Next Article in Journal
A Two-Stage DEA Model to Evaluate the Performance of Iberian Banks
Previous Article in Journal
Trade Openness and Economic Growth: A Study on Asean-6
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

A New Method for Measuring Total Factor Productivity Growth Based on the Full Industry Equilibrium Approach: The Case of the Greek Economy

1
Laboratory of Applied Economics, Department of Economics, University of Western Macedonia, 52100 Kastoria, Greece
2
Economic Analysis and Policy Lab, School of Social Sciences, Hellenic Open University, 26335 Patras, Greece
3
Department of Economics, Manchester Metropolitan University, Manchester M15 6BH, UK
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Economies 2021, 9(3), 114; https://doi.org/10.3390/economies9030114
Submission received: 24 June 2021 / Revised: 29 July 2021 / Accepted: 5 August 2021 / Published: 16 August 2021

Abstract

:
A new method of identifying the sources of output growth and measuring total factor productivity (TFP) is proposed, with an application to data from the Greek economy. The price accounting approach, based on the full industry equilibrium (FIE) framework introduced by Opocher and Steedman, where technical progress not only increases outputs relative to inputs but also reduces output prices relative to input rewards, is used. The contributions of this paper are that, first, it amends the FIE TFP measurement approach to account for heterogeneous labor inputs, imported inputs, and indirect taxes, and applies the method to real-world data from the Greek economy; second, it provides a comparison of the results with those found by the use of the neoclassical approach to TFP measurement arguing that the FIE approach measures better sectoral TFP change, and third, it provides an estimate of the effects of sectoral research and development (R&D) expenditures and R&D diffusion from other sectors on TFP change for the Greek economy.

1. Introduction

Total factor productivity (TFP) change is an inherent and important part of both Solow’s (1956) and Lucas (1988) and Romer’s (1986, 1994) growth theories. It is recognized to be an important factor in both long-term economic growth and short-term growth fluctuations and is an important long-term factor in raising the living standards of a country. Since total factor productivity (TFP) is the portion of output not explained by the amount of inputs used in production, its level is determined by how efficiently and intensely the inputs are utilized in production.
There are thousands of studies on TFP growth in many countries; the following paragraphs review the most recent ones. Tsamadias et al. (2019) examined TFP growth among the OEDC countries, dividing the sample countries into two groups, the European Union (EU) members and the non-EU, to account for country heterogeneity for the period 1995–2015. Research and development (R&D) expenditure and human capital (HC) were found to have a positive effect on TFP, while foreign direct investment (FDI) had a positive and significant effect only in the case of non-European countries. However, they found that the contribution of R&D was considerably higher than that of HC and FDI in all cases. Pegkas et al. (2020) empirically analyzed the influence of domestic and foreign R&D capital on TFP in Eurozone countries for the period 1995–2016. They discovered that variations in local and international R&D capital accounted for TFP changes. Their findings demonstrate that R&D capital has a beneficial impact on TFP. The contribution of foreign R&D capital to TFP is higher than that of local R&D capital. Sharif et al. (2021) focused on the Asia-Pacific region to analyze the impact of R&D spending on TFP growth. The role of public and private R&D and their capacity to generate economic spillovers were examined. Their results show that the impact of both public and private R&D varies across countries. Huang et al. (2019) investigated how indigenous R&D spending, as well as technological spillovers from foreign direct investments, export, and import, affected China’s TFP. Their findings, which were based on Chinese provincial panel data encompassing 30 provinces from 2000 to 2014, demonstrate that indigenous R&D investments play a key role in fostering TFP growth. There are also TFP growth benefits from technology spillovers caused by openness. However, the varied behaviors of these technology spillovers are determined by factors impacting technological absorptive capacity, such as human capital and domestic R&D investments. Yue et al. (2019) added two environmental indicators into the TFP framework: ecological footprint, which reflects human ecological consumption, and human development index, which assesses human well-being levels. The indicator of sustainable total factor productivity takes into consideration ecological inputs such as energy consumption, built-up land use, and biological resource occupation, as well as the comprehensive outputs of economic growth, life expectancy, and educational attainment. From 1994 through 2014, data were collected for 55 countries. The findings demonstrate that, first, TFP change has a decreasing tendency, indicating that most states have placed less emphasis on long-term growth. The slow pace of sustainable technical advancement was the primary cause of the declining trend. Second, 19 of the 55 countries had a positive, long-term TFP increase and were able to maintain it. In a more recent article on this line of analysis, Shen et al. (2020) used a sustainable TFP growth index derived from translog production functions to assess the process of sustainable development. From 2006 to 2016, the sustainable TFP growth of 30 Chinese provinces was estimated. The findings reveal that China’s TFP growth was modest, indicating poor long-term development. Second, variables including labor productivity and environmental legislation were shown to increase sustainable technological efficiency in a favorable way, but capital deepening, economic openness, and industrial structure harmed it. Third, TFP growth in China’s regions showed a range of increasing tendencies, from high to low, in the order of western, central, and eastern regions. Four, the high incidence of economic imbalance was shown by the dispersion of TFP growth among provinces. Amri et al. (2019) investigated the linkage between carbon dioxide (CO2) emissions, TFP, and information and communication technology (ICT) in Tunisia from 1975 to 2014. The results demonstrate the rejection of the Environmental Kuznets Curve (EKC) hypothesis by obtaining a higher value of the long-term TFP coefficient compared to the short-term one.
Furthermore, for the period 1990 to 2006, Haider et al. (2021) looked at how R&D, trade, and ICT affected TFP growth in 25 European countries, Japan, and the United States. They broke down TFP growth into two components: catching up and innovation (frontier shifts). Frontier shifts tend to be lower with increasing distance from the frontier, and major disparities occur and remain between sectors and countries, although catching-up effects are statistically significant. Shabbir and Yaqoob (2019) calculated TFP for the India and Pakistan cotton production sector. Their findings demonstrate that in Pakistan, overall improvements in farm inputs have a more stable impact on cotton productivity, whereas in India, mechanization and area are the reasons for the sector’s TFP rise. Saleem et al. (2019) investigated the factors that influence TFP and economic growth in Pakistan. For the period 1972–2016, TFP was calculated from an aggregate Cobb–Douglas production function. The findings show that innovation has a substantial impact on Pakistan’s economic growth and output levels. TFP and its determinants were investigated in 420 agricultural firms in Vietnam by Giang et al. (2019). Agriculture is a crucial sector for the country’s economic growth and poverty alleviation. Fixed and random effects models were used to calculate TFP. According to the study’s results, reform efforts should concentrate on increasing the productivity of small agricultural businesses. Furthermore, they found that foreign investment, effective utilization of bank loans, and internet accessibility should all be improved to contribute to the country’s long-term progress. Ngo et al. (2020) employed the generalized method of moments (GMM) to identify factors that affect TFP across 21 manufacturing sectors in Vietnam for the period 2010–2015. In several fragmentations of companies in terms of both labor and total capital, as well as in particular manufacturing sectors, the results reveal that large firms have much higher TFP levels than small enterprises. Doumi (2017) explored the evolution of TFP in the agricultural sector of ten Mediterranean countries for the period 1980–2012. The results show that Morocco experienced positive TFP change during the past two decades, ahead of Portugal and behind the rest of the countries in the sample. Kéïta and Hannu (2021) investigated the link between corruption and taxation hampering TFP. The empirical study used panel data from 90 countries from 1996 to 2014. The results show that both corruption and tax burden deteriorate TFP.
All the above studies and the literature until now suggest TFP growth rate is residually determined (the famous Solow residual) after subtracting the growth rates of normally employed factor inputs, weighted by their income shares, from the output growth rate.
A completely different and novel approach to measuring TFP change is proposed here where TFP change measurement is based on decomposing the effects of technological progress on prices. This new method is based on the full industry equilibrium (FIE) framework introduced recently by Opocher and Steedman (2015) and on the pioneering work of Opocher (2010). FIE has its foundations in the modern classical economic theory and attempts to combine two competing approaches to microeconomics; namely, the neoclassical long-run theory of the firm and the Sraffa-inspired classical version of economics. Both approaches share some common ground, and their amalgamation may be profitably utilized to develop firmer theoretical conclusions of practical significance.
The FIE approach (or price accounting approach) achieves a synthesis between the two theories via the method of comparative statics analysis, according to which one starts with a state of equilibrium and then hypothesizes an exogenous change to a variable, such as, for example, the real wage (or profit rate), taxation, terms of trade, price of a strategic input (e.g., the price of oil), factor productivity, etc. Then the object of study becomes the movement of all relative prices which, following the aforementioned exogenous event, must change to be consistent with arriving at a situation of zero maximum profits earned by all industries. This is called, using a Wicksellian term, “full industry equilibrium” (FIE). The question at issue concerns predicting the sign of such price changes by taking into account the inter-industry structure of the economy and the attainment of the final equilibrium state, where there are no net (excess economic) profits. It is noteworthy that FIE differs from neoclassical general equilibrium since it is independent of consumer preferences or demand decisions associated with them.
In a FIE context, the firm in the industry competes with other similarly motivated firms for produced and non-produced inputs under the scheme of maximum net profits equal to zero. This is another methodological concession made to the standard neoclassical theory, according to which the mere presence of profits is sufficient to attract an inflow of firms until profits become equal to zero. In FIE the use of twice differentiable cost functions is often adopted and possible complementarities between inputs are often ruled out. In other words, the cost functions used in the analysis are assumed to be “well behaved”. Competition leads to changes in the structure of relative commodity prices and, as far as the prices of primary inputs are concerned, it is possible to derive qualitative restrictions within the framework of comparative statics analysis1.
Taking into account the above, this paper examines the effects of total factor productivity (TFP) change on prices, under the FIE framework. These effects could be quite similar to those of taxation, but there is an important difference in that, while taxation is directly a policy variable, productivity is not. The TFP growth rate in neoclassical economics is residually determined after subtracting the growth rates of normally employed factor inputs, weighted by their income shares, from the output growth rate. The advantage of the FIE approach is that it breaks down the technical change measured by TFP into the changes in both average primary input prices and distribution. Moreover, FIE price accounting enables the identification of trend components of productivity in each industry. Lastly, the change in the primary input prices may be broken down to industry productivity change per se and to changes due to other industries.
The contributions of this paper are: (a) it introduces a completely new method for TFP measurement, based on the FIE, but extending FIE to account for heterogeneous labor inputs, imported inputs, and indirect taxes, and applies the method to real-world data from the Greek economy; (b) using econometric analysis it accounts for the effects of sectoral monopoly power on TFP changes, providing a comparison of the results with those found by the use of the neoclassical approach to TFP measurement; and (c) provides an estimate of the effects of technical change measured by sectoral research and development (R&D) and diffused R&D expenditures on sectoral TFP change for the Greek economy. Measuring productivity in each industry of the Greek economy by applying the FIE methodology has economic policy significance because it might show that the effects of technical progress on the disembodied productivity of the factors of production are different when the methodology used deviates from that of the orthodox neoclassical economic theory, and state intervention with targeted sectoral R&D policy might be misleading if the latter has been used as a measurement of TFP. This could lead to quite different policy emphases concerning R&D tax breaks and direct R&D investments.
The paper proceeds as follows: Section 2 develops the methodology for the measurement of TFP change under the FIE approach and derives a comparable formula for the neoclassical TFP change. Data used for the empirical part of the paper are also described in this section. Section 3 describes and discusses the results and Section 4 concludes.

2. Methodology and Data Description

2.1. The FIE Approach to Measuring TFP Change

The full industry equilibrium (FIE) approach (Opocher and Steedman 2015) is an alternative for measuring sectoral TFP change.
When there is one primary factor input (labor), of the same quality across sectors, the TFP price accounting approach can be used as follows (ibid. pp. 158–63): Let p, u, l, A, w, c be the vector of commodity input prices, the unit vector, the vector of factor inputs per unit of output, the matrix of commodity inputs per unit of gross output, the factor price, and the indirect cost function, respectively (small bold letters indicate vectors and capital bold letters indicate matrices). Then
p = c(w, p; T); where T indicates time.
By totally differentiating:
p ^ _ = ( w ^ w l _ γ _ ) ( I _ A _ ) 1 ;
where γ _ c T 1 c is the rate if productivity growth. Since w l _ = u _ ( I _ A _ )   then   p ^ _ = w ^ u _ γ _ ( I _ A _ ) 1 . TFP change for each sector can be calculated from vector γ _ ; ^ indicates the rate of change.
We amend the indirect cost function above to account for many primary inputs and imported inputs:
pj = cj(mj, p, fj, tj; T)
where m, p, f, t, c are monetary wage, the vector of commodity input prices, the value of imported inputs, net indirect taxes (assuming that prices are expressed at a consumer level and include net indirect taxes), and the indirect cost function, respectively. T indicates time.
By totally differentiating (1) it is derived that:
p j ˙ = l j m j ˙ + i = 1 n α i j p i ˙ + b j f j ˙ + z j t j ˙ + c j T ;
Dotted variables denote change (d(.)); l is the primary input coefficient, b and z are input coefficients for imported inputs and net indirect taxes, and n is the number of sectors; (2), in a rate of change terms denoted by a hat become:
p j ^ = ( m j l j p j ) m j ^ + i ( a i j p i p j ) p i ^ + ( b j f j p j ) f j ^ + ( z j t j p j ) t j ^ γ j
where γ j c j T 1 c j , j denotes sector j and ^ indicates the rate of change. γ j is TFP change in sector j.
In (3), by replacing the share of wages of sector j in gross output with σ j * , the share of imports of j sector in gross output with β j * , the share of net indirect taxes of j in gross output with ζ j * , and a i j p i p j , the value of input i in the value of one unit of output j with α j * , we get:
p j ^ = σ j * m j ^ + i α i j * p i ^ + β j * f j ^ + ζ j * t j ^ γ j
or
p j ^ = σ j * m j ^ + p ^ A j * + β j * f j ^ + ζ j * t j ^ γ j
where A j * is the jth column of the A* matrix of commodity inputs per unit of gross output expressed in unit values. Equation (4) decomposes percentage change in product price of sector j to its components: the first RHS term is the effect of change in factor rewards, the second the relative change in the prices of produced inputs effect, the third is the effect in the terms of trade change, and the fourth the effect from a change in net indirect taxes. γ j is the TFP change in the sector.
Solving (4) for γ j we get:
γ j = σ j * m j ^ + p ^ A j * + β j * f j ^ + ζ j * t j ^ p j ^
Apart from the factors in (1) that affect prices, economic theory, since Lerner (1934), has proven that monopoly power has a rising effect on prices. Although FIE assumptions considered that all sectors are in a long-run equilibrium with zero profit rates, in the real world this assumption might be quite unrealistic. Therefore, since the TFP change calculation in (5) is based on price change rates, the effects of sectoral monopoly power on prices must be accounted for. Monopoly power is usually measured, in empirical studies, by an industry’s concentration using the Herfindahl–Hirschman index (Hirschman 1964). However, the calculation of the latter requires information on the market shares of each individual firm in each sector and such disaggregated data are not available for the Greek economy. As an alternative, for measuring sectoral concentration, the Schmalensee (1977) firms concentration index is used from the following formula:
S I j = ( A S j 1 A S j 2 ) 2 ( n j 1 2 1 ) 3 n j 1 + n j 1 A S j 1 2 + ( n j n j 1 ) A S j 2 2
where A S j 1 , A S j 2 , n j are the average market shares of the five first in terms of sales firms, the average market shares of the remaining firms in sector j, and the total number of firms in sector j, respectively. n j 1 is the number of the largest firms in sector j and in our case is set equal to five. An increase in sectoral concentration is an indication of an increase in monopoly power; therefore, a positive relationship is expected between changes in prices and the change in market concentration. From Equation (5) it can be observed that the TFP change rate of a sector j ( γ j ) is affected negatively by the change rate of prices in that sector.
To account for the effect of the change rate in monopoly power of a sector on the TFP change rate, γ j s are regressed on S I j ^ :
γ j = a 1 + b 1 S I j ^ + u j ;
u j is the disturbance term. The residuals of this regression are the sectoral TFP change rates ( γ j ’s) without the effect the change in monopoly power on price change rates. The expected sign of the estimated coefficient of S I j ^ is negative. The results are reported in Section 3, below.
Several studies have theoretically and empirically identified factors that determine TFP (see Silveira et al. 2021 for a review of literature of TFP determinants). Theory suggests that human capital (ibid; Arazmuradov et al. 2014; Danska-Borsiak 2018; Akinlo and Adejumo 2016), trade (Bhattacharya et al. 2021; Kim 2016), FDI/imports (Bhattacharya et al. 2021; Kim 2016; Akinlo and Adejumo 2016; Harris and Moffat 2020), and R&D expenses (Danska-Borsiak 2018; Otsuka 2017; Kim 2016) are the main determinants of TFP growth. However, it is recognized that the latter is the main driver of TFP growth (among others, Saleem et al. 2019; Huang et al. 2019; Shabbir and Yaqoob 2019; Sharif et al. 2021; Pegkas et al. 2020; Tsamadias et al. 2019; Haider et al. 2019; Griliches 1979, 1994; Griffith et al. 2004; Edquist and Henrekson 2006; Hall et al. 2009; Eberhardt et al. 2013; Donghyun et al. 2014; Gehringeer et al. 2015; Venturini 2015) because it facilitates the adoption and implementation of new technologies exogenously facilitating the domestic production of technological innovations. Productivity gains are linked to R&D diffusion because innovative producers are more receptive to new technologies and thus can maximize gains and reduce costs.
Therefore, R&D is recognized to be the main driver of TFP growth as it is the most commonly used measure of technical change. Direct R&D expenditure affects the innovative capacity of a sector both directly and indirectly by increasing its absorptive capacity for knowledge created in other sectors. The relationship between TFP change rates calculated by FIE ( γ j ’s) and R&D expenditure was examined by the regression of γ j ’s on total sectoral R&D expenditure over the period for which the γ j ’s are calculated, i.e., 2010–2015. A variable ( R D _ D I F j ) measuring R&D diffusion from the total R&D expenditure of other sectors of the economy into sector j (indirect R&D expenditure or embodied R&D) was also included in the model2.
γ j = c 1 + d 1   l o g ( R D j ) + d 2   l o g ( R D _ D I F j ) .
Equation (7) is in semi-log form because it is convenient that the coefficient of total sectoral R&D be interpreted as elasticity ( γ j ’s are already expressed in percentage change rates). The estimated R&D coefficients d1 and d2 are expected to be positive and statistically significant.

2.2. The Neoclassical Framework for Measuring TFP Change

TFP growth rate in neoclassical economics is residually determined after subtracting the growth rates of normally employed factor inputs, weighted by their income shares, from the output growth rate. An attempt is made here to review this method and amend it to be comparable to Equation (5). The literature on the issue is quite extensive. Both theoretical and empirical studies measure TFP as an indication of disembodied technical progress caused by R&D and R&D spillovers. Several literature reviews cover the subject (among others, Gollop and Jorgenson (1980); Mohnen (1989); Kydland and Prescott (1982); Griliches (1992); Coe and Helpman (1993); Bernstein and Mohnen (1994); Nadiri (1993); Katsoulacos and Tsounis (2000); Athanasoglou et al. (2008); Sakurai et al. (1996); Vamvakidis (2002); Aulin-Ahmavaara (2004); Vournakis (2007); Jones and Romer (2010); Sheng and Song (2013); Voutsinas and Tsamadias (2014); Gogos et al. (2013); Comin (2010); Haider et al. (2021); Próchniak (2016); Manasse (2016)).
Usually, TFP is expressed as production per unit of a composite index of inputs, appropriately aggregated. Two methods can be distinguished in the literature to calculate TFP: the growth accounting approach and the production function approach. Both methods produce the same results under the assumption of constant returns to scale and perfect competition in product and factor markets. TFP growth then corresponds to the concept of technical change which causes shifts in the production function, distinct from movements along the production function caused by factor substitution due to changes in relative factor prices (Jorgenson and Griliches 1967).
The growth accounting approach with input–output data will be used here. The use of input–output accounts allows the identification of a detailed cost structure in a given industry, covering the production structure of both primary and intermediate inputs. A word of caution is required regarding TFP indicators; they do not exactly correspond to technical change if competition does not prevail in both products and factor markets, or there are regulations distorting competition and/or externalities that cause scale economies. In particular, the effect of economies of scale is likely to be a major part of productivity growth in capital-intensive industries. In practice the distinction between economies of scale and pure technical change is difficult, but in theory, the contribution of economies of scale is distinguished from that of technical change in productivity growth.
TFP, for a sector or the economy as a whole, is generally defined as the ratio of the volume of production Y relative to the total volume of input X, i.e., TFP = Y X . Therefore, the growth rate of TFP is computed as:
T F P ˙ TFP = Y ˙ Y X ˙ X
where the dot indicates change (it can be seen also as the first derivative against time, i.e., for Y, Y ˙ = d Y d t etc). From Equation (8) it is seen that TFP growth is a residual between the rate of change in production and the rate of change in production inputs.
TFP change then is calculated as the change in output growth between two distinct points in time when all the remaining sources of output growth are subtracted. Therefore, we can identify apart from TFP, the contribution of primary factor productivity change in output growth, the contribution of capital, and the contribution of intermediate inputs of domestic and of imported origin. When examining Equation (8) for several successive points in time, substitution effects among inputs (intermediate of domestic and imported origin and labor and capital) can also be identified.
It is known that using value-added instead of gross output is a better indication of resource allocation3. Consequently, the value-added approach will be used here for measuring the TFP change according to the neoclassical approach.
Let
Y j V A = p j Y j i p i X i i t i X i i p i m X i m
be the value-added output of sector j at factor cost. Y denotes final product in physical units, X intermediate inputs in physical units, subscripts denote sectors, superscript m denotes imports, p denotes price, and t net indirect taxes per unit of product. Further,
T F P j ˙ T F P j = T F P j ^ = Y j V A T 1 Y j V A = ( Y j T 1 Y j ) p j Y j Y j V A
By totally differentiating Equation (9), substituting from Equation (8), and solving for T F P j ^ we get:
T F P j ^ = Y j V A ^ i ( w i L i Y j V A L j ^ ) Y j p j p j ^ Y j V A + i ( X i p i Y j V A p i ^ ) + i ( X i m p i m Y j V A p i m ^ ) + i ( X i t i Y j V A t i ^ )  
By substituting in Equation (11) l i * ,   y j * ,   x i * ,   m i *   and   t i * —the share of the value of the ith labor input in value-added j, the ratio of the value of output j over value-added j, the share of the value of domestic inputs in value-added j, the share of the value of imported inputs in value-added j and the share of net indirect taxes in value-added j, respectively—we get:
T F P j ^ = Y j V A ^ i l i * L j ^ y j * p j ^ + i x i * p i ^ + i m i * p i m ^ + i t i * t i ^
As can be seen, in Equation (12) T F P j ^ depends on p j ^ and therefore, the effects of monopoly power on sectoral TFP change rate have to be accounted for. So, an estimation similar to Equation (6) has been performed:
T F P j ^ = α 2 + β 2   S I j ^ + v j
The residuals of this regression are the sectoral TFP change rates without the effect of change of monopoly power on price change rates ( T F P j ) ^ .4 The expected sign of the coefficient again is negative. This can be derived easily from Equation (12); empirical studies examining the relationship between TFP change and change in sectoral concentration establish also a negative relationship (Bournakis 2012; Tsekouras and Daskalopoulou 2006). The results are reported in Appendix B. Equation (7) is estimated again with T F P j ^ as the dependent variable. A comparison of the estimation results of the two regressions will indicate which TFP methodology measures better technical progress caused by R&D expenditure, the neoclassical or FIE.

2.3. Data Description

Both FIE and neoclassical methods of TFP measurement have been applied to real-world data from the Greek economy to provide a comparison of the results between the two methods. As a background, we quickly remind the reader about the macroeconomic indicators in Greece during the studied period of 2010 to 2015. During this period Greece was struck by a deep recession as a result of the adjustment program imposed by the Troika to deal with the huge budget deficit and sovereign debt crisis following the 2008 financial crisis. The average annual real GDP growth for the period was −3.93%, the average price changes over the period were −2.3%, the average annual unemployment rate was 24.2% of the labor force, and the average annual current account balance was USD −9.9 billion (IMF 2021). Furthermore, there was an emigration of the most skilled and qualified individuals together with a fall in employment coupled with wage cuts of 22.5% to 23.2% dictated by the Troika (Agiomirgianakis et al. 2019).
The choice of the Greek economy was made for two reasons: (a) data availability, and (b) suitable macroeconomic indicators for making a comparison between the FIE and the neoclassical methods. Regarding the first reason, the use of Equation (5) for empirical work requires that input–output (i–o) table data report also labor inputs in physical terms; i.e., total hours worked per sector. These kinds of data are not available in the i–o tables reported for the EU countries by Eurostat and the OECD and were available for the Greek economy for the two years of the study only. Secondly, macroeconomic indicators for Greece during the examined period made the country ideal to compare the results of TFP growth calculated according to the new method introduced here (FIE) and the neoclassical one because according to theory5, when prices decrease, the neoclassical approach would underestimate TFP changes.
Sixty-four sector input–output tables of the Greek economy using the NACE rev.2 classification scheme for 2010 and 2015 (Hellenic Statistical Authority 2010, 2015) were used for the calculation of both the neoclassical and FIE approaches to sectoral TFP change. Output and import price data for the 64 sectors of the input–output tables were also extracted from Hellenic Statistical Authority (2016a, 2016b). Total sales data of the largest firms in each sector and total sectoral sales for the calculation of the Schmalensee index were obtained from the Hellenic Statistical Authority after special request (these data are not publicly available). Sectoral R&D expenditure data in constant prices for the period 2011–2015 were extracted from the OECD database (OECD 2011–2015).

3. Results and Discussion

Equations (5) and (12) were applied to the dataset and then Equation (6) was estimated to isolate the effect of change in monopoly power on sectoral TFP changes. Estimation results were checked for robustness by estimating Equation (6) using γj values calculated by input–output table data from the two different years, 2010 and 2015. Therefore, Equation (5) was calculated using A j * from both 2010 and 2015 input–output tables. The 2010 γ′j values can be called “Laspeyres values” as they use for their calculation the earlier year, while the 2015 γ′j values can be called “Paasche values” as they use for their calculation the more recent year. The results from the estimation of Equation (6) are presented in Appendix A together with the estimation diagnostics (Breusch–Pagan heteroskedasticity test, Jarque–Bera normality test, and statistical significance of the coefficients). The robustness check led to the conclusion that the estimated coefficient values using Laspeyres and Paasche γ′js and their statistical significance are almost identical.
Figure 1 depicts the γ′j values using data from the two years. As can be seen, most of them are on the 45° line. The Pearson correlation coefficient between the Laspeyres and Paasche γ′j s is 0.916, its t-statistic 17.98, and it is statistically significant at zero level of statistical significance. Additionally, the ranking of industries using the two types of γ′j index is almost identical; the Spearman rank correlation coefficient has a value of 0.966, with a t-statistic of 29.37 and it is statistically different from zero at zero level of statistical significance. Detailed descriptive statistics are reported in Table 1. The means for the indexes calculated using the production structure for both years are very close to their medians, indicating that there are not many outlier values.
Table A3 in Appendix B presents the results of the TFP change in the 64 sectors using the FIE approach using 2010 (Laspeyres γ′j) and 2015 (Paasche γ′j) as base years. The terms of trade effect ( β j * f j ^ in (5)) is also reported in separate columns. Thirty-three out of 64 sectors experienced a positive change in TFP while the remaining 31 sectors experienced a negative change. The first five sectors with the highest TFP change were services sectors (61, 44, 45, 33, 60) followed by transport equipment (21), chemical products (11), printing and recording services (9), and products of forestry, logging, and related services (2). Of the 33 sectors with a positive change in their TFP, 13 were services sectors. The highest negative change in TFP was experienced by the refined petroleum products and coke (10) and employment services (52) industries, while 21 of the 31 sectors with negative TFP change were also services sectors including telecommunication services (39), education services (56), and financial services (41).
The median value of the terms of trade contribution to the total price change was 0.057. In 40 sectors, the contribution of the terms of trade change to total prices change was less than 10%. These results can be attributed (a) to the degree of openness of the Greek economy; it is a relatively closed economy (its openness index has a value of about 40%) relative to the other EU countries (with an openness index of more than 70%), and (b) to the fact that international prices do not change much over five years. The sectors with the highest terms of trade effect on prices were pharmaceutical products (12), non-metallic mineral products (14), and machinery and equipment (19). Production of these sectors relies heavily on imported inputs.
We will now turn to compare the results with those found by the use of the neoclassical approach to TFP measurement. It is argued in Opocher and Steedman (2015) that when prices decrease, the neoclassical approach would underestimate the true rate of value-added TFP increase6. During the period 2010–2015 the average price change in all sectors was −2.295% (with a median of −2.825%). Therefore, neoclassical TFP changes were expected to be lower, on average, than the γs calculated according to FIE. To test this hypothesis, the mean and median values of the TFP change calculated according to the neoclassical and FIE approaches were compared7. For robustness, both the Laspeyres and Paasche methods were used in the test.
As can be seen from Table A3, the FIE approach yields, on average, higher values of TFP change than the neoclassical approach. Further, a test for equality of the means and medians of Table A3 was conducted to test whether the observed difference in means and medians was statistically significant. As can be seen from Appendix C, the difference in means and medians was statistically significant at a convenient (5%) level of statistical significance, which empirically confirms the prediction by theory.
Therefore, measuring sectoral total productivity change in the Greek economy by applying the FIE methodology has economic policy significance because it produces different estimates than the neoclassical one. This finding also affects the study of the effects of technical progress on TFP change, which may be different when the neoclassical methodology is used. Consequently, it is suggested that sectoral characteristics should be considered by the government in establishing relevant policies for enhancing sectoral productivity; generally, governments would like to focus their attention, with production enhancing measures, to sectors that produce positive rates of growth, contributing to the average growth of the economy. Specifically, by examining and comparing the results of Table A3 and Table A4, it is seen that during the examined period characterized by a great depression for the Greek economy, TFP growth rates were systematically underestimated when using the neoclassical method of measurement. As a result, fifteen sectors that exhibited positive TFP growth measured according to the approach proposed here would have been considered as sectors with negative TFP growth if the standard in the literature approach had been used, misleading policymakers to divert measures away from these sectors8 and hampering the overall growth rate of the economy.
The knowledge produced outside a sector, in other sectors of the same economy or abroad, may be important for sectoral TFP change. We tested the hypothesis that the main drivers of TFP change lie with the R&D conducted within a sector and the R&D diffused by other sectors into the sector. For testing this hypothesis, Equation (7) was used and the results are reported in Table 2.
Ex ante, one may expect that R&D diffused by other sectors is related to the R&D conducted within a sector, since the absorptive capacity of new knowledge is related to the level of knowledge existing in a sector. If the relation between the regressors of the model is high, it will cause a multicollinearity problem in the estimation of Equation (7). The presence of multicollinearity affects the variance of the estimated coefficients but not their value. The variance inflation factors (VIF) test was conducted to ensure that the correlation between regressors did not affect significantly the variance of the coefficients (and therefore, their statistical significance). VIF is a method of measuring how much the variance of an estimated regression coefficient is increased due to collinearity. If VIF is less than 5 then it is accepted that multicollinearity is not high (Sheather 2009). The VIF for the coefficients of l o g ( R D j ) for all models was about 1.60 (second column, Table 2) and for the coefficients of l o g ( R D _ D I F j ) about 1.09 (third column, Table 2). Therefore, VIF for all estimated coefficients in all models was less than 5 and it is concluded that multicollinearity is not a problem in the estimation of Equation (7).
R D j is sectoral total R&D expenditure, in constant prices, for the period 2011–2015 and R D _ D I F j is R&D diffusion from the total R&D expenditure of other sectors of the economy into sector j (indirect R&D expenditure or embodied R&D). As can be seen from the last two columns, the residuals from all three estimations passed the normality and heteroskedasticity tests. R&D expenditure coefficients estimated by using TFP change calculated by the FIE method were consistently higher than those estimated by the neoclassical method and their statistical significance is also higher. Furthermore, both models with FIE measures performed better than the model with the neoclassical measure of sectoral TFP change in terms of adjusted R2 and AIC9 which, in turn, implies that the FIE method of measurement TFP change is better than the neoclassical one. The estimated coefficient of the R&D expenditure variable found using the neoclassical method of TFP change (0.097) was within the range value of the coefficients found by other studies for the Greek economy (0.0192 to 0.127) (Bournakis 2012; Voutsinas and Tsamadias 2014; Gogos et al. 2013; Tsekouras and Daskalopoulou 2006). The results (Table 2) indicate that sectoral TFP change depends on R&D expenditure, both in the form of direct sectoral investment and indirect, diffused by other sectors. A comparison of the values of the coefficients shows that direct sectoral R&D investment has about triple the effect on TFP change compared to diffused R&D from other sectors. Indirect R&D affects TFP change but the coefficients are significantly lower than in-sector R&D. Additionally, the models with the FIE measures of TFP change performed better for the effects of in-sector technical progress measured by total sectoral R&D expenditure and R&D diffused by the other sectors of the economy. All R&D coefficients had the expected sign.
The value of the sectoral R&D expenditure coefficient (0.29) is important for policymakers. It means that if R&D expenditure is increased by 1% on average in all sectors, TFP growth will contribute to the total growth of the economy by (a conservative estimate10 of) 0.29% plus another 0.09% from the R&D diffusion (indirect R&D expenditures)11. The productivity of the Greek economy could be enhanced by higher R&D expenditure combined with the necessary structural reforms to improve the efficiency of the innovation system, especially when the sectors with higher and positive TFP growth are given incentives to increase their investment in R&D and/or government spending in projects related to R&D. This policy targeting is specifically important during recession times because negative growth rates of an economy can be reduced or even turned to positive by enhancing TFP growth rates.

4. Conclusions

The paper provides a new approach to the neoclassical method for the measurement of total factor productivity change based on the full industry equilibrium methodology accounting for heterogeneous labor inputs, imported inputs, indirect taxes, and monopoly power. This is a completely new method that uses changes in prices as a basis to measure TFP growth and not changes in output used by the literature until now. Empirical findings from the application of the method to real-world data from the Greek economy are provided together with a comparison with those found by using the neoclassical approach to TFP change. Additionally, total sectoral R&D and indirect R&D diffused by other sectors of the economy were tested to be the main drivers of TFP change.
The empirical findings suggest that the FIE methodology (the price accounting approach) produces different sectoral TFP change results from the neoclassical approach. It was found that during the period examined, where the Greek economy was overwhelmed by a deep recession and consequently was characterized by systematic price decreases, the neoclassical approach underestimated sectoral TFP change, providing a less accurate measurement. Further, estimation results indicate that when the FIE approach for TFP change measurement is used for R&D expenditure (total sectoral and diffused from other sectors) the quality of the model is higher than that using the neoclassical methodology for TFP change measurement.
Measuring productivity change in each industry of the Greek economy by applying the FIE methodology has economic policy significance because it showed that the effects of technical progress measured by R&D expenditure on the disembodied productivity of the factors of production are different from the measures derived from the orthodox neoclassical economic theory. Specifically, in evaluating and comparing the results of the new technique with those of the neoclassical method, it became clear that TFP growth rates were systematically underestimated when employing the latter throughout the analyzed period, which was marked by a significant slump for the Greek economy. As a result, fifteen sectors that had positive TFP growth measured according to the approach proposed here would have been classified as having negative TFP growth if the standard in the literature approach had been used, leading policymakers to divert resources away from these sectors, slowing the economy’s overall growth rate. Higher R&D spending, combined with necessary structural reforms to improve the efficiency of the innovation system, could boost the productivity of the Greek economy, particularly if sectors with higher and positive TFP growth were given incentives to increase their investment in R&D and/or government spending on R&D projects. This policy targeting is especially crucial during recessions since improving TFP growth rates might help an economy’s negative growth rates to be lowered or even turned positive. State intervention with targeted sectoral R&D policy will be misleading if the neoclassical method has been used as a measurement of TFP change. This leads to quite different policy emphases in deciding R&D tax breaks and direct R&D investments, especially during periods of systematic price increases (decreases) where the neoclassical approach overestimates (underestimates) sectoral TFP changes.
Increased public R&D spending, as well as incentives for the private sector to increase R&D spending, could boost productivity and hence lead to economic growth. Parallel to this, the implementation of policies in Greece that encourage private R&D investment and innovation will help the public sector make better use of its knowledge. More attention should be placed on improving R&D capabilities, including human capital and infrastructure, strengthening relationships between small and medium-sized businesses, research institutions, and universities, establishing a venture capital market, and increasing labor mobility in this framework. This analysis should be expanded to include the following dimensions: first, more determinants of TFP growth, particularly human capital and R&D diffused in the economy via trade flows and FDI (subject to data availability12); second, the results could be re-examined using regional data for the Greek economy; third, total sectoral R&D expenditure was considered for five years in our analysis of the effects of R&D expenditure on TFP growth. R&D capital is determined by applying a uniform discounting rate to R&D expenses in time-series studies with a large number of years. This “radioactive” uniform depreciation across all sectors, on the other hand, has the disadvantage of being distant from the genuine one. It would be interesting to look at how Greece’s economic adjustment program has altered the link between R&D capital and TFP since 2010. No doubt the reader will think of other interesting and possible developments of the method introduced here.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, I.S.; methodology, I.S. and N.T.; resources, N.T.; data curation, N.T.; applied work, N.T.; writing—original draft preparation, N.T. and I.S. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

Financial assistance from research grant 80325 by the Research Committee of the University of Western Macedonia is gratefully acknowledged.

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

Main datasets used by the study are publicly available from the Hellenic Statistical Authority: https://www.statistics.gr/en/statistics/eco (accessed on 3 August 2021).

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A. Descriptive Statistics for Measures of Sectoral TFP Change and Estimation Results from Equation (6)

Table A1. Descriptive statistics for γ′j Laspeyres, γ′j Paasche, and neoclassical TFP change.
Table A1. Descriptive statistics for γ′j Laspeyres, γ′j Paasche, and neoclassical TFP change.
γ′j
Laspeyres
γ′j
Paasche
T F P j ^
Mean3.47 × 10−185.20 × 10−18−0.061147
Median0.0083590.000137−0.028878
Maximum0.2716320.7055790.023373
Minimum−0.534969−0.516493−1.359287
Std. Dev.0.1291800.1592550.176366
Skewness−1.1821860.759561−6.476690
Kurtosis7.0158869.15284347.56073
Jarque–Bera57.91358107.10725742.530
Probability0.0000000.0000000.000000
Sum1.11 × 10−161.67 × 10−16−3.913377
Sum Sq. Dev.1.0513071.5978181.959617
Observations646464
Source: Authors’ calculations from Table A3 and Table A4.
Table A2. Estimation results from Equations (6) and (13).
Table A2. Estimation results from Equations (6) and (13).
Dependent
Variable
RegressandCoefficient
(Probability)
Intercept
(Probability)
R2adjBreusch–Pagan–Godfrey
Heteroskedasticity Test:
F-Statistic (Prob. F(1,62))
Jarque–Bera
Normality Test (Probability)
γ′j Laspeyres S I j ^ −0.097537
(0.0000)
0.003836
(0.0872)
0.3295280.408730
(0.5250)
57.91358
(0.000000)
γ′j Paasche S I j ^ −0.097677
(0.0000)
0.019104
(0.0948)
0.2764000.000572
(0.9810)
107.1072
(0.000000)
T F P j ^ S I j ^ −0.098707
(0.0000)
0.022113
(0.0625)
0.2238280.108699
(0.7427)
5742.530
(0.000000)
Source: Authors’ estimations.

Appendix B. TFP Change Calculated According to the FIE and the Neoclassical Approaches

Table A3. TFP change calculated by the FIE approach.
Table A3. TFP change calculated by the FIE approach.
NoSector Descriptionγ′j LaspeyresRankγ′j Paasche RankTerms of Trade Effect LaspeyresTerms of Trade Effect Paasche
1Products of agriculture, hunting, and related services0.04821−0.023380.0070.007
2Products of forestry, logging, and related services0.13290.091140.0050.002
3Fish and other fishing products; aquaculture products; support services to fishing−0.06750−0.092520.0050.004
4Mining and quarrying−0.12059−0.13257−0.050−0.051
5Food products, beverages, and tobacco products−0.04043−0.045440.0150.014
6Textiles, wearing apparel, and leather products0.068150.078150.0320.038
7Wood and products of wood and cork, except furniture; articles of straw and plaiting materials−0.001340.060180.0150.020
8Paper and paper products0.01032−0.002330.0150.014
9Printing and recording services0.13480.12980.0000.000
10Coke and refined petroleum products −0.53564−0.51664−0.037−0.042
11Chemicals and chemical products0.14470.13170.0310.031
12Basic pharmaceutical products and pharmaceutical preparations−0.04745−0.06549−0.095−0.093
13Rubber and plastics products0.012300.012280.0110.011
14Other non-metallic mineral products0.007330.009310.0050.006
15Basic metals0.044230.057190.0000.000
16Fabricated metal products, except machinery and equipment0.016290.022240.0020.003
17Computer, electronic, and optical products0.027260.01129−0.004−0.004
18Electrical equipment0.119110.109110.0180.018
19Machinery and equipment n.e.c.0.046220.036210.0220.023
20Motor vehicles, trailers, and semi-trailers0.127100.11610−0.009−0.009
21Other transport equipment0.14560.13360.0000.000
22Furniture; other manufactured goods0.102120.104120.0070.007
23Repair and installation services of machinery and equipment0.029240.014250.0000.000
24Electricity, gas, steam, and air-conditioning−0.24062−0.33863−0.009−0.010
25Natural water; water treatment and supply services−0.05347−0.012350.0000.000
26Sewerage; waste collection, treatment, and disposal activities; materials recovery; remediation activities and other waste management services −0.013390.010300.0030.002
27Constructions and construction works−0.05949−0.062460.0000.000
28Wholesale and retail trade and repair services of motor vehicles and motorcycles−0.01841−0.034410.0000.000
29Wholesale trade services, except of motor vehicles and motorcycles0.011310.002320.0000.000
30Retail trade services, except of motor vehicles and motorcycles0.049200.026230.0000.000
31Land transport services and transport services via pipelines−0.16461−0.218610.0010.001
32Water transport services−0.01036−0.027390.0000.000
33Air transport services0.19340.26130.0410.079
34Warehousing and support services for transportation−0.01037−0.046450.0030.002
35Postal and courier services0.065170.069160.0030.003
36Accommodation and food services−0.04144−0.042430.0000.000
37Publishing services−0.09854−0.13959−0.002−0.003
38Motion picture, video and television program production services, sound recording and music publishing; programming and broadcasting services−0.05146−0.06347−0.011−0.018
39Telecommunications services−0.01038−0.02137−0.002−0.002
40Computer programming, consultancy and related services; information services−0.00735−0.02036−0.006−0.004
41Financial services, except insurance and pension funding−0.02742−0.03942−0.001−0.001
42Insurance, reinsurance and pension funding services, except compulsory social security0.066160.06517−0.034−0.023
43Services auxiliary to financial services and insurance services−0.07452−0.063480.0000.000
44Real estate activities without imputed rents0.24520.70610.0000.000
45Imputed rents0.20330.18350.0000.000
46Legal and accounting services; services of head offices; management consulting services−0.12360−0.11055−0.001−0.001
47Architectural and engineering services; technical testing and analysis services−0.07151−0.081500.0000.000
48Scientific research and development services−0.11557−0.117560.0000.000
49Advertising and market research services−0.08753−0.101530.0000.000
50Other professional, scientific and technical services; veterinary services0.022280.04320−0.002−0.002
51Rental and leasing services0.100130.09213−0.023−0.008
52Employment services−0.36863−0.301620.0000.000
53Travel agency, tour operator and other reservation services and related services0.029250.013260.0000.000
54Security and investigation services; services to buildings and landscape; office administrative, office support and other business support services−0.11355−0.10154−0.001−0.001
55Public administration and defense services; compulsory social security services0.026270.013270.0000.000
56Education services−0.01740−0.029400.0000.000
57Human health services−0.05348−0.081510.0000.000
58Social work services−0.11356−0.208600.0000.000
59Creative, arts, and entertainment services; library, archive, museum and other cultural services; gambling and betting services0.05618−0.00334−0.005−0.001
60Sporting services and amusement and recreation services0.18250.20040.0000.000
61Services furnished by membership organizations0.27210.31520.0000.000
62Repair services of computers and personal and household goods0.077140.11990.0000.000
63Other personal services0.056190.034220.0000.000
64Services of households as employers; undifferentiated goods and services produced by households for own use −0.11958−0.132580.0000.000
Negative change rates in red. Source: Authors’ calculations.
Table A4. TFP change measured according to the neoclassical approach.
Table A4. TFP change measured according to the neoclassical approach.
Sector Description T F P j ^   Rank
1Products of agriculture, hunting, and related services0.00611
2Products of forestry, logging, and related services0.0193
3Fish and other fishing products; aquaculture products; support services to fishing−0.03034
4Mining and quarrying−0.40063
5Food products, beverages, and tobacco products−0.03738
6Textiles, wearing apparel, and leather products−0.01926
7Wood and products of wood and cork, except furniture; articles of straw and plaiting materials−0.14862
8Paper and paper products−0.05144
9Printing and recording services−0.04041
10Coke and refined petroleum products −1.35964
11Chemicals and chemical products0.0145
12Basic pharmaceutical products and pharmaceutical preparations−0.12459
13Rubber and plastics products−0.01022
14Other non-metallic mineral products−0.05547
15Basic metals0.00217
16Fabricated metal products, except machinery and equipment−0.01825
17Computer, electronic, and optical products0.00313
18Electrical equipment0.0098
19Machinery and equipment n.e.c.0.00215
20Motor vehicles, trailers, and semi-trailers0.00214
21Other transport equipment0.0116
22Furniture; other manufactured goods−0.00521
23Repair and installation services of machinery and equipment0.00118
24Electricity, gas, steam, and air-conditioning−0.08353
25Natural water; water treatment and supply services−0.02832
26Sewerage; waste collection, treatment, and disposal activities; materials recovery; remediation activities and other waste management services −0.03637
27Constructions and construction works−0.11958
28Wholesale and retail trade and repair services of motor vehicles and motorcycles−0.06950
29Wholesale trade services, except for motor vehicles and motorcycles−0.01324
30Retail trade services, except for motor vehicles and motorcycles−0.02328
31Land transport services and transport services via pipelines−0.06749
32Water transport services−0.01023
33Air transport services0.0089
34Warehousing and support services for transportation−0.02027
35Postal and courier services−0.09255
36Accommodation and food services−0.04643
37Publishing services−0.09757
38Motion picture, video, and television program production services, sound recording and music publishing; programming and broadcasting services−0.09556
39Telecommunications services−0.04042
40Computer programming, consultancy, and related services; information services−0.03739
41Financial services, except insurance and pension funding−0.05346
42Insurance, reinsurance, and pension funding services, except compulsory social security−0.08954
43Services auxiliary to financial services and insurance services−0.03033
44Real estate activities without imputed rents0.0184
45Imputed rents0.0107
46Legal and accounting services; services of head offices; management consulting services−0.05245
47Architectural and engineering services; technical testing and analysis services−0.05748
48Scientific research and development services−0.07852
49Advertising and market research services−0.02630
50Other professional, scientific, and technical services; veterinary services−0.02831
51Rental and leasing services0.00610
52Employment services−0.14761
53Travel agency, tour operator, and other reservation services and related services0.00216
54Security and investigation services; services to buildings and landscape; office administrative, office support, and other business support services−0.03035
55Public administration and defense services; compulsory social security services−0.00219
56Education services−0.02529
57Human health services−0.03940
58Social work services−0.07651
59Creative, arts and entertainment services; library, archive, museum, and other cultural services; gambling and betting services0.00512
60Sporting services and amusement and recreation services0.0212
61Services furnished by membership organizations0.0231
62Repair services of computers and personal and household goods−0.00320
63Other personal services−0.03436
64Services of households as employers; undifferentiated goods and services produced by households for own use −0.13860
Negative change rates in red. Source: Authors’ calculations.

Appendix C. Test of the Equality of Means and Medians of TFP Change Measured According to the Neoclassical and FIE Approaches

T F P ^ vs. γ′ Laspeyres T F P ^ vs. γ′ Paasche
Test for Equality of Means
Anova F-test, significance level in parentheses
5.006844
(0.0272)
4.237668
(0.0416)
Test for Equality of Medians
Kruskal–Wallis, significance level in parentheses
9.565793
(0.0020)
6.093841
(0.0136)
Test for Equality of Medians
Kruskal–Wallis (tie-adj.), significance level in parentheses
9.565793
(0.0020)
6.093841
(0.0136)
Test for Equality of Medians
van der Waerden, significance level in parentheses
9.938526
(0.0016)
6.613421
(0.0101)
Source: Authors’ calculations.

Notes

1
In the empirical work that follows it is considered that this assumption cannot be applied to real-world data. The existence of monopoly power is acknowledged and its effects on prices is isolated using regression analysis.
2
Following Leontief’s methodology (Leontief 1986) R D _ D I F = R D ( I A * ) 1 R D . R D _ D I F j is the jth element of R D _ D I F .
3
4
T F P j ^ throughout the paper is used to denote the per centage change in sectoral TFP calculated according to the neoclassical methodology.
5
See Section 3 Results and Discussion for a further explanation on this.
6
See Opocher and Steedman (2015, pp. 162–63) for its theoretical proof.
7
TFP’ change according to the neoclassical approach was estimated from (13) and the results are reported in Appendix B.
8
These sectors are: 6 Textiles, wearing apparel and leather products, 8 Paper and paper products, 9 Printing and recording services, 13 Rubber and plastics products, 14 Other non-metallic mineral products, 16 Fabricated metal products, 22 Furniture, 29 Wholesale trade services, 30 Retail trade services, 35 Postal and courier services, 42 Insurance, 50 Other professional, scientific and technical services, 55 Public administration and defence services, 62 Repair services of computers, 63 Other personal services.
9
If a model is more than 2 AIC units lower than another, it is considered significantly better than that model.
10
By ‘conservatives estimates’ we mean the coefficients eatimated when TFP growth was calculated according to the Paasche method of base year since these are systematically lower that those calculated accoring to the Laspeyres method of base year.
11
Since, the estimation results were obtained by total R&D expedtiture over the period 2010–2015 an 1% increase in R& expenditure does not refer to the annual figures but to the total five-year period.
12
It was not possible to include in the present paper the effects of R&D diffusion from abroad because import matrices were not available.

References

  1. Agiomirgianakis, George, Georg Bertsatos, and Nicholas Tsounis. 2019. Gender Wage Gaps and Economic Crisis in Greece. International Review of Applied Economics 33: 254–76. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Akinlo, Anthony Enisan, and Omowumi Adejumo. 2016. Determinants of Total Factor Productivity Growth in Nigeria, 1970–2009. Global Business Review 17: 257–70. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Amri, Fethi, Younes Ben Zaied, and Bechir Ben Lahouel. 2019. ICT, total factor productivity, and carbon dioxide emissions in Tunisia. Technological Forecasting and Social Change 146: 212–17. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Arazmuradov, Annageldy, Gianmaria Martini, and Davide Scotti. 2014. Determinants of total factor productivity in former Soviet Union economies: A stochastic frontier approach. Economic Systems 38: 115–35. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  5. Athanasoglou, Panayiotis, Evangelia Georgiou, and Christos Staikouras. 2008. Assessing Output and Productivity Growth in the Banking Industry. Working Paper. Athens: Bank of Greece. [Google Scholar]
  6. Aulin-Ahmavaara, Pirkko. 2004. Aggregation of Industry-Level TFP-measures. Paper presented at the International Conference on Input-Output and General Equilibrium: Data, Modeling and Policy Analysis, Jointly Organized by the EcoMod Network and the IIOA, Free University of Brussels, Brussels, Belgium, September 2–4. [Google Scholar]
  7. Bernstein, Jeffrey, and Pierre Mohnen. 1994. International R&D Spillovers between US and Japanese R&D Intensive Sectors. NBER Working Paper No. 4682. New York: NBER. [Google Scholar]
  8. Bhattacharya, Mita, Luka Emeka Okafor, and Pradeep Valarmathi. 2021. International firm activities, R&D, and productivity: Evidence from Indian manufacturing firms. Economic Modelling 97: 1–13. [Google Scholar]
  9. Bournakis, Ioannis. 2012. Sources of TFP growth in a framework of convergence-evidence from Greece. International Review of Applied Economics 26: 47–72. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  10. Coe, David, and Elhanan Helpman. 1993. International R&D Spillovers. NBER Working Paper Series No. 4444; New York: NBER. [Google Scholar]
  11. Comin, Diego. 2010. Total Factor Productivity. In Economic Growth. The New Palgrave Economics Collection. Edited by Steven Durlauf and Lawrence Blume. London: Palgrave Macmillan. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  12. Danska-Borsiak, Barbara. 2018. Determinants of total factor productivity in Visegrad Group nuts-2 regions. Acta Oeconomica 68: 31–50. [Google Scholar]
  13. Donghyun, Oh, Almas Heshmati, and Hans Lööf. 2014. Total factor productivity of Korean manufacturing industries: Comparison of competing models with firm-level data. Japan and the World Economy 30: 25–36. [Google Scholar]
  14. Doumi, Ali. 2017. Measurement of Total Factor Productivity in Agriculture: Study on a Panel of Mediterranean Countries (1980–2012). Journal of International and Global Economic Studies 9: 41–56. [Google Scholar]
  15. Eberhardt, Markus, Christian Helmers, and Hubert Strauss. 2013. Do spillovers matter when estimating private returns to R&D? Review of Economics and Statistics 95: 436–48. [Google Scholar]
  16. Edquist, Harald, and Magnus Henrekson. 2006. Technological breakthroughs and productivity growth. Research in Economic History 24: 1–53. [Google Scholar]
  17. Gehringeer, Agnieszka, Inmaculada Martínez-Zarzoso, and Felicitas Nowak-Lehmann Danzinger. 2015. What are the drivers of total factor productivity in the European Union? Economics of Innovation and New Technology 25: 406–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Giang, Mai Huong, Tran Dang Xuan, Bui Huy Trung, and Mai Thanh Que. 2019. Total Factor Productivity of Agricultural Firms in Vietnam and Its Relevant Determinants. Economies 7: 4. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  19. Gogos, Stylianos, Nikolaos Mylonidis, Dimitris Papageorgiou, and Vanghelis Vassilatos. 2013. 1979–2001: A Greek great depression through the lens of neoclassical growth theory. Economic Modelling 36: 316–31. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Gollop, Frank, and Dale Jorgenson. 1980. U.S. Productivity Growth by Industry, 1947–1973. In New Developments in Productivity Measurement and Analysis. Edited by John Kendrick and Beatrice Vaccara. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. [Google Scholar]
  21. Griffith, Rachel, Stephen James Redding, and John Van Reenen. 2004. Mapping the two faces of R&D: Productivity growth in a panel of OECD industries. Review of Economics and Statistics 86: 883–95. [Google Scholar]
  22. Griliches, Zvi. 1979. Issues in assessing the contribution of research and development to productivity growth. Bell Journal of Economics 10: 92–116. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Griliches, Zvi. 1992. The Search for R&D Spillovers. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 94: 29–47. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Griliches, Zvi. 1994. Productivity, R&D and the data constraint. American Economic Review 84: 1–23. [Google Scholar]
  25. Haider, Franz, Robert Kunst, and Franz Wirl. 2021. Total factor productivity, its components and drivers. Empirica 48: 283–327. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  26. Haider, Salman, Aadil Ganaie, and Bandi Kamaiah. 2019. Total factor productivity and openness in Indian economy: 1970–2011. Foreign Trade Review 54: 46–57. [Google Scholar]
  27. Hall, Bronwyn, Jacques Mairesse, and Pierre Mohnen. 2009. Measuring the Returns to R&D. NBER Working Paper No. 15622. Cambridge: National Bureau of Economic Research. [Google Scholar]
  28. Harris, Richard, and John Moffat. 2020. The impact of product subsidies on plant-level total factor productivity in Britain, 1997–2014. Scottish Journal of Political Economy 67: 387–403. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Hellenic Statistical Authority. 2010. Input-Output Tables. Athens: Hellenic Statistical Authority. [Google Scholar]
  30. Hellenic Statistical Authority. 2015. Input-Output Tables. Athens: Hellenic Statistical Authority. [Google Scholar]
  31. Hellenic Statistical Authority. 2016a. Annual Average Indices of Import Price Index. Athens: Hellenic Statistical Authority. [Google Scholar]
  32. Hellenic Statistical Authority. 2016b. Annual Consumer Price Indices. Athens: Hellenic Statistical Authority. [Google Scholar]
  33. Hirschman, Albert. 1964. The Paternity of an Index. The American Economic Review 54: 761–62. [Google Scholar]
  34. Huang, Junbing, Xiaochen Cai, Shuo Huang, Sen Tian, and Hongyan Lei. 2019. Technological factors and total factor productivity in China: Evidence based on a panel threshold model. China Economic Review 54: 271–85. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2021. World Economic Outlook (WEO) Database. Washington: IMF Pubmications. [Google Scholar]
  36. Jones, Charles, and Paul Michael Romer. 2010. The New Kaldor Facts: Ideas, Institutions, Population, and Human Capital. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 2: 224–45. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  37. Jorgenson, Dale, and Zvi Griliches. 1967. The Explanation of Productivity Change. The Review of Economic Studies 34: 249–83. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Katsoulacos, Yannis, and Nicholas Tsounis. 2000. Knowledge Intensive Business Services and Productivity Growth: The Greek Evidence. In Services and the Knowledge-Based Economy. Edited by Mark Boden and Ian Miles. London: Continuum, Chapter 11. [Google Scholar]
  39. Kéïta, Kouramoudou, and Laurila Hannu. 2021. Corruption and Tax Burden: What Is the Joint Effect on Total Factor Productivity? Economies 9: 26. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Kim, Sangho. 2016. Factor determinants of total factor productivity growth for the Japanese manufacturing industry. Contemporary Economic Policy 34: 572–86. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Kydland, Finn, and Edward Prescott. 1982. Time to Build and Aggregate Fluctuations. Econometrica 50: 1345–70. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Leontief, Wassili. 1986. Input-Output Economics. New York: Oxford University Press. [Google Scholar]
  43. Lerner, Abba. 1934. The Concept of Monopoly and the Measurement of Monopoly Power. The Review of Economic Studies 1: 157–75. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Lucas, Robert. 1988. On the mechanics of economic development. Journal of Monetary Economics 22: 3–42. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Manasse, Paolo. 2016. Lessons for Europe from the Greek Crisis. In A New Growth Model for the Greek Economy. Edited by Panagiotis Petrakis. New York: Palgrave Macmillan, Chapter 5. [Google Scholar]
  46. Mohnen, Pierre. 1989. New Technologies and Inter-Industry Spillovers. In STI Review. Paris: OECD, pp. 131–47. [Google Scholar]
  47. Nadiri, Ishaq. 1993. Innovations and Technological Spillovers. NBER Working Paper No. 4423. New York: NBER. [Google Scholar]
  48. Ngo, Quang-Thanh, Quang-Van Tran, Tien-Dung Nguyen, and Trung-Thanh Nguyen. 2020. How Heterogeneous Are the Determinants of Total Factor Productivity in Manufacturing Sectors? Panel-Data Evidence from Vietnam. Economies 8: 57. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. OECD. 2011–2015. R-D Expenditure by Industry. Paris: OECD. [Google Scholar]
  50. Opocher, Arrigo. 2010. Measuring Productivity Increase by Long-run Prices: The Early Analyses of G.R. Porter and R.Giffen. European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 17: 1271–91. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Opocher, Arrigo, and Ian Steedman. 2015. Full Industry Equilibrium: A Theory of the Industrial Long Run. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. [Google Scholar]
  52. Otsuka, Akihiro. 2017. Regional determinants of total factor productivity in Japan: Stochastic frontier analysis. Annals of Regional Science 58: 579–96. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Pegkas, Panagiotis, Christos Staikouras, and Constantinos Tsamadias. 2020. Does Domestic and Foreign R&D Capital Affect Total Factor Productivity? Evidence from Eurozone Countries. International Economic Journal 34: 258–78. [Google Scholar]
  54. Próchniak, Mariusz. 2016. Changes in Total Factor Productivity. In The Role of Economic Policy and Institutions. Edited by Marzenna Weresa, Zbigniew Matkowski and Ryszard Rapacki. Warsaw: World Economy Research Institute, SGH Warsaw School of Economics. [Google Scholar]
  55. Romer, Paul Michael. 1986. Increasing Returns and Long-Run Growth. Journal of Political Economy 94: 1002–37. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  56. Romer, Paul Michael. 1994. The Origins of Endogenous Growth. Journal of Economic Perspectives 8: 3–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  57. Sakurai, Norihisa, Evangelos Ioannidis, and George Papaconstantinou. 1996. The Impact of R&D and Technology Diffusion on Productivity Growth: Evidence for 10 OECD Countries in the 1970s and 1980s. OECD Science, Technology and Industry Working Papers, 1996/02. Paris: OECD Publishing. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Saleem, Hummera, Malik Shahzad, Muhammad Bilar Khan, and Bashir Ahmad Khilji. 2019. Innovation, total factor productivity and economic growth in Pakistan: A policy perspective. Economic Structures 8: 7. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Schmalensee, Richard. 1977. Using the H-Index of concentration with published data. Review of Economics and Statistics 59: 186–93. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Shabbir, Malik Shahzad, and Nusrat Yaqoob. 2019. The impact of technological advancement on total factor productivity of cotton: A comparative analysis between Pakistan and India. Journal of Economic Structures 8: 1–16. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  61. Sharif, Naubahar, Kevin Chandra, Athar Mansoor, and Kirti Sinha. 2021. A comparative analysis of research and development spending and total factor productivity growth in Hong Kong, Shenzhen, Singapore. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 57: 108–20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  62. Sheather, Simon. 2009. A Modern Approach to Regression with R. New York: Springer. [Google Scholar]
  63. Shen, Yongchang, Shujing Yue, Shiqian Sun, and Mengqi Guo. 2020. Sustainable total factor productivity growth: The case of China. Journal of Cleaner Production 256: 120727. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  64. Sheng, Yu, and Ligang Song. 2013. Re-estimation of firms’ total factor productivity in China’s iron and steel industry. China Economic Review 24: 177–88. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  65. Silveira, Naijela Janaina Costa, Diogo Ferraz, Diego Scarpa de Mello, Eduardo Polloni-Silva, Herick Fernando Moralles, and Daisy Rebelatto. 2021. Calculating Models for Total Factor Productivity Measurement. Exacta. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  66. Solow, Robert. 1956. A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 70: 65–94. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  67. Tsamadias, Constantinos, Panagiotis Pegkas, Emmanuel Mamatzakis, and Christos Staikouras. 2019. Does R&D, human capital and FDI matter for TFP in OECD countries? Economics of Innovation and New Technology 28: 386–406. [Google Scholar]
  68. Tsekouras, Kostas, and Irene Daskalopoulou. 2006. Market Concentration and Multifaceted and Productive Efficiency. Journal of Productivity Analysis 25: 79–91. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  69. Vamvakidis, Athanasios. 2002. How Robust is the Growth-Openness Connection? Historical Evidence. Journal of Economic Growth 7: 57–80. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  70. Venturini, Francesco. 2015. The modern drivers of productivity. Research Policy 44: 357–69. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  71. Vournakis, Ioannis. 2007. Productivity Convergence between Greece and Germany, What Is the Role for Trade and R&D. Paper presented at Ninth Annual Conference, European Trade Study Group, Athens, Greece, September 13–15. [Google Scholar]
  72. Voutsinas, Ioannis, and Constantinos Tsamadias. 2014. Does research and development capital affect total factor productivity? Evidence from Greece. Economics of Innovation and New Technology 23: 17–36. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  73. Yue, Shujing, Yongchang Shen, and Jianhong Yuan. 2019. Sustainable total factor productivity growth for 55 states: An application of the new malmquist index considering ecological footprint and human development index. Resources Conservation and Recycling 146: 475–83. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. γ′js scatter diagram calculated with 2010 and 2015 A j * . Source: Authors’ calculations.
Figure 1. γ′js scatter diagram calculated with 2010 and 2015 A j * . Source: Authors’ calculations.
Economies 09 00114 g001
Table 1. Mean and median values of TFP change over the period 2010–2015 calculated according to the neoclassical and FIE approaches.
Table 1. Mean and median values of TFP change over the period 2010–2015 calculated according to the neoclassical and FIE approaches.
T F P ^ γ′ Laspeyresγ′ Paasche
Mean−0.0611473.47 × 10−185.20 × 10−18
Median−0.0288780.0083590.000137
Source: Authors’ calculations (extracted from Appendix A).
Table 2. Estimation results from Equation (7).
Table 2. Estimation results from Equation (7).
Dependent VariableRegressand
l o g ( R D j )
Coefficient
(Probability)
VIF
Regressand
l o g ( R D _ D I F j )
Coefficient
(Probability)
VIF
Intercept
Coefficient
(Probability)
R2adjAICBreusch–Pagan–Godfrey Heteroskedasticity Test: F-Statistic (Prob. F(1,62))Jarque–Bera Normality Test (Probability)
γ′j Laspeyres0.371130 **
(0.0000)
1.598850
0.121866 **
(0.0095)
1.089770
0.301901 *
(0.0286)
0.340701−3.03550.002124
(0.9634)
74.66734
(0.0000)
γ′j Paasche0.290525 **
(0.0009)
1.585329
0.093667 **
(0.0004)
1.080817
0.430790 *
(0.0430)
0.245685−2.61070.996554
(0.3220)
33.14470
(0.0000)
T F P j ^ 0.097113 +
(0.0865)
1.598755
0.057560 *
(0.0321)
1.089971
0.046521 +
(0.0525)
0.149678−1.05020.263140
(0.6098)
5698.413
(0.0000)
**, *, + statistically different from zero at least at 1%, 5%, and 10% level of statistical significance, respectively; AIC: Akaike information criterion is a measure of the relative quality of a statistical model for a given set of data and, therefore, it provides a means for model selection. Source: Authors’ estimations.
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Tsounis, N.; Steedman, I. A New Method for Measuring Total Factor Productivity Growth Based on the Full Industry Equilibrium Approach: The Case of the Greek Economy. Economies 2021, 9, 114. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies9030114

AMA Style

Tsounis N, Steedman I. A New Method for Measuring Total Factor Productivity Growth Based on the Full Industry Equilibrium Approach: The Case of the Greek Economy. Economies. 2021; 9(3):114. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies9030114

Chicago/Turabian Style

Tsounis, Nicholas, and Ian Steedman. 2021. "A New Method for Measuring Total Factor Productivity Growth Based on the Full Industry Equilibrium Approach: The Case of the Greek Economy" Economies 9, no. 3: 114. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies9030114

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop