Microcredit and Survival Microenterprises: The Role of Market Structure
Abstract
:Most observers agree that in the right circumstances microfinance can increase household incomes, but its impact on poor clients remains controversial. Judith ShawAre microloan recipients at the bottom-of-the-pyramid benefited to the extent microfinance practitioners want them to be? And if not, what changes are necessary in MFI lending policies?
1. Introduction
2. African Microfinance
3. Theoretical Analysis
3.1. Value Chains
USAID/E35 applies the value chain approach to drive economic growth with poverty reduction through the integration of large numbers of micro- and small enterprises (MSEs) into increasingly competitive value chains. By influencing the structures, systems and relationships that define the value chain, USAID helps MSEs to improve (or upgrade) their products and processes, and thereby contribute to and benefit from the chain’s competitiveness. Through this approach USAID enables MSEs—including small-scale farmers—to create wealth and escape poverty.
3.2. Market Equilibrium Analysis: Local and External Markets
3.3. The Role of Transfer Costs
3.4. Choosing Sectors for MFI Loans
3.5. Value Chain Relationships
Strong, mutually beneficial relationships between firms facilitate the transfer of information, skills and services—all of which are essential to upgrading. Value chain opportunities and constraints generally require a coordinated response by multiple firms in the chain—which necessitates trust and a willingness to collaborate. The value chain approach, therefore, emphasizes a dynamic that has long been recognized: Social capital (networks of relationships and social institutions) are critical to business and competitiveness.
In particular, it is an opportunity to significantly expand livestock exports from the county into both Ethiopia and the rest of Kenya. Merille, previously a tiny settlement on the southern boundary, is proof of the value of roads to the livestock market… (T)he market now operates weekly, rather than fortnightly, and attracts between 60–90 buyers, many from out of the county. Moyale livestock market is similarly buoyant, attracting traders coming from Ethiopia to buy livestock. This expanded demand works to dramatically increase prices: currently average goat prices are 40 per cent higher in Marsabit than Turkana and bull prices are almost double It seems that bigger markets with more buyers actually increase livestock prices and hence income to local producers. As the backbone of the county’s economy, the road will dramatically improve pastoralists’ ability to realize the value of their animals.
3.6. Summary
4. Empirical Evidence
4.1. The MixMarket Data
4.2. Evidence from the MixMarket Data Analysis for MFIs from All Regions
4.3. Evidence on Business Purpose from Interview Data
5. Conclusions and Suggestions for Future Work
- What do business size transition matrices look like? In which industries is there a sink at the lowest levels?
- What is the likelihood of getting larger and larger loans for MFI clients and which industries do they tend to be in?
- Is there a relationship between firm size and the probability of loan repayment?
- What is the geographical area over which firms sell their products/services? Is this localized or at the national or provincial or global level?
- Are the outputs of the firm sold to other businesses or to final consumers?
- What are the Herfindahl indices across industries and does this have any relationship to concentration of small firms?
- What is the level of human capital possessed by borrowers? Do they have access to business expertise? Is there any correlation between human capital and success? Is there any connection between human capital and what industries borrowers go into? Is there any connection between human capital and where borrowers get their money from?
- Do loan sizes increase over time? Do borrowers move from informal lending/MFIs to other sources for their loans? Do they reduce the number of activities in which they are involved?24 Does the number of people employed increase over time?
Acknowledgments
Conflicts of Interest
Appendix
A.1. Additional Evidence from MixMarket Data Analysis
Variable/Specification | 1 | 2 | 3 | 4 |
---|---|---|---|---|
1. profstatind | −0.01193 (−1.42) | −0.00948 (−1.3) | −0.0506 (−2.79) | −0.03889 (−3.7) |
legstatind | ||||
0 | −0.00927 (−0.69) | −0.03567 (−2.79) | −0.08648 (−1.96) | −0.04918 (−2.39) |
1 | −0.03505 (−2.51) | −0.05013 (−3.92) | −0.20012 (−4.51) | −0.10735 (−5.1) |
2 | −0.04266 (−3.64) | −0.05537 (−5.08) | −0.16281 (−4.06) | −0.07765 (−4.25) |
3 | −0.05554 (−4.12) | −0.07063 (−5.75) | −0.20274 (−4.78) | −0.11919 (−5.93) |
regionind | ||||
0 | −0.0453 (−4.8) | −0.02336 (−2.7) | −0.03409 (−1.29) | −0.02408 (−1.78) |
2 | −0.06386 (−8.41) | −0.0332 (−4.66) | −0.01295 (−0.57) | −0.03112 (−2.63) |
3 | −0.05397 (−3.82) | −0.02349 (−1.89) | −0.03052 (−0.95) | −0.03721 (−2.07) |
4 | −0.04155 (−6.04) | −0.02019 (−3.1) | −0.02221 (−1.06) | −0.02833 (−2.75) |
5 | −0.05621 (−7.17) | −0.03497 (−4.82) | −0.03546 (−1.56) | −0.02489 (−2.18) |
avlbalgnp | −0.00154 (−1.27) | −0.00533 (−1.12) | −0.00355 (−1.49) | |
lnassets | −0.00285 (−2.68) | −0.00621 (−2.0) | −0.00657 (−3.87) | |
roa | −0.17799 (−12.55) | −0.15775 (−3.02) | −0.15962 (−7.05) | |
indivp | 0.020516 (0.88) | 0.037013 (2.97) | ||
solidarityp | 0.017764 (0.72) | 0.013556 (1.06) | ||
vgbankp | omitted | (omitted) | ||
microfinp | −0.01381 (−0.25) | |||
smefinp | 0.01136 (−0.2) | |||
lgcorpfinp | omitted | |||
urbanp | −0.01589 (−0.94) | |||
ruralp | omitted | |||
_cons | 0.164985 (11.96) | 0.201566 (9.73) | 0.397287 (4.51) | 0.290276 (8.02) |
No. of observations | 10996 | 9707 | 1368 | 3745 |
Overall R-square | 0.0157 | 0.0317 | 0.0419 | 0.0428 |
Llossrat | 1 | 2 | 3 | 4 |
---|---|---|---|---|
1. profstatind | 0.019298 (1.85) | 0.015588 (1.25) | 0.033509 (1.16) | 0.019737 (1.39) |
legstatind | ||||
0 | 0.000916 (0.05) | −0.00268 (−0.13) | −0.03022 (−0.42) | −0.01321 (−0.45) |
1 | 0.015679 (0.79) | 0.017002 (0.82) | 0.008781 (0.12) | 0.006725 (0.22) |
2 | 0.022294 (1.31) | 0.013306 (0.75) | 0.012655 (0.19) | 0.010489 (0.4) |
3 | 0.025298 (1.35) | 0.019357 (0.97) | 0.034672 (0.5) | 0.022688 (0.78) |
Regionind | ||||
0 | −0.03459 (−2.71) | −0.01181 (−0.84) | −0.00309 (−0.08) | −0.01155 (−0.61) |
2 | −0.02831 (−2.62) | 0.00793 (0.68) | 0.046346 (1.27) | 0.018381 (1.2) |
3 | −0.03212 (−1.8) | −0.01141 (−0.53) | −0.00902 (−0.18) | −0.00831 (−0.36) |
4 | −0.02172 (−2.29) | −0.00143 (−0.13) | 0.002385 (0.07) | −0.00404 (−0.29) |
5 | −0.03898 (−3.61) | −0.02204 (−1.84) | −0.00562 (−0.16) | −0.01508 (−0.99) |
avlbalgnp | −0.00092 (−0.65) | −0.00117 (−0.16) | −0.0006 (−0.19) | |
lnassets | 0.001356 (−0.98) | 0.003612 (0.74) | 0.002493 (1.07) | |
roa | −0.10177 (−6.62) | −0.08754 (−10.8) | −0.06067 (−1.9) | |
indivp | 0.005815 (0.16) | |||
solidarityp | 0.00229 (0.06) | |||
vgbankp | Omitted | |||
microfinp | 0.037856 (0.46) | |||
smefinp | 0.074524 (0.85) | |||
lgcorpfinp | Omitted | |||
urbanp | 0.039031 (1.47) | 0.022743 (1.80) | ||
ruralp | Omitted | 0 | ||
_cons | 0.022113 (1.12) | −0.01191 (−0.41) | −0.13349 (−0.96) | −0.04582 |
No. of observations | 9593 | 9007 | 1226 | 3110 |
Overall R-square | 0.0026 | 0.0083 | 0.0016 | 0.0074 |
A.2. Evidence from the MixMarket Data Analysis for African MFIs
Dependent Variable | PAR30 | PAR30 | PAR30 | Llossrat | Llossrat | Llossrat |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Variable/Specification | 1 | 2 | 3 | 1 | 2 | 3 |
1. profstatind | −0.04188 (−1.15) | −0.04171 (−1.36) | −0.10469 (−1.62) | 0.04829 (0.65) | 0.012499 (0.68) | 0.012451 (0.57) |
legstatind | ||||||
0 | 0.125365 (3.52) | 0.035108 (0.99) | 0.245021 (2.94) | 0.017683 (0.16) | 0.013404 (0.47) | 0.042129 (1.37) |
1 | −0.02467 (−0.52) | −0.04325 (−1.01) | 0.087298 (1.72) | 0.070452 (0.57) | 0.024481 (0.78) | 0.027458 (1.47) |
2 | −0.0288 (−0.87) | −0.05205 (−1.65) | 0.204299 (2.79) | 0.082048 (0.8) | 0.013359 (0.51) | 0.013161 (0.54) |
3 | −0.08665 (−1.75) | −0.11197 (−2.54) | Omitted | 0.073644 (0.59) | 0.032635 (1.04) | Omitted |
4 | Omitted | Omitted | Empty | Omitted | Omitted | Empty |
avlbalgnp | −0.00409 (−1.81) | 0.007299 (0.42) | 0.000186 (0.09) | 0.000228 (0.04) | ||
lnassets | −0.00641 (−2.2) | −0.03491 (−4.26) | −0.00149 (−0.56) | −0.00348 (−1.21) | ||
roa | −0.1061 (−4.11) | 0.236563 (2.04) | −0.0912 (−2.44) | 0.012768 (0.5) | ||
indivp | 0.058392 (0.69) | −0.07268 (−2.37) | ||||
solidarityp | 0.066238 (0.85) | −0.08876 (−3.23) | ||||
vgbankp | Omitted | Omitted | ||||
microfinp | 0.233164 (0.83) | −0.01504 (−0.17) | ||||
smefinp | 0.350036 (1.23) | −0.00141 (−0.02) | ||||
lgcorpfinp | Omitted | Omitted | ||||
urbanp | −0.03394 (−0.7) | −0.00351 (−0.22) | ||||
ruralp | Omitted | Omitted | ||||
_cons | 0.17233 | 0.281266 (4.62) | 0.278999 (0.9) | −0.03853 (−0.32) | 0.02424 (0.48) | 0.147301 (1.45) |
No. of observations | 1790 | 1382 | 117 | 1449 | 1287 | 102 |
Overall R-square | 0.0201 | 0.0476 | 0.3048 | 0.0016 | 0.0043 | 0.2375 |
References
- Abdulai, Adams, and Devi Datt Tewari. 2017. Trade-off between outreach and sustainability of microfinance institutions: evidence from sub-Saharan Africa. Enterprise Development and Microfinance 28: 162–81. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Adjei, Joseph Kimos, Thankom Arun, and Farhad Hossain. 2009. The Role of Microfinance in Asset Building and Poverty Reduction: The Case of Sinapi Aba Trust of Ghana. Manchester: Brooks World Poverty Institute. [Google Scholar]
- Annim, Samuel Kobina. 2012. Targeting the poor versus financial sustainability and external funding: Evidence of microfinance institutions in Ghana. Journal of Development Entrepreneurship 17. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Barnes, Carolyn, Gary Gaile, and Richard Kibombo. 2001a. The Impact of Three Microfinance Programs in Uganda; Washington: Development Experience Clearinghouse, USAID.
- Barnes, C., Erica Keogh, and Nontokozo Nemarundwe. 2001b. Microfinance Program Clients and Impact: An Assessment of Zambuko Trust Zimbabwe. Washington: Assessing the Impact of Microenterprise Services (AIMS). [Google Scholar]
- Bateman, Milford. 2007. De-industrialization and social disintegration in Bosnia. In What’s Wrong with Microfinance. Edited by Thomas Dichter and Malcolm Harper. Rugby: Practical Action Publishing. [Google Scholar]
- Bateman, Milford. 2010. Why Doesn’t Microfinance Work. London: Zed Books. [Google Scholar]
- Bauchet, Jonathan, Cristobal Marshall, Laura Starita, Jeanette Thomas, and Anna Yalouris. 2011. Latest Findings from Randomized Evaluations of Microfinance. Access to Finance Forum Reports by CGAP and Its Partners No. 2, December 2011. Washington: Consultative Group to Assist the Poor. [Google Scholar]
- Cotter, Jim. 1996. Distinguishing between Poverty Alleviation and Business Growth. Small Enterprise Development 7: 49–53. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cull, Robert, Asli Demirgüç-Kunt, and Jonathan Morduch. 2007. Financial Performance and Outreach: A Global Analysis of Leading Microbanks. The Economic Journal 117: F107–33. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cull, Robert, Asli Demirgüç-Kunt, and Jonathan Morduch. 2009. Microfinance Meets the Market. The Journal of Economic Perspectives 23: 167–92. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Duflo, Esther. 2005. Gender Equality in Development. Working Paper, Massachussetts Institute of Technology. Available online: http://citeseerx.ist.psu.edu/viewdoc/summary?doi=10.1.1.592 (accessed on 19 December 2017).
- Easterly, William. 2006. The White Man’s Burden: Why the West’s Efforts to Aid the Rest Have Done So Much Ill and So Little Good. London: The Penguin Press. [Google Scholar]
- Epstein, Marc, and Kristi Yuthas. 2010. Microfinance in Cultures of Replacement. Journal of Development Entrepreneurship 15: 35–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Fafchamps, Marcel. 2003. Market Institutions in Sub-Saharan Africa: Theory and Evidence. Cambridge: MIT Press. [Google Scholar]
- Fitzgibbon, Catherine, and Courtenay Cabot Venton. 2014. Financial Graduation Feasibility Study. Nairobi: FSD Kenya. [Google Scholar]
- Ghate, Prabhu, Evelinda Ballon, and Virginia Manalo. 1996. Poverty alleviation and enterprise development: The need for a differentiated approach. International Development 8: 163–78. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hermes, Neil, and Robert Lensink. 2007. The Empirics of Microfinance: What do We Know? The Economic Journal 117: F1–10. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hossain, Shahadat. 2013. Is Commercialization of Microfinance Responsible for Over-Indebtedness? The Case of Andhra Pradesh Crisis. Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development 4: 142–53. [Google Scholar]
- Johnston, Don, and Jonathan Morduch. 2007. Microcredit vs. Microsaving: Evidence from Indonesia. Working Paper. New York, NY, USA: New York University. [Google Scholar]
- Karlan, Dean, and Jonathan Zinman. 2011. Microcredit in Theory and Practice: Using Randomized Credit Scoring for Impact Evaluation. Science 332: 1278–84. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Kiiru, Joy, and John Mburu. 2006. User Costs of Joint Liability Borrowing and their Effect on Livelihood Assets for Rural Poor Households. International Journal of Women, Social Justice and Human Rights 2: 87–100. [Google Scholar]
- Kipesha, Erasmus F., and Xianzhi Zhang. 2013. Sustainability, profitability and outreach trade-off: Evidence from microfinance institutions in east Africa. European Journal of Business and Management 5: 2222–839. [Google Scholar]
- Kpolovie, Peter J., S. Ewansiha, and M. Esara. 2017. Continental Comparison of Human Development Index (HDI). International Journal of Humanities Social Sciences and Education 4: 9–27. [Google Scholar]
- Krishna, Anirudh, and Devendra Bajpai. 2011. Lineal Spread and Radial Dissipation: Experiencing Growth in Rural India, 1993–2005. Economic and Political Weekly 46: 44–51. [Google Scholar]
- Mair, Johanna, and Ignasi Marti. 2007. Entrepreneurship for social impact: Encouraging market access in rural Bangladesh. Corporate Governance 7: 493–501. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Makame, A.H., and V. Murinde. 2006. Empirical Findings on Cognitive Dissonance around Microfinance Outreach and Sustainability. Unpublished paper. Birmingham, UK: University of Birmingham. [Google Scholar]
- Minten, Bart, Lalaina Randrianarison, and Johan Swinnen. 2006. Global Retail Chains and Poor Farmers: Evidence from Madagascar. LICOS Centre for Transition Economies Discussion Paper No. 164/2006. Leuven, Belgium: Katholieke Universiteit Leuven. [Google Scholar]
- Mix. 2015. Global Outreach & Financial Performance Benchmark Report—2015. Washington: Mix. [Google Scholar]
- Morduch, Jonathan. 2011. Why Finance Matters. Science 332: 1271–72. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Morduch, Jonathan. 2013. How Microfinance Really Works. The Milken Institute Review Second Quarter, 51–59. [Google Scholar]
- Mosley, Paul, and David Hulme. 1998. Microenterprise finance: Is there a conflict between growth and poverty alleviation? World Development 26: 783–90. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Nanor, Michael A. 2008. Microfinance and Its Impact on Selected Districts in Eastern Region of Ghana. Kumasi: College of Art and Social Sciences, Kwame Nkrumah University of Science and Technology. [Google Scholar]
- Ouma, Clemencia Osa, and Charles M. Rambo. 2013. The Impact of Microcredit on Women Owned Small and Medium Enterprises: Evidence from Kenya. Global Journal of Business Research 7: 57–69. [Google Scholar]
- Pitt, Mark, and Shahidur Khandker. 1998. The Impact of Group-Based Credit Programs on Poor Households in Bangladesh: Does the Gender of Participants Matter? Journal of Political Economy 106: 858–996. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Porter, Michael E. 1985. The Competitive Advantage: Creating and Sustaining Superior Performance. New York: Free Press. [Google Scholar]
- Robinson, Marguerite. 2001. The Microfinance Revolution: Sustainable Banking for the Poor. Washington: The World Bank. [Google Scholar]
- Rosenberg, Richard. 2010. What’s the Impact of Loan Size in Microfinance. CGAP Blog. Available online: http://www.cgap.org/blog/whats-impact-loan-size-microfinance (accessed on 8 November 2017).
- Schaffner, Julie. 2014. Development Economics. Hoboken: Wiley. [Google Scholar]
- Shaw, Judith. 2004. Microenterprise Occupation and Poverty Reduction in Microfinance Programs: Evidence from Sri Lanka. World Development 32: 1247–64. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Shukla, Rajesh. 2010. How India Earns, Spends, and Saves: Unmasking the Real India. New Delhi: Sage Publications. [Google Scholar]
- USAID. 2015. Overview of the Value Chain Approach. Available online: https://www.microlinks.org/good-practice-center/value-chain-wiki/overview-value-chain-approach (accessed on 11 May 2015).
- Van Rooyen, Carina, Ruth Stewart, and Thea de Wet. 2012. The Impact of Microfinance in Sub-Saharan Africa: A Systematic Review of the Evidence. World Development 40: 2249–62. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhang, Quanda. 2017. Does microfinance reduce poverty? Some international evidence. The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics 17: 1–13. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
1 | Of course, empirically, it is not easy to distinguish between the two. Even if a loan is given for income-generating purposes, money being fungible, it is likely to be used for other purposes. |
2 | Data obtained from the World Bank database (http://databank.worldbank.org). |
3 | The Kenyan shilling has fluctuated between KSh 85 per US$ in mid-2011 and KSh 100 on a depreciating trend, with the current rate (November 2017) being around 103. I use a conversion rate of KSH 100 per US$ throughout in the paper. |
4 | This group includes hardware shops, bookshops and dry-cleaning outlets. |
5 | E3 refers to USAID’s Bureau for Economic Growth, Education, and Environment. |
6 | Fitzgibbon and Venton (2014) also look at value chains and make some recommendations similar to those I make in Section 4, but this time from the viewpoint of enabling individual households to be financially self-sufficient. Their work does not include any analysis of the impact of microcredit on product markets. |
7 | This does not have to be high-level technology. For example, a Kiva loan recipient that I interviewed in Nairobi (part of the dataset that I analyze in Section 4.3) operates a small-scale shoe manufacturing operation with simple machines, employing three persons! |
8 | In Chapter 8, she discusses market equilibrium in developing countries, where transactions costs are very important. |
9 | These costs include not just the actual transport costs, but also storage, financing, risk of theft and all transactions costs associated with the transfer of goods from the local market to the external market. For example, selling in the local market may involve fewer information asymmetries than selling in the external market, where the buyer may not be as known to the seller; transfer costs would thus include additional costs deriving from such information asymmetries, e.g., cheating of quantity, quality and terms of the transaction. |
10 | This is a reasonable scenario given that microenterprises are usually constrained by liquidity and MFIs also have difficulty in obtaining funds to lend out. There is usually, then, unmet demand for microcredit. Alternatively, the microcredit expansion may be financed by subsidies; in this case, the demand curve would shift downwards and a similar result is likely to ensure, except that the negative effect on producers would be moderated by the lower borrowing costs available. In this case, the existence of unused local resources is also likely to moderate the resulting price increase, if any. |
11 | |
12 | To make matters worse, in these markets, the elasticity of the demand curve could increase with increased supply: initially, the clientele may be high-income and demand may be very elastic, but as quantities supplied increase, producers have to reach out to low-income clientele, and the demand curve could become quite inelastic (thanks to the referee for this point). |
13 | In preparing the data for analysis, I discovered that because of fiscal year changes, in some cases, an MFI had data for two different periods, but designated by the same fiscal year. In these cases, I changed the fiscal year designation for some of the years in a way that made most sense, so as to only include distinct MFI-fiscal year units. I don’t believe that this would make a great difference. Since none of the data variables that I use are flow variables, I did not correct them for the number of months included in a particular fiscal year. |
14 | PAR30 is defined as the portion of loans greater than 30 days past due, including the value of all renegotiated loans (restructured, rescheduled, refinanced and any other revised loans) compared to gross loan portfolio. I also redid the analysis with PAR90 with similar results; these results are not reported. |
15 | This decision is discretionary only if the MFI is unregulated. If it is regulated, loans are required to be fully provisioned, which means that they are effectively written off. |
16 | Kpolovie et al. (2017) report that the average Human Development Index, developed by the United Nations Development Programme (UNDP) was lowest for Africa at 0.5356, followed by Oceania (0.6926), Asia (0.7141), North America (0.7333), South America (0.7379), and Europe (0.8453). Other developmental statistics for the different continents were provided in the Introduction. |
17 | To get some quantitative feel for this, we can look at a couple of statistics provided by themix.org. According to Mix (2015), rural banks in Africa had the highest number of borrowers per loan officer (1294) compared to 715 for Credit Unions/Cooperatives, which comes in next. In East Asia and the Pacific, rural banks, NBFIs, NGOs and Credit Union/Cooperatives were all equally low. In South Asia, all MFI types had fairly similar numbers. No rural banks are listed for the other continents. Operating expense for rural banks in Africa was highest at 39.3% as a proportion of the loan portfolio with NGOs coming in next at 30.9%. For East Asia and the Pacific, rural banks and NGOs had equally high numbers; for South Asia, all MFI types had comparable numbers, while no rural banks are listed for the other continents. |
18 | Since avlbal (unadjusted loan size) and avlbalgnp (loan size adjusted for GNP per capita) behave very similarly, and, if anything, avlbalgnp tends to show more of a relationship to the dependent variables, I do not report results for avlbal. |
19 | Rosenberg (2010) makes an interesting comment about loan sizes. He says: “People tend to see loan size as a rough proxy of client poverty, which appears to be more or less true as long as you say the word “rough” very emphatically. However, the first few loans that an MFI makes to a client typically reflect, not the client’s ability to use and repay the amount, but rather the MFI’s risk management policy (i.e., we will give the client more serious money only after she has established a good track record in repaying small—i.e., low risk—loans). This means that, according to Rosenberg, loan size reflects both the likelihood of repayment and the poverty of the borrower. In any case, he does relate loan size and how poor the borrower is likely to be, which I take to be positively related with the inhospitability of the business environment for borrowers. |
20 | I elected to run a random-effects regression rather than a fixed-effects regression for several reasons: one, my MFI-specific variables are likely to vary over time; two, the time period I consider includes the 2007 financial crisis which is likely to cause time variation in the independent variables; three, some of my explanatory variables are time-invariant and, hence, would be perfectly collinear with MFI dummies in a fixed-effects regression. |
21 | I drop observations with a value of “Other” for legstatind because I do not know how to interpret this designation; in any case, this only accounts for 240 observations. I also deleted observations that were neither marked for-profit or non-profit; this accounted for 981 observations. |
22 | The detailed results from the loan loss regressions are also discussed in the Appendix. |
23 | Rafiki clients not from Nairobi branches were from Thika, Ruiru, Rongai, and Kitengela; all areas were within 15 miles of Nairobi. |
24 | Involvement in several disparate activities at the same time is often an indication of the need for diversification in income sources, which also bespeaks informality and lack of success. |
25 | I also tried the available loan balance by itself; it was always insignificant and always less significant than avlbalgnp. |
Proxy Variable for Inhospitable Business Environment | Description | Category Expected to be Correlated with Business Unprofitability/Expected Sign |
---|---|---|
Profit Status | Values for this categorical variable:
| Non-Profit |
Region of Operation | Values for this categorical variable:
| Africa |
Legal Status of MFI | Values for this categorical variable:
| Rural Banks |
Lending Methodology | Percent of gross loan portfolio accounted for by:
| Village Bank methodology |
Rural/Urban loans | Percent of gross loan portfolio accounted for by loans made in:
| Rural |
Client firm size | Percent of enterprise loans made to:
| Microenterprises |
MFI Size | Natural Log of Assets (lnassets) | Negative |
ROA | Return on Assets (roa) | Negative |
Loan Size | Average loan balance per borrower (avlbal) | Negative |
Relative Loan Size | Average loan balance per borrower/GNI per capita (avlbalgnp) | Negative |
Panel A: PAR30 | |||||
Profstatind | mean | sd | max | min | N |
0 | 0.070482 | 0.132002 | 5.4845 | 0 | 6107 |
1 | 0.072387 | 0.16152 | 7.1143 | 0 | 4889 |
Total | 0.071329 | 0.145862 | 7.1143 | 0 | 10,996 |
Test for equality of means: Pr(|T| > |t|) = 0.4963 | |||||
Panel B: Loan Loss Rate (llossrat) | |||||
Profstatind | mean | sd | max | min | N |
0 | 0.019754 | 0.118193 | 5.584 | 0 | 5359 |
1 | 0.031786 | 0.426564 | 25.7075 | 0 | 4234 |
Total | 0.025065 | 0.29688 | 25.7075 | 0 | 9593 |
Test for equality of means: Pr(|T| > |t|) = 0.0487 |
Panel A: PAR30 | |||||
Legstatind | mean | sd | max | min | N |
0 | 0.078495 | 0.288746 | 7.1143 | 0 | 1143 |
1 | 0.084382 | 0.119531 | 1.7923 | 0 | 1638 |
2 | 0.065119 | 0.123511 | 3.7318 | 0 | 4019 |
3 | 0.063763 | 0.106157 | 1 | 0 | 3667 |
4 | 0.115053 | 0.144346 | 1.2171 | 0 | 529 |
Total | 0.071329 | 0.145862 | 7.1143 | 0 | 10,996 |
Test for equality of all means: F = 20.28, Prob > F = 0.0000 | |||||
Panel B: Loan Loss Rate (llossrat) | |||||
Legstatind | mean | sd | max | min | N |
0 | 0.017998 | 0.040815 | 0.5972 | 0 | 1035 |
1 | 0.019808 | 0.153722 | 4.7395 | 0 | 1399 |
2 | 0.034966 | 0.471109 | 25.7075 | 0 | 3459 |
3 | 0.021271 | 0.113874 | 5.584 | 0 | 3269 |
4 | 0.008402 | 0.021707 | 0.3039 | 0 | 431 |
Total | 0.025065 | 0.29688 | 25.7075 | 0 | 9593 |
Test for equality of all means: F = 1.69, Prob > F = 0.1489 |
Panel A: PAR30 | |||||
Regionind | mean | sd | max | min | N |
0 | 0.075572 | 0.123188 | 1.2171 | 0 | 1183 |
1 | 0.103605 | 0.146069 | 1.7923 | 0 | 1790 |
2 | 0.058027 | 0.154593 | 5.4845 | 0 | 2012 |
3 | 0.056803 | 0.116828 | 0.9434 | 0 | 412 |
4 | 0.069372 | 0.084276 | 1 | 0 | 3651 |
5 | 0.059574 | 0.221601 | 7.1143 | 0 | 1948 |
Total | 0.071329 | 0.145862 | 7.1143 | 0 | 10,996 |
Test for equality of all means: F = 24.82, Prob > F = 0.0000 | |||||
Panel B: Loan Loss Rate (llossrat) | |||||
Regionind | mean | sd | max | min | N |
0 | 0.013302 | 0.046784 | 0.9907 | 0 | 1113 |
1 | 0.048436 | 0.695809 | 25.7075 | 0 | 1449 |
2 | 0.021192 | 0.267533 | 9.8906 | 0 | 1712 |
3 | 0.016235 | 0.04367 | 0.4446 | 0 | 365 |
4 | 0.028386 | 0.054399 | 1.5604 | 0 | 3227 |
5 | 0.012535 | 0.067749 | 1.3329 | 0 | 1727 |
Total | 0.025065 | 0.29688 | 25.7075 | 0 | 9593 |
Test for equality of all means: F = 2.97, Prob > F = 0.0111 |
Variable/Specification | PAR30 | Llossrat |
---|---|---|
1. profstatind | −0.01193 (−1.42) | 0.019298 (1.85) |
legstatind | legstatind | |
0 | −0.00927 (−0.69) | 0.000916 (0.05) |
1 | −0.03505 (−2.51) | 0.015679 (0.79) |
2 | −0.04266 (−3.64) | 0.022294 (1.31) |
3 | −0.05554 (−4.12) | 0.025298 (1.35) |
regionind | Regionind | |
0 | −0.0453 (−4.8) | −0.03459 (−2.71) |
2 | −0.06386 (−8.41) | −0.02831 (−2.62) |
3 | −0.05397 (−3.82) | −0.03212 (−1.8) |
4 | −0.04155 (−6.04) | −0.02172 (−2.29) |
5 | −0.05621 (−7.17) | −0.03898 (−3.61) |
_cons | 0.164985 (11.96) | 0.022113 (1.12) |
No. of observations | 10,996 | 9593 |
Overall R-square | 0.0157 | 0.0026 |
Business Sector | Kiva Clients | Rafiki Clients | All Clients | ||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Personal Interviews | Data Provided Directly by Kiva | Total for Kiva Clients | Personal Interviews | Total for All Clients | |
Agriculture | 1 | 2 | 3 | 4 | 7 |
Retail | 20 | 8 | 28 | 8 | 36 |
Service | 4 | 6 | 10 | 4 | 14 |
Manufacturing | 0 | 3 | 3 | 0 | 3 |
Trading | 0 | 0 | 0 | 2 | 2 |
Total | 25 | 19 | 44 | 18 | 62 |
© 2017 by the author. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Viswanath, P.V. Microcredit and Survival Microenterprises: The Role of Market Structure. Int. J. Financial Stud. 2018, 6, 1. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijfs6010001
Viswanath PV. Microcredit and Survival Microenterprises: The Role of Market Structure. International Journal of Financial Studies. 2018; 6(1):1. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijfs6010001
Chicago/Turabian StyleViswanath, P. V. 2018. "Microcredit and Survival Microenterprises: The Role of Market Structure" International Journal of Financial Studies 6, no. 1: 1. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijfs6010001
APA StyleViswanath, P. V. (2018). Microcredit and Survival Microenterprises: The Role of Market Structure. International Journal of Financial Studies, 6(1), 1. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijfs6010001