understanding how individuals might react to different policy interventions, more effective and targeted strategies can be developed. Indeed, there have been several demonstrations of the possible application of quantum-mechanics in political studies, especially in the realm of international relations studies [62,63]. Importantly, the cited works present rather a general philosophical discussion of such models, thereby highlighting unexplored fields of research where the physical model of decision-making can find specific practical applications.

6. Conclusions

We demonstrated that the psychological phenomenon of PR can be modelled using the physical phenomenon of magnetisation reversal. Using a spin transfer torque as the mechanism of magnetisation reversal, we revealed the ability of the magnetisation reversal model to capture complex individual’s decisions made in psychological experiments. We have also shown that our model extends beyond PR and encompasses a wide range of decision-making regularities, reaffirming the observation that human preferences are imprecise.
Our model uniquely integrates the physical principle of magnetisation reversal from ferromagnetic nanostructures with human decision-making dynamics, diverging significantly from traditional decision theory models. Traditional models, such as expected utility theory, assume stable preferences, often failing to capture the inconsistencies and paradoxes inherent in real-world decision-making, like preference reversals. Theoretically, our model addresses these limitations by incorporating imprecision and noise directly into the decision-making process, reflecting the probabilistic nature of human preferences. This approach aligns more closely with empirical observations and challenges classical assumptions about rationality and consistency in human choices. By leveraging the Landau–Lifshitz–Gilbert equation to simulate decision dynamics, our model also bridges a gap between physical phenomena and psychological behaviour, offering a novel perspective that combines insights from both fields. Practically, the model’s ability to predict and explain complex decision behaviours has significant implications. It can enhance the design of behavioural interventions, inform public policy, and improve economic forecasting by providing a more accurate representation of how people make decisions under uncertainty. Additionally, its applicability in neuromorphic computing and social physics suggests the potential for developing advanced technologies and strategies for influencing collective behaviour.

6.1. Implications on Literature

This research contributes to a dynamic and ever-evolving body of literature that challenges traditional economic and psychological theories. It encourages the development of new theories that accommodate the stochastic and probabilistic nature of human decision making. The use of physical models to explain psychological phenomena can inspire new research methodologies that are more robust and predictive of real-world behaviours. The findings demonstrate the value of cross-disciplinary research and can stimulate collaborative studies that bridge gaps between fields such as cognitive psychology, economics, physics, and computer science.

6.2. Implications on Practice and Policy

In practice, these models can inform the design of behavioural interventions that are more aligned with how people actually make decisions, potentially increasing their efficacy. The ability to more accurately predict human behaviour can revolutionise economic forecasting and financial planning, providing tools for better risk assessment and market analysis. Policymakers can use insights from this research to craft policies that consider the probabilistic nature of human decisions, leading to more nuanced and effective public policies. The interdisciplinary nature of this research can also influence educational curricula, promoting a more integrative approach to teaching economics, psychology, and physics.
While our work bolsters the exploration of physics as a lens to comprehend human psychology, its tangible implications are profound: the model holds promise for designing neuromorphic hardware systems rooted in nanomagnetic devices. Such interdisciplinary convergence has the potential to reshape the way we interface with both the human mind and advanced computational systems.
The implication of magnetisation reversal as a model for human decision making not only accentuates the universality of certain principles across ostensibly disparate domains but also underscores the rich tapestry of relationships waiting to be unearthed between the physical and cognitive realms. For example, the integration of these findings can stimulate a paradigm shift in how we design and conceptualise next-generation cognitive devices. Moreover, the ability of physical effects to emulate cognitive processes suggests a future where the boundaries between cognition and artificial intelligence blur, leading to new possibilities for collaborative intelligence.

6.3. Implications on Interdisciplinary Research in Physics

Last but not least, the present work contributes to a more than four decades long endeavour to establish the field of sociophysics [89,90,91,92,93]. Although sociophysics has maturated as an independent discipline, it has been unable to find a secure place in specialised physical journals and university classrooms yet. The present work demonstrates that a physical model developed to investigate the fundamental physical effect of magnetisation reversal can be applied in the domain of social sciences without the need to modify the model parameters. While some physicists may find this result to be contradictory, our findings demonstrate that the actual frontiers of physics are located well beyond our current understanding and that the point where a physical topic becomes a non-physical one is more difficult to define than is immediately apparent.

Author Contributions

I.S.M.: conceptualisation, data curation, formal analysis, investigation, methodology, writing—original draft; writing—review and editing; G.P.: conceptualisation, data curation, formal analysis, investigation, methodology, writing—original draft; writing—review and editing. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

The authors did not receive any funding to support this project.

Institutional Review Board Statement

This work was approved by Humanities and Social Sciences Research Ethics Committee (HSSREC) of the University of Warwick (approval number 31/13-14).

Informed Consent Statement

Upon arrival to the laboratory, each participant was provided with the study information sheet and a consent form. Informed consent was obtained from all participants in the study. All participants were adults (18 years of age or older). No minors participated in the experiments; therefore, obtaining parental/guardian consent was not applicable to this work.

Data Availability Statement

All data relevant to this work are presented in this paper. Large-size relevant raw data are uploaded to GitHub: https://github.com/BehaviouralDataScience/Magnetisation-Reversal-Model (accessed on 12 July 2024) alongside the software used to process them. The computational code implementing the magnetisation reversal model is available at https://github.com/IvanMaksymov/MagneticPreferenceReversal (accessed on 12 July 2024).

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflicts of interest.

Abbreviations

The following abbreviations are used in this manuscript:
CDFCumulative distribution function
CPTCumulative prospect theory
EUTExpected utility theory
FDTDFinite difference time-domain
FMFerromagnetic Metal
PRPreference Reversal
QDTQuantum Decision Theory
STSure Thing
STNOSpin Transfer Torque Nano-Oscillator

References

  1. Lindman, H. Inconsistent preferences among gambles. J. Exp. Psychol. 1971, 89, 390–397. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Bhatia, S.; Loomes, G. Noisy preferences in risky choice: A cautionary note. Psychol. Rev. 2017, 124, 678–687. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  3. Loomes, G.; Pogrebna, G. Do preference reversals disappear when we allow for probabilistic choice? Manag. Sci. 2017, 63, 166–184. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Blavatskyy, P. Probabilistic independence axiom. Geneva Risk Insur. Rev. 2021, 46, 21–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Busemeyer, J.R.; Wang, Z. Primer on quantum cognition. Span. J. Psychol. 2019, 22, E53. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Sharma, E.; Tully, S.M.; Wang, X. Scarcity and intertemporal choice. J. Personal. Soc. Psychol. 2023. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Moffatt, P.; Starmer, C.; Sugden, R.; Bardsley, N.; Cubitt, R.; Loomes, G. Experimental Economics: Rethinking the Rules; Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ, USA, 2009. [Google Scholar]
  8. Chater, N. The Mind Is Flat: The Illusion of Mental Depth and the Improvised Mind; Penguin UK: London, UK, 2018. [Google Scholar]
  9. Blavatskyy, P.R.; Pogrebna, G. Models of stochastic choice and decision theories: Why both are important for analyzing decisions. J. Appl. Econom. 2010, 25, 963–986. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Bardsley, N.; Cubitt, R.; Loomes, G.; Moffatt, P.; Starmer, C.; Sugden, R. Experimental economics. In Experimental Economics; Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ, USA, 2009. [Google Scholar]
  11. Lichtenstein, S.; Slovic, P. Reversals of preference between bids and choices in gambling decisions. J. Exp. Psychol. 1971, 89, 46–55. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Blavatskyy, P.; Panchenko, V.; Ortmann, A. How common is the common-ratio effect? Exp. Econ. 2023, 26, 253–272. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Grether, D.; Plott, C. Economic theory of choice and the preference reversal phenomenon. Am. Econ. Rev. 1979, 69, 623–638. [Google Scholar]
  14. Butler, D.J.; Loomes, G.C. Imprecision as an account of the preference reversal phenomenon. Am. Econ. Rev. 2007, 97, 277–297. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Mosteller, F.; Nogee, P. An experimental measurement of utility. J. Political Econ. 1951, 59, 371–404. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Loomes, G.; Pogrebna, G. Testing for independence while allowing for probabilistic choice. J. Risk Uncertain. 2014, 49, 189–211. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Butler, D.J.; Pogrebna, G. Predictably intransitive preferences. Judgm. Decis. Mak. 2018, 13, 217–236. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Loomes, G.; Sugden, R. Regret theory: An alternative theory of rational choice under uncertainty. Econ. J. 1982, 92, 805–824. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Yearsley, J.M.; Busemeyer, J.R. Quantum cognition and decision theories: A tutorial. J. Math. Psychol. 2016, 74, 99–116. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Gronchi, G.; Strambini, E. Quantum cognition and Bell’s inequality: A model for probabilistic judgment bias. J. Math. Psychol. 2017, 78, 65–75. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Galam, S. Heterogeneous beliefs, segregation, and extremism in the making of public opinions. Phys. Rev. E 2005, 71, 046123. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Castellano, C.; Fortunato, S.; Loreto, V. Statistical physics of social dynamics. Rev. Mod. Phys. 2009, 81, 591–646. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Redner, S. Reality-inspired voter models: A mini-review. C. R. Phys. 2019, 20, 275–292. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Capraro, V.; Perc, M. Mathematical foundations of moral preferences. J. R. Soc. Interface 2021, 18, 20200880. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  25. Kvam, P.D.; Busemeyer, J.R.; Pleskac, T.J. Temporal oscillations in preference strength provide evidence for an open system model of constructed preference. Sci. Rep. 2021, 11, 8169. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Hohmann, M.; Devriendt, K.; Coscia, M. Quantifying ideological polarization on a network using generalized Euclidean distance. Sci. Adv. 2023, 9, eabq2044. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  27. Ortega, P.A.; Braun, D.A. Thermodynamics as a theory of decision-making with information-processing costs. Proc. R. Soc. A 2013, 469, 20120683. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Pakhomov, A.; Sudin, N. Thermodynamic view on decision-making process: Emotions as a potential power vector of realization of the choice. Cogn. Neurodyn. 2013, 7, 449–463. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Evans, B.P.; Prokopenko, M. A maximum entropy model of bounded rational decision-making with prior beliefs and market feedback. Entropy 2021, 23, 669. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  30. Annila, A. The fundamental nature of motives. Front. Neurosci. 2022, 16, 806160. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Atmanspacher, H.; Filk, T. A proposed test of temporal nonlocality in bistable perception. J. Math. Psychol. 2010, 54, 314–321. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Aerts, D.; Sozzo, S.; Tapia, J. Identifying quantum structures in the Ellsberg paradox. Int. J. Theor. Phys. 2014, 53, 3666–3682. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Busemeyer, J.R.; Bruza, P.D. Quantum Models of Cognition and Decision; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 2012. [Google Scholar]
  34. al Nowaihi, A.; Dhami, S. The Ellsberg paradox: A challenge to quantum decision theory? J. Math. Psychol. 2017, 78, 40–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Khrennikov, A. Quantum-like brain: “Interference of minds”. Biosystems 2006, 84, 225–241. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Mindell, A. Quantum Mind: The Edge Between Physics and Psychology; Deep Democracy Exchange: Portland, OR, USA, 2012. [Google Scholar]
  37. Pothos, E.M.; Busemeyer, J.R. Quantum Cognition. Annu. Rev. Psychol. 2022, 73, 749–778. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Nielsen, M.; Chuang, I. Quantum Computation and Quantum Information; Oxford University Press: New York, NY, USA, 2002. [Google Scholar]
  39. Pothos, E.M.; Busemeyer, J.R. A quantum probability explanation for violations of ‘rational’ decision theory. Proc. R. Soc. B 2009, 276, 2171–2178. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Aerts, D.; D’Hooghe, B.; Sozzo, S. A Quantum Cognition Analysis of the Ellsberg Paradox. In Proceedings of the Quantum Interaction; Song, D., Melucci, M., Frommholz, I., Zhang, P., Wang, L., Arafat, S., Eds.; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 2011; pp. 95–104. [Google Scholar]
  41. Aerts, D.; Sozzo, S.; Tapia, J. A Quantum Model for the Ellsberg and Machina Paradoxes. In Proceedings of the Quantum Interaction; Busemeyer, J.R., Dubois, F., Lambert-Mogiliansky, A., Melucci, M., Eds.; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 2012; pp. 48–59. [Google Scholar]
  42. Blutner, R.; Graben, P.B. Quantum cognition and bounded rationality. Synthese 2016, 193, 3239–3291. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Wei, M.; al Nowaihi, A.; Dhami, S. Quantum decision theory, bounded rationality and the Ellsberg Paradox. Stud. Microecon. 2019, 7, 110–139. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Ishwarya, M.S.; Cherukuri, A.K. Decision-making in cognitive paradoxes with contextuality and quantum formalism. Appl. Soft Comput. 2020, 95, 106521. [Google Scholar]
  45. Ostermair, C. An experimental investigation of the Allais paradox with subjective probabilities and correlated outcomes. J. Econ. Psychol. 2022, 93, 102553. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Abel, C.R. The quantum foundations of utility and value. Philos. Trans. R. Soc. A 2023, 381, 20220286. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  47. Galam, S.; Moscovici, S. Towards a theory of collective phenomena: Consensus and attitude changes in groups. Eur. J. Soc. Psychol. 1991, 21, 49–74. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Galam, S. Rational group decision making: A random field Ising model at T = 0. Physica A 1997, 238, 66–80. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Axelrod, R. The dissemination of culture: A model with local convergence and global polarization. J. Confl. Resolut. 1997, 41, 203–226. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Sznajd-Weron, K.; Sznajd, J. Opinion evolution in closed community. Int. J. Mod. Phys. C 2000, 11, 1157–1165. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Lakshmanan, M. The fascinating world of the Landau-Lifshitz-Gilbert equation: An overview. Phil. Trans. R. Soc. A 2011, 369, 1280–1300. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  52. Mcmullin, E. What do Physical Models Tell us? In Logic, Methodology and Philosophy of Science III; Van Rootselaar, B., Staal, J., Eds.; Studies in Logic and the Foundations of Mathematics; Elsevier: Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 1968; Volume 52, pp. 385–396. [Google Scholar]
  53. Ralph, D.C.; Stiles, M.D. Spin transfer torques. J. Magn. Magn. Mater. 2008, 320, 1190–1216. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Rippard, W.H.; Pufall, M.R.; Kaka, S.; Russek, S.E.; Silva, T.J. Direct-current induced dynamics in Co90Fe10/Ni80Fe20 point contacts. Phys. Rev. Lett. 2004, 92, 027201. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  55. Slavin, A.; Tiberkevich, V. Nonlinear auto-oscillator theory of microwave generation by spin-polarized current. IEEE Trans. Magn. 2009, 45, 1875–1918. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Maksymov, I.S.; Kostylev, M. Impact of conducting nonmagnetic layers on the magnetization dynamics in thin-film magnetic nanostructures. J. Appl. Phys. 2013, 113, 043927. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Blavatskyy, P.; Pogrebna, G. Endowment effects? “Even” with half a million on the table! Theory Decis. 2010, 68, 173–192. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Sharma, S.N.; Khan, A. Intertemporal preference reversals are associated with early activation of insula and sustained preferential processing of immediate rewards in visual cortex. Sci. Rep. 2021, 11, 22277. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Taddeo, M. On the risks of relying on analogies to understand cyber conflicts. Minds Mach. 2016, 26, 317–321. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Wakker, P.P. Prospect Theory: For Risk and Ambiguity; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 2010. [Google Scholar]
  61. Favre, M.; Wittwer, A.; Heinimann, H.R.; Yukalov, V.I.; Sornette, D. Quantum decision theory in simple risky choices. PLoS ONE 2016, 11, e0168045. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  62. Allan, B.B. Social action in quantum social science. Millennium 2018, 47, 87–98. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  63. Tesař, J. Quantum theory of international relations: Approaches and possible gains. Hum. Aff. 2015, 25, 486–502. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  64. Maksymov, I.S. Quantum-inspired neural network model of optical illusions. Algorithms 2024, 17, 30. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  65. Maksymov, I.S.; Pogrebna, G. Quantum-mechanical modelling of asymmetric opinion polarisation in social networks. Information 2024, 15, 170. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  66. Benedek, G.; Caglioti, G. Graphics and Quantum Mechanics–The Necker Cube as a Quantum-like Two-Level System. In Proceedings of the 18th International Conference on Geometry and Graphics, Milan, Italy, 3–7 August 2018; Cocchiarella, L., Ed.; Springer International Publishing: Cham, Switzerland, 2019; pp. 161–172. [Google Scholar]
  67. Furuta, T.; Fujii, K.; Nakajima, K.; Tsunegi, S.; Kubota, H.; Suzuki, Y.; Miwa, S. Macromagnetic simulation for reservoir computing utilizing spin dynamics in magnetic tunnel junctions. Phys. Rev. Appl. 2018, 10, 034063. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  68. Watt, S.; Kostylev, M. Reservoir computing using a spin-wave delay-line active-ring resonator based on yttrium-iron-garnet film. Phys. Rev. Appl. 2020, 13, 034057. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  69. Blachowicz, T.; Ehrmann, A. Magnetic elements for neuromorphic computing. Molecules 2020, 25, 2550. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  70. Yokouchi, T.; Sugimoto, S.; Rana, B.; Seki, S.; Ogawa, N.; Shiomi, Y.; Kasai, S.; Otani, Y. Pattern recognition with neuromorphic computing using magnetic field–induced dynamics of skyrmions. Sci. Adv. 2022, 8, eabq5652. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  71. Dudas, J.; Carles, B.; Plouet, E.; Mizrahi, F.A.; Grollier, J.; Marković, D. Quantum reservoir computing implementation on coherently coupled quantum oscillators. NPJ Quantum Inf. 2023, 9, 64. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  72. Allwood, D.A.; Ellis, M.O.A.; Griffin, D.; Hayward, T.J.; Manneschi, L.; Musameh, M.F.K.; O’Keefe, S.; Stepney, S.; Swindells, C.; Trefzer, M.A.; et al. A perspective on physical reservoir computing with nanomagnetic devices. Appl. Phys. Lett. 2023, 122, 040501. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  73. Marrows, C.H.; Barker, J.; Moore, T.A.; Moorsom, T. Neuromorphic computing with spintronics. NPJ Spintron. 2024, 2, 12. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  74. Riou, M.; Torrejon, J.; Garitaine, B.; Araujo, F.A.; Bortolotti, P.; Cros, V.; Tsunegi, S.; Yakushiji, K.; Fukushima, A.; Kubota, H.; et al. Temporal pattern recognition with delayed-feedback spin-torque nano-oscillators. Phys. Rev. Appl. 2019, 12, 024049. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  75. Brataas, A. Quantum scattering theory of spin transfer torque, spin pumping, and fluctuations. Phys. Rev. B 2022, 106, 064402. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  76. Maksymov, I.S. Analogue and physical reservoir computing using water waves: Applications in power engineering and beyond. Energies 2023, 16, 5366. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  77. Naruse, M.; Nomura, W.; Aono, M.; Ohtsu, M.; Sonnefraud, Y.; Drezet, A.; Huant, S.; Kim, S.J. Decision making based on optical excitation transfer via near-field interactions between quantum dots. J. Appl. Phys. 2014, 116, 154303. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  78. Box, G.E.P.; Draper, N.R. Empirical Model-Building and Response Surfaces; John Wiley and Sons: New York, NY, USA, 1987. [Google Scholar]
  79. Busemeyer, J.R.; Wang, Y.M. Model comparisons and model selections based on generalization criterion methodology. J. Math. Psychol. 2000, 44, 171–189. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  80. Aerts, D.; Arguëlles, J.A. Human perception as a phenomenon of quantization. Entropy 2022, 24, 1207. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  81. Aerts, D.; Beltran, L. A Planck radiation and quantization scheme for human cognition and language. Front. Psychol. 2022, 13, 850725. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  82. Maksymov, I.S. Quantum Mechanics of Human Perception, Behaviour and Decision-Making: A Do-It-Yourself Model Kit for Modelling Optical Illusions and Opinion Formation in Social Networks. arXiv 2024, arXiv:physics.soc-ph/2404.10554. [Google Scholar]
  83. Rao, A.; Plank, P.; Wild, A.; Maass, W. A long short-term memory for AI applications in spike-based neuromorphic hardware. Nat. Mach. Intell. 2022, 4, 467–479. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  84. Nakajima, M.; Inoue, K.; Tanaka, K.; Kuniyoshi, Y.; Hashimoto, T.; Nakajima, K. Physical deep learning with biologically inspired training method: Gradient-free approach for physical hardware. Nat. Commun. 2022, 13, 7847. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  85. Busemeyer, J.R.; Fakhari, P.; Kvam, P. Neural implementation of operations used in quantum cognition. Prog. Biophys. Mol. Biol. 2017, 130, 53–60. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  86. Khrennikov, A.; Basieva, I.; Pothos, E.M.; Yamato, I. Quantum probability in decision making from quantum information representation of neuronal states. Sci. Rep. 2018, 8, 16225. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  87. Khrennikov, A.; Asano, M. A quantum-like model of information processing in the brain. Appl. Sci. 2020, 10, 707. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  88. Saleem, M.; Hamid, M. Consciousness, cognition and neural networks in the brain: Advances and perspectives in neuroscience. Int. J. Comput. Sci. Netw. Secur. 2023, 23, 47–54. [Google Scholar]
  89. Galam, S.; Feigenblat, Y.G.; Shapir, Y. Sociophysics: A new approach of sociological collective behaviour. I. mean-behaviour description of a strike. J. Math. Sociol. 1982, 9, 1–13. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  90. Galam, S. Application of statistical physics to politics. Physics A 1999, 274, 132–139. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  91. Galam, S. Sociophysics: A personal testimony. Physics A 2004, 336, 49–55. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  92. Galam, S. Physicists, non physical topics, and interdisciplinarity. Front. Phys. 2022, 10, 986782. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  93. Galam, S. Fake News: “No ban, no spread—with sequestration”. Physics 2024, 6, 859–876. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Maksymov, I.S.; Pogrebna, G. The Physics of Preference: Unravelling Imprecision of Human Preferences through Magnetisation Dynamics. Information 2024, 15, 413. https://doi.org/10.3390/info15070413

AMA Style

Maksymov IS, Pogrebna G. The Physics of Preference: Unravelling Imprecision of Human Preferences through Magnetisation Dynamics. Information. 2024; 15(7):413. https://doi.org/10.3390/info15070413

Chicago/Turabian Style

Maksymov, Ivan S., and Ganna Pogrebna. 2024. "The Physics of Preference: Unravelling Imprecision of Human Preferences through Magnetisation Dynamics" Information 15, no. 7: 413. https://doi.org/10.3390/info15070413

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop