Next Article in Journal
Experimental Investigation of the Generalized Euler Characteristic of the Networks Split at Edges
Previous Article in Journal
Effects of Random Environmental Perturbation on the Dynamics of a Nutrient–Phytoplankton–Zooplankton Model with Nutrient Recycling
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Fuzzy Strong Nash Equilibria in Generalized Fuzzy Games with Application in Urban Public-Sports Services

1
Xi’an University of Finance and Economics, Xi’an 710100, China
2
Department of Mathematics, Eastern Michigan University, Ypsilanti, MI 48197, USA
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Mathematics 2022, 10(20), 3784; https://doi.org/10.3390/math10203784
Submission received: 21 August 2022 / Revised: 23 September 2022 / Accepted: 10 October 2022 / Published: 13 October 2022
(This article belongs to the Section Fuzzy Sets, Systems and Decision Making)

Abstract

:
In this paper, we apply the existence of solutions of the Ky Fan minimax inequality to establish the existence of fuzzy strong Nash equilibria in generalized fuzzy games and strong Nash equilibria in fuzzy coalition generalized games. We then show some applications of our existence results about the strong Nash equilibrium in urban public-sports services.

1. Introduction

The Ky Fan minimax inequality [1] is one of the most important results in mathematical sciences that is equivalent to many important mathematical theorems, such as the classical Brouwer’s fixed point theorem and Kakutani fixed point theorem. It is a useful tool in solving existence problems in many fields such as game theory, mathematical economy, and optimizations. So far, there have been many known variations and generalizations of Ky Fan’s original minimax inequality in [1]. For example, Briec and Yesilce [2] studied Ky Fan inequality in some idempotent and harmonic convex structure, Lin and Tian [3] provided generalizations of the Ky Fan minimax inequality by relaxing the compactness and convexity of sets and the quasi-concavity of the functional, and Qiu [4] proved the existence of pseu-Ky Fan’s points for vector Ky Fan inequalities using the FKKM principle.
The Nash equilibrium is one of the most important concepts in game theory that has been studied extensively in the literature. In 1954, Nash [5] established the famous existence theorem for equilibrium of an n-person non-cooperative game. Since then, there have been many variations and generalizations of Nash’s theorem that have appeared in the literature, including those for discontinuous games by Dasgupta and Maskin [6] and Reny [7], and those for generalized games by Debreu [8], Ding and Yuan [9], Harker [10], Scalzo [11], Wu [12], and Wu and Shen [13]. Baye et al. [14] and Hou [15] provided characterizations for the existence of Nash equilibria. For fuzzy games, Dutta and Gupta [16] investigated the Nash equilibrium strategy of two-person zero-sum games with fuzzy payoffs and established a relation between the Pareto Nash equilibrium strategy and the parametric bi-matrix game, Liu and Yu [17] derived an existence theorem for Nash equilibria in generalized fuzzy games with locally convex Hausdorff topological vector spaces for strategy spaces and/or discontinuous payoff functions, Maeda [18] provided a characterization of equilibrium strategy of two-person zero-sum games with fuzzy payoffs through Nash equilibrium strategies of a family of parametric bi-matrix games with crisp payoffs, Wang and Teo [19] developed an algorithm to solve the fuzzy Nash equilibrium problem, and Praveena and Devi [20] provided a survey on fuzzy-based game-theory approaches for supply-chain uncertainties in E-Commerce applications. The existence of Strong Nash equilibria has also been studied, see Holman and Law-Yone [21], Konishi et al. [22], and Nessah and Tian [23]. However, unlike standard Nash equilibria, strong Nash equilibria rarely exist, even if they are highly relevant for certain decision-making problems. Thus, providing the sufficient conditions for their existence is desirable in both classical and fuzzy game theory. It is our main purpose here to study the existence of strong Nash equilibria, in particular in the fuzzy setting, through the Ky Fan minimax inequality.
In this paper, we apply the existence of solutions of the Ky Fan minimax inequality to establish the existence of fuzzy strong Nash equilibria in generalized fuzzy games and strong Nash equilibria in fuzzy coalition generalized games in Section 3 and Section 4. We then show some applications of our existence results about strong Nash equilibrium in urban public-sports services in Section 5. The main contribution and novelty here is the connection between the solutions of the appropriate Ky Fan minimax inequalities and the fuzzy strong Nash equilibria we provided, which leads to sufficient conditions for the existence of strong Nash equilibria that generalize the existence theorem by Nessah and Tian [23].

2. Necessary and Sufficient Conditions for Solutions of the Ky Fan Minimax Inequality

Let X and C be topological spaces and φ ( x , z ) : X × C R be a function. The Ky Fan minimax inequality is the following problem:
Find   x * C such   that φ ( x , x * ) 0 x X .
The following concepts are given in [14], with φ ( x , z ) = U ( x , z ) U ( z , z ) .
Definition 1.
Let X be a non-empty subset of a topological vector space. The function φ ( x , z ) : X × X R is diagonally transfer-continuous in z if φ ( x , z ) > 0 implies that there is an open neighborhood O z of z and x X such that φ ( x , z ) > 0 for all z O z .
Definition 2.
Let X be a non-empty convex subset of a topological vector space and C be a non-empty convex subset of X. A function φ ( x , z ) : X × C R is diagonally transfer quasi-concave in x if, for any { x 1 , , x k } X , there is { z 1 , , z k } C , where x h z h , such that, for each z c o { z 1 , , z k } and z = j = 1 l λ j z h j with each λ j > 0 and j = 1 l λ j = 1 , one has φ ( x , z ) 0 for some x { x h 1 , , x h l } .
Let Δ n = { ( λ 0 , λ 1 , , λ n ) | λ i 0   for   0 i n   and   i = 0 n λ i = 1 } . The next concept from [15] (with φ ( x , z ) = f ( x , z ) f ( z , z ) ) is weaker than diagonal transfer quasi-concavity.
Definition 3.
Let X be a topological space, and A , Y X . A function φ : X × Y R is called C -quasi-concave on A if, for any finite subset { x 0 , x 1 , , x n } A , there is a continuous mapping ϕ n : Δ n Y such that
min { φ ( x i , ϕ n ( λ 0 , λ 1 , , λ n ) ) | i J } 0
for all ( λ 0 , λ 1 , , λ n ) Δ n , where J = { j { 0 , 1 , , n } | λ j 0 } .
Note that function φ ( x , z ) is diagonally transfer quasi-concave on X implies that φ is C -quasi-concave on X: For any { x 0 , x 1 , , x n } X , there is { z 0 , z 1 , , z n } C such that for each z c o { z 0 , z 1 , , z k } , z = j = 0 n λ j z j , there is x i { x 0 , , x n } satisfying φ ( x i , z ) 0 . Then, one can see that φ ( x , z ) is C -quasi-concave by taking ϕ n ( λ 0 , λ 1 , , λ n ) = j = 0 n λ j z j .
The following characterization for solutions of the Ky Fan minimax inequality follows easily from Lemma 1 in [24].
Theorem 1.
Assume that X is a subset of a Hausdorff topological vector space and C is a non-empty convex subset of X. Then, the Ky Fan minimax inequality (1) has a solution if and only if there is a non-empty convex compact subset D of C such that the restricted mapping φ | X × D : X × D R is diagonally transfer-continuous on D and diagonally transfer quasi-concave on X.
In the following characterization, a finite-dimensional subset means a subset of a finite-dimensional subspace. The proof adopts a similar approach for the proof of Theorem 1 in [15], and we omit the detailed proof.
Theorem 2.
Let X be a Hausdorff topological vector space and C be a non-empty convex subset of X. Then, the Ky Fan minimax inequality (1) has a solution if and only if there is a non-empty convex compact finite-dimensional subset D of C such that the restricted mapping φ | X × D : X × D R is diagonally transfer-continuous on D and C -quasi-concave on X.

3. Necessary and Sufficient Conditions for the Existence of Fuzzy Strong Nash Equilibria in Generalized Fuzzy Games

Throughout this section, we let N = { 1 , 2 , , n } be the set of n players and denote by N the set of all coalitions (subsets of N). For each i N , X i is the strategy space for player i and let X = i N X i be the set of strategy profiles. A game G on player set N is ( X i , u i ) i N with the strategy space X i and the payoff function u i : X R for each i N .
A generalized game Γ = ( X i , F i , u i ) i N is a game with player set N such that each player i has strategy space X i , each player i has a payoff function u i : X R that depends on his or her own variable x i as well as on the variables x i of all other players, and each player i’s strategy must belong to a set F i ( x ) = F i ( x i ) X i that depends on the rival players’ strategies x i . Clearly, a game is a special generalized game with F i ( x ) = X i for all x X and each i N . A Nash equilibrium of a generalized game is defined as follows (note that the following concept is stronger than the one given in [10,25] where x i F i ( x * ) there is replaced by x i F i ( X ) below).
Definition 4.
A vector x * = ( x i * ) i N X = i N X i is called a Nash equilibrium of a generalized game Γ if x * F ( x * ) = i N F i ( x * ) and
u i ( x i * , x i * ) u i ( x i , x i * ) for all x i F i ( X ) and for every i N .
The following concept of strong Nash equilibrium for generalized games extends the corresponding concept for games given in [23] (due to Aumann).
Definition 5.
A vector x * = ( x i * ) i N X = i N X i is called a strong Nash equilibrium of a generalized game Γ = ( X i , F i , u i ) i N if x * F ( x * ) = i N F i ( x * ) and for all S N and all x S F S ( X ) = i S F i ( X ) ,
u i ( x S , x S * ) u i ( x S * , x S * ) for at least one i S .
Clearly, a strong Nash equilibrium is a Nash equilibrium in a generalized game.
Let X be a topological space. A fuzzy set in X is a function with domain X and values in [ 0 , 1 ] . If A is a fuzzy set and x X , the function-value A ( x ) (or μ A ( x ) ) is called the grade of membership of x in A. The collection of all fuzzy sets in X is denoted by F ( X ) . Let A F ( X ) and α [ 0 , 1 ] . The α -level set of A, denoted by A α , is defined by
A α = { x X | A ( x ) α }   if   α ( 0 , 1 ] ,
A 0 = { x X | A ( x ) > 0 } .
A generalized fuzzy game Γ with player set N is a tuple Γ = ( X i , F i , P i , α i , β i ) i N , where for each i N , X i is the nonempty strategy space of i, F i and P i are fuzzy mappings from X = i N X i to the set F ( X i ) of fuzzy sets in X i . Any strategy profile x X is denoted by ( x i , x i ) , where x i X i and x i X i = j i X j . For each x X , F i ( · , x ) is the fuzzy set of strategies feasible to player i and P i ( · , x ) is the fuzzy set of strategies in X i that are preferred to x i when the other players choose x i . The functions α i , β i : X [ 0 , 1 ] provide the degree of feasibility α i ( x ) on strategies and the level of satisfaction β i ( x ) on preferences for player i at the strategy profile x X , respectively.
Definition 6.
A fuzzy Nash equilibrium for a generalized fuzzy game ( X i , F i , P i , α i , β i ) i N is a profile x * = ( x i * ) i N X such that for every i N ,
x i * F i ( · , x * ) α i ( x * ) and F i ( · , x * ) α i ( x * ) P i ( · , x * ) β i ( x * ) = .
The following concept of fuzzy strong Nash equilibrium for a generalized fuzzy game extends the strong Nash equilibrium given in Definition 5. For each S N , let X = i N X i and X S = i S X i and denote
( F S ( X ) ) α ( X ) = i S ( F i ( X ) ) α i ( X ) = i S x X ( F i ( x ) ) α i ( x ) .
Definition 7.
An element x * = ( x i * ) i N X is a fuzzy strong Nash equilibrium for a generalized fuzzy game ( X i , F i , P i , α i , β i ) i N if for every i N , x i * ( F i ( x * ) ) α i ( x * ) and for all S N , there is no x S ( F S ( X ) ) α ( X ) = i S ( F i ( X ) ) α i ( X ) satisfying
( x S , x S * ) P i ( x * ) β i ( x * ) for every i S .
Note that a fuzzy game is a special generalized fuzzy game with F i ( x ) = X i for all x X and each i N .
For a generalized fuzzy game Γ = ( X i , F i , u i , α i , β i ) i N with payoff functions u i satisfying | u i ( x ) | M i for every i N , we define the fuzzy preference mappings P i by
P i ( z ) = u i ( x i , z i ) u i ( z i , z i ) 2 M i if   u i ( x i , z i ) > u i ( z i , z i ) 0 otherwise .
Then an element x * = ( x i * ) i N X is a fuzzy strong Nash equilibrium for a generalized fuzzy game Γ = ( X i , F i , u i , α i , β i ) i N if for every i N , x i * ( F i ( x * ) ) α i ( x * ) and for all S N , there is no x S ( F S ( X ) ) α ( X ) satisfying
u i ( x S , x S * ) u i ( x S * , x S * ) 2 M i β i ( x * ) for every i S .
Remark 1.
Denote by ( X i , F i , P i , α i ) i N (or ( X i , F i , u i , α i ) i N ) a generalized fuzzy game with β i = 0 for every i N . Then, it is clear from Definition 7 that if x * X is a fuzzy strong Nash equilibrium for a generalized fuzzy game ( X i , F i , P i , α i ) i N (or ( X i , F i , u i , α i ) i N ), then x * is a fuzzy strong Nash equilibrium for generalized fuzzy game ( X i , F i , P i , α i , β i ) i N (or ( X i , F i , u i , α i , β i ) i N ) for any β i : X [ 0 , 1 ] .
Let Γ = ( X i , F i , P i , α i , β i ) i N be a generalized fuzzy game. Denote F = i N F i and let
C = { x X | x ( F ( x ) ) α ( x ) } .
Clearly, we have C X .
Define the function Φ : X × C R as follows:
Φ ( x , z ) = S N min i S P ˜ i ( ( x S , z S ) , z ) ,
where P ˜ i ( ( x S , z S ) , z ) = 1 if x S ( F S ( X ) ) α ( X ) and ( x S , z S ) ( P i ( z ) ) β i ( z ) , and P ˜ i ( ( x S , z S ) , z ) = 0 otherwise.
Proposition 1.
An x * C is a fuzzy strong Nash equilibrium of the generalized fuzzy game Γ = ( X i , F i , P i , α i , β i ) i N if and only if Φ ( x , x * ) 0 for all x X .
Proof. 
The necessity follows directly from the definition. For the sufficiency, let x * C be such that Φ ( x , x * ) 0 for all x X . Then, by (5) and (8), we have for all S N and all x S ( F S ( X ) ) α ( X ) ,
( x S , x S * ) ( P i ( x * ) ) β i ( x * )   for   at   least   one   i S ,
that is, x * is a fuzzy strong Nash equilibrium of Γ . □
Clearly, Theorems 1 and 2, together with Proposition 1, imply the following two characterizations for the existence of fuzzy strong Nash equilibria in generalized fuzzy games.
Theorem 3.
Assume that Γ = ( X i , F i , P i , α i , β i ) i N is a generalized fuzzy game such that for each i N , X i is a non-empty convex subset of a Hausdorff topological vector space, and let C be non-empty convex. Then, Γ has a fuzzy strong Nash equilibrium if and only if there is a non-empty convex compact subset D of C such that the restricted mapping Φ | X × D : X × D R is diagonally transfer-continuous on D and diagonally transfer quasi-concave on X.
Theorem 4.
Assume that Γ = ( X i , F i , P i , α i , β i ) i N is a generalized fuzzy game such that for each i N , X i is a non-empty convex subset of a Hausdorff topological vector space, and let C be non-empty convex. Then, Γ has a fuzzy strong Nash equilibrium if and only if there is a non-empty convex compact finite-dimensional subset D of C such that the restricted mapping Φ | X × D : X × D R is diagonally transfer-continuous on D and C -quasi-concave on X.
Next, we establish the existence of fuzzy strong Nash equilibria in generalized games by applying Theorem 3.
Proposition 2.
Let Γ = ( X i , F i , u i , α i , β i ) i N be a generalized fuzzy game with β i = 0 for every i N . If u i is continuous for each i N , then Φ is diagonally transfer-continuous.
Proof. 
Let Φ ( x , z ) > 0 . Then, by the definition, there exist S N and x S ( F S ( X ) ) α ( X ) such that ( x S , z S ) ( P i ( z ) ) 0 , i.e., u i ( x S , z S ) > u i ( z ) or u i ( x S , z S ) u i ( z ) > 0 for all i S . For each i S , since u i is continuous, u i ( x S , z S ) u i ( z ) is continuous and so there is an open neighborhood O z i of z such that u i ( x S , z S ) u i ( z ) > 0 , i.e., u i ( x S , z S ) > u i ( z ) for all z O z i . Take O z = i S O z i . Then, O z is an open neighborhood of z such that u i ( x S , z S ) > u i ( z ) , i.e., ( x S , z S ) P i ( z ) , for all z O z and every i S . Since x S ( F S ( X ) ) α ( X ) and ( x S , z S ) P i ( z ) for all i S , we have P ˜ S ( x , z ) = 1 for all z O z . It follows that Φ ( x , z ) > 0 for all z O z . Thus, Φ is diagonally transfer continuous. □
Proposition 3.
Let Γ = ( X i , F i , u i , α i , β i ) i N be a generalized fuzzy game with β i = 0 for every i N and C = X . If u i is quasi-concave for each i N , then Φ is diagonally transfer quasi-concave on X.
Proof. 
Assume that Γ = ( X i , F i , u i , α i , β i ) i N is a generalized fuzzy game with β i = 0 for every i N . Then, by (6), we have
( P i ( z ) ) 0 = { x X | u i ( x i , z i ) > u i ( z i , z i ) } .
Let ψ i S ( x , z ) = u i ( x S , z S ) for each S N . For each i N and every S N , since u i is quasi-concave, ψ i S ( x , z ) is quasi-concave in x. Let { x 1 , , x k } be any subset of X, take { z 1 , , z k } = { x 1 , , x k } C = X , and let z c o { x 1 , , x k } . Then, z = j = 1 l λ j x h j with each 1 h j k , λ j > 0 and j = 1 l λ j = 1 . It follows that for each i N and every S N ,
ψ i S ( z , z ) = ψ i S j = 1 l λ j x h j , z min 1 j l ψ i S ( x h j , z ) = ψ i S ( x i S , z ) ,
for some x i S { x h j 1 , , x h j n } . Let x { x h j 1 , , x h j n } be such that ψ i S ( x , z ) ψ i S ( x i S , z ) for all i N and all S N . Then, it follows that for all S N and every i N ,
ψ i S ( x , z ) ψ i S ( z , z )   or   u i ( x S , z S ) u i ( z ) .
This implies that Φ ( x , z ) 0 . □
Theorem 3 and Propositions 2 and 3 together give the following theorem for the existence of fuzzy strong Nash equilibria of generalized fuzzy games.
Theorem 5.
Assume that Γ = ( X i , F i , u i , α i , β i ) i N is a generalized fuzzy game such that for each i N , X i is a non-empty convex compact subset of a Hausdorff topological vector space, u i ( x ) is continuous in x and quasi-concave, and C = X . Then, there is a fuzzy strong Nash equilibrium for Γ.
Proof. 
Since X i is compact for each i N , it follows from the Tychonoff theorem that X = i N X i is compact. By Remark 1, we only need to consider the case β i = 0 for every i N , i.e., the special generalized fuzzy game ( X i , F i , u i , α i ) i N . It follows from Theorem 3 with C = D and Propositions 2 and 3 that there is a fuzzy strong Nash equilibrium for the special generalized fuzzy game ( X i , F i , u i , α i ) i N . Thus, Γ has a fuzzy strong Nash equilibrium by Remark 1. □
Recall that a game Γ = ( X i , u i ) i N is a special generalized game Γ = ( X i , F i , u i ) i N with F i ( x ) = X i for all x X and each i N . By taking F i to be a crisp mapping (i.e., F i ( · , x ) takes values 0 or 1) with F i ( x ) = X i for all x X and α i = β i = 0 for each i N , Theorem 5 provides the following existence theorem of strong Nash equilibrium, which generalizes Theorem 3.1 in [23].
Theorem 6.
Assume that Γ = ( X i , u i ) i N is a game such that for each i N , X i is a non-empty convex compact subset of a Hausdorff topological vector space and u i ( x ) is continuous in x and quasi-concave. Then, there is a strong Nash equilibrium for Γ.

4. Existence of Strong Nash Equilibria in Fuzzy Coalition Generalized Games

Recall from Aubin [26] that a f u z z y c o a l i t i o n is a vector s [ 0 , 1 ] n , namely, s = ( s 1 , s 2 , , s n ) with 0 s i 1 for each 1 i n (where s i is the participation level of agent i). A crisp coalition S N corresponds to a special fuzzy coalition s = ( s 1 , s 2 , , s n ) with s i = 1 if i S and s i = 0 if i S . Denote e N = ( 1 , 1 , , 1 ) . We will use F N for the set of all non-zero fuzzy coalitions on player set N, that is,
F N = { s = ( s 1 , s 2 , , s n ) 0 | 0 s i 1   for   each   i n } .
The following concept of fuzzy coalition generalized games is a natural extension of the corresponding concept of generalized games given in [27], with payoff functions u i instead of preferences P i .
A fuzzy coalition generalized game  Γ = ( ( X i , u i ) i N , ( F s ) s F N ) is a game with a player set N such that each player i has strategy space X i ; each player i has a payoff function u i : X = i N X i R that depends on his or her own variable x i as well as on the variables x i of all other players, and for each fuzzy coalition s F N , F s ( X ) X S = i S X i represents the set of feasible strategies corresponding to the fuzzy coalition s, where S = c a r ( s ) .
The following concept extends the strong Nash equilibrium given in Definition 5, where F i = F s with s i = 1 and s j = 0 for j i .
Definition 8.
A vector x * = ( x i * ) i N X = i N X i is called a strong Nash equilibrium of a fuzzy coalition generalized game Γ = ( ( X i , u i ) i N , ( F s ) s F N ) if x * F ( x * ) = i N F i ( x * ) and for all s F N and all x S F s ( X ) with S = c a r ( s ) ,
u i ( x S , x S * ) u i ( x S * , x S * ) for at least one i S .
Clearly, any strong Nash equilibrium of a fuzzy coalition generalized game is a Nash equilibrium.
Let Γ = ( ( X i , u i ) i N , ( F s ) s F N ) be a fuzzy coalition generalized game. Denote
C = { x X | x F ( x ) = i N F i ( x ) } .
For each S N , denote
F S * = s F N : c a r ( s ) = S F s ( X ) .
Clearly, F S * X S = i S X i .
Let
P i ( z ) = { x X | u i ( x ) > u i ( z ) } .
Define the function Ψ : X × C R as follows:
Ψ ( x , z ) = S N min i S P ˜ i ( ( x S , z S ) , z ) ,
where P ˜ i ( ( x S , z S ) , z ) = 1 if x S F S * and ( x S , z S ) P i ( z ) , and P ˜ i ( ( x S , z S ) , z ) = 0 otherwise.
Proposition 4.
An x * C is a strong Nash equilibrium of the fuzzy coalition generalized game Γ = ( ( X i , u i ) i N , ( F s ) s F N ) if and only if Ψ ( x , x * ) 0 for all x X .
Proof. 
The necessity follows directly from the definition. For the sufficiency, let x * C be such that Ψ ( x , x * ) 0 for all x X . By (10), we have for all S N and all x S F S * X S ,
( x S , x S * ) P i ( x * )   for   at   least   one   i S ,
that is, x * is a strong Nash equilibrium of Γ by (9). □
The following two characterizations follow from Theorems 1 and 2 and Proposition 4.
Theorem 7.
Assume that Γ = ( ( X i , u i ) i N , ( F s ) s F N ) is a fuzzy coalition generalized game such that for each i N , X i is a non-empty convex subset of a Hausdorff topological vector space, and let C be non-empty convex. Then, Γ has a strong Nash equilibrium if and only if there is a non-empty convex compact subset D of C such that the restricted mapping Ψ | X × D : X × D R is diagonally transfer-continuous on D and diagonally transfer quasi-concave on X.
Theorem 8.
Assume that Γ = ( ( X i , u i ) i N , ( F s ) s F N ) is a fuzzy coalition generalized game such that for each i I , X i is a non-empty convex subset of a Hausdorff topological vector space, and let C be non-empty convex. Then, Γ has a strong Nash equilibrium if and only if there is a non-empty convex compact finite-dimensional subset D of C such that the restricted mapping Ψ | X × D : X × D R is diagonally transfer-continuous on D and C -quasi-concave on X.
Similar to Propositions 2 and 3, we have the next two facts.
Proposition 5.
Let Γ = ( ( X i , u i ) i N , ( F s ) s F N ) be a fuzzy coalition generalized game. If u i is continuous for each i N , then Ψ is diagonally transfer-continuous.
Proposition 6.
Let Γ = ( ( X i , u i ) i N , ( F s ) s F N ) be a fuzzy coalition generalized game and C = X . If u i is quasi-concave for each i N , then Ψ is diagonally transfer quasi-concave on X.
By Theorem 7 and Propositions 5 and 6, one has the following existence theorem for the strong Nash equilibrium of a fuzzy coalition generalized game.
Theorem 9.
Assume that Γ = ( ( X i , u i ) i N , ( F s ) s F N ) is a fuzzy coalition generalized game such that for each i N , X i is a non-empty convex compact subset of a Hausdorff topological vector space, u i ( x ) is continuous in x and quasi-concave, and C = X . Then, Γ has a strong Nash equilibrium.

5. Applications

By viewing a sport public service or sport facility as a resource, we present the following example through congestion games to show applications in sport public services. Congestion games have been used to model situations such as rush-hour traffic and the demand for factors of production, see [21] for more on congestion games. Additionally, please see [28] for optimal resource allocations in cloud manufacturing platforms.
Example 1.
A congestion game is described as follows: N = { 1 , 2 , . . . , n } is the set of players, and M = { 1 , 2 , . . . , m } is the set of facilities. Each player j has a non-empty set of strategies X i . Every strategy A i X i is a subset of M. With every facility a and every integer 1 k n , a real number u a ( k ) is associated, which can be interpreted as the utility to each user of a if the total number of users of a is k. Let X = i = 1 n X i and let A = ( A 1 , , A n ) X . The m-dimensional congestion vector corresponding to A is σ ( A ) = ( σ a ( A ) ) a M , where
σ a ( A ) = | { i N | a A i } | .
The payoff function of player i is defined by
π i ( A ) = a A i u a ( σ a ( A ) ) .
When each player tries to make strategy choices to maximize payoffs, a strong Nash equilibrium is a very good solution. One can replace A i by a mixed action x i = ( x i , 1 , x i , 2 , , x i , m ) , with 0 x i , j 1 being the participation level of player i in facility j for 1 j m . The set of all mixed actions is denoted by Δ ( X ) . Clearly, Δ ( X ) is convex and compact. Define
σ j ( x ) = i = 1 n x i , j   f o r   j M .
For each x Δ ( X ) , define the payoff function of player i by
π i ( x ) = j = 1 m u j ( σ j ( x ) ) .
By Theorem 6, when payoff functions π i ( x ) is continuous and quasi-concave, there is a strong Nash equilibrium for the game.

6. Concluding Remarks

In this paper, we apply the existence of solutions of the Ky Fan minimax inequality to establish the existence of fuzzy strong Nash equilibria in generalized fuzzy games and strong Nash equilibria in fuzzy coalition generalized games in Section 3 and Section 4, and we provide an application of our existence results about strong Nash equilibrium in urban public-sports services in Section 5.
As strong Nash equilibria rarely exist, providing sufficient conditions for their existence is a relevant contribution to game theory. As a consequence of our main result (Theorem 5), Theorem 6 improves the existence theorem by Nessah and Tian [23] through a different approach—the Ky Fan minimax inequality.
It would be desirable to obtain more sufficient conditions for the existence of strong Nash equilibria and fuzzy strong Nash equilibria and explore more applications involving strong Nash equilibria in future studies.

Author Contributions

Formal analysis, T.H. and J.L. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

The research is supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (Grant No. 71973103) and Social Science Foundation of Shaanxi Province (Grant No. 2020Q008).

Data Availability Statement

No data is involved.

Acknowledgments

The authors would like to thank the anonymous referees for helpful suggestions and comments, which resulted in significant improvements to the paper. The research is supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (Grant No. 71973103) and Social Science Foundation of Shaanxi Province (Grant No. 2020Q008).

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Fan, K. A minimax inequality and application. In Inequalities; Academic Press: New York, NY, USA, 1972; Volume 3, pp. 103–113. [Google Scholar]
  2. Briec, W.; Yesilce, I. Ky-Fan inequality, Nash equilibria in some idempotent and harmonic convex structure. J. Math. Anal. Appl. 2022, 508, 125862. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Lin, Y.J.; Tian, G. Minimax Inequalities Equivalent to the Fan-Knaster-Kuratowski-Mazurkiewicz Theorems. Appl. Math. Optim. 1993, 28, 173–179. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  4. Qiu, X. The Existence of the pseu-Ky Fan’Points and the Applications in Multiobjective Games. In East Asia Game Theory International Conference; Springer: Singapore, 2019; pp. 105–115. [Google Scholar]
  5. Nash, J.F. Equilibrium points in N-person games. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 1950, 36, 48–49. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  6. Dasgupta, P.; Maskin, E. The existence of equilibrium in discontinuous economic games. Part I: Theory. Rev. Econ. Stud. 1986, 53, 1–26. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Reny, P.J. On the existence of pure and mixed strategy Nash equilibria in discontinuous games. Econometrica 1999, 67, 1029–1056. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Debreu, G. A social equilibrium existence theorem. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 1952, 38, 886–893. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  9. Ding, X.P.; Yuan, G.X. The Study of Existence of Equilibria for Generalized Games without Lower Semicontinuity in Locally Topological Vector Spaces. J. Math. Anal. Appl. 1998, 227, 420–438. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  10. Harker, P.T. Generalized Nash games and quasi-variational inequalities. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 1991, 54, 81–94. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Scalzo, V. Equilibrium existence in games: Slight single deviation property and Ky Fan minimax inequality. J. Math. Econ. 2019, 82, 197–201. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Wu, X. A New Fixed Point Theorem and its Applications. Proc. Am. Math. Soc. 1997, 125, 1779–1783. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Wu, X.; Shen, S. A Further Generalization of Yannelis-Prabhakar’s Continuous Selection Theorem and Its Applications. J. Math. Anal. Appl. 1996, 197, 61–74. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  14. Baye, M.R.; Tian, G.; Zhou, J. Characterizations of the Existence of Equilibria in Games with Discontinuous and Non-quasiconcave Payoffs. Rev. Econ. Stud. 1993, 60, 935–948. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Hou, J.C. Characterization of the existence of a pure-strategy Nash equilibrium. Appl. Math. Lett. 2009, 22, 689–692. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  16. Dutta, B.; Gupta, S.K. On Nash equilibrium strategy of two-person zerosum games with trapezoidal fuzzy payoffs. Fuzzy Inf. Eng. 2014, 6, 299–314. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  17. Liu, J.; Yu, G. Fuzzy Kakutani-Fan-Glicksberg Fixed Point Theorem and Existence of Nash Equilibria for Fuzzy Games. Fuzzy Sets Syst. 2022, 447, 100–112. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Maeda, T. On characterization of equilibrium strategy of two-person zero-sum games with fuzzy payoffs. Fuzzy Sets Syst. 2003, 139, 283–296. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Wang, X.; Teo, K.L. Generalized Nash equilibrium problem over a fuzzy strategy set. Fuzzy Sets Syst. 2022, 434, 172–184. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Praveena, S.; Devi, S.P. A survey on fuzzy based game theory approaches for supply chain uncertainties in E-Commerce applications. Mater. Today Proc. 2022, 62, 4862–4868. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Holman, R.; Law-Yone, N. Strong Equilibrium in Congestion Games. Games Econ. Behav. 1997, 21, 85–101. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  22. Konishi, H.; Bretou, M.L.; Weber, S. Equivalence of strong and coalition-proof Nash equilibria in games without spillovers. Econ. Theory 1997, 9, 97–113. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Nessah, R.; Tian, G. On the existence of strong Nash equilibria. J. Math. Anal. Appl. 2014, 414, 871–885. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Tian, G. Necessary and Sufficient Conditions for Maximization of a Class of Preference Relations. Rev. Econ. Stud. 1993, 60, 949–958. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Cubiotti, P.; Yao, J. Nash equilibria of generalized games in normed spaces without upper semicontinuity. J. Glob. Optim. 2010, 46, 509–519. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Aubin, J.P. Mathematics Methods of Games and Economic Theory; Dover Publication: Amsterdam, The Netherlands; New York, NY, USA; Oxford, UK, 1979. [Google Scholar]
  27. Kajii, A. A generalization of Scarf’s theorem: An α-core existence theorem without transitivity or completeness. J. Econ. Theory 1992, 56, 194–205. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Delaram, J.; Houshamand, M.; Ashtiani, F.; Valilai, O.F. A utility-based matching mechanism for stable and optimal resource allocation in cloud manufacturing platforms using deferred acceptance algorithm. J. Manuf. Syst. 2021, 60, 569–584. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Huang, T.; Liu, J. Fuzzy Strong Nash Equilibria in Generalized Fuzzy Games with Application in Urban Public-Sports Services. Mathematics 2022, 10, 3784. https://doi.org/10.3390/math10203784

AMA Style

Huang T, Liu J. Fuzzy Strong Nash Equilibria in Generalized Fuzzy Games with Application in Urban Public-Sports Services. Mathematics. 2022; 10(20):3784. https://doi.org/10.3390/math10203784

Chicago/Turabian Style

Huang, Tieying, and Jiuqiang Liu. 2022. "Fuzzy Strong Nash Equilibria in Generalized Fuzzy Games with Application in Urban Public-Sports Services" Mathematics 10, no. 20: 3784. https://doi.org/10.3390/math10203784

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop