The Optimal Stopping Problem under a Random Horizon
Abstract
:1. Introduction
- Can we associate with (1) an optimal stopping problem under with reward and value process ?
- How are the two pairs, and , connected to each other?
- What are the structures in induced by ?
- How are the maximal (minimal) optimal times of (1) and their -optimal stopping problem counterparts related to each other?
2. Notations and the Random Horizon Setting
2.1. General Notations
2.2. The Random Horizon and the Progressive Enlargement of
- (a)
- For any , the process
- (b)
- The process
- (a)
- is a -martingale, and for any , is given by
- (b)
- For any , we have . In particular, is a Brownian motion for for any .
- (2)
- In general, the -martingale might not be uniformly integrable, and hence in general, might not be well defined for . For these facts, we refer the reader to [20] (Proposition 4.3), where the conditions for being uniformly integrable are fully singled out when .
3. The Optimal Stopping Problem under a Random Horizon
3.1. Parametrization of -Reward Using -Processes
- (a)
- is locally bounded if and only if and are locally bounded.
- (b)
- is RCLL if and only if is RCLL.
- (c)
- is an RCLL -semimartingale if and only if is an RCLL -semimartingale. Furthermore,
- (d)
- For any , if and only if
- (e)
- If is of class-, then , and is of class-.
- (a)
- By virtue of (19), it is clear that the local boundedness of the pair implies the local boundedness of . To prove the reverse, we assume that is locally bounded and is the localizing sequence of stopping times. Hence, there exists a sequence of positive constants such that
- (b)
- Thanks to (16) and the fact that is an RCLL process, we deduce that is RCLL if and only if is RCLL. Thus, we assume that is an RCLL process, and we consider the sequence of -stopping times , given by
- (c)
- It is clear that is an RCLL -semimartingale, and hence is an RCLL -semimartingale if and only if is an RCLL -semimartingale. Thus, if is an RCLL -semimartingale, then is an RCLL -semimartingale. To prove the converse, we note that by stopping with defined above and by using [16] (Théorème 26, Chapter VII, pp. 235), there is no loss of generality in assuming is bounded, which leads to the boundedness of (see [22] (Lemma B.1) or [23] (Lemma 4.4 (b), pp. 63)). Thus, thanks to [16] (Théorème 47, pp. 119, and Théorème 59, pp. 268), which implies that the optional projection of a bounded RCLL -semimartingale is an RCLL -semimartingale, we deduce that is an RCLL -semimartingale. A combination of this with the condition and the fact that G is an RCLL -semimartingale implies that is an RCLL -semimartingale. Furthermore, direct calculation yields
- (d)
- Here, we prove assertion (d). To this end, we use (16) and derive
- (e)
- Assume that is of class-. On the one hand, we have , or equivalently, . On the other hand, due to , for any , we have
3.2. The Mathematical Structures of the Value Process (Snell Envelope)
- (a)
- If either is nonnegative or , then the -Snell envelope of , denoted by , is given by
- (b)
- Let T , and is given in (14). If either or , then the -Snell envelope of , denoted by , satisfies
- (b)
- For and with (see Lemma 3), we have
- (a)
- For any RCLL -semimartingale L, it holds that
- Part 1. In this part, we assume that is bounded and prove assertion (a). Hence, under this assumption, the associated processes , and are also bounded. As a result, both and are uniformly integrable -martingales. Thus, by defining
- Part 2. Here, we assume that is bounded, and we fix and prove assertion (b). Let and such that . Then, similarly to Part 1, by taking -conditional expectations on both sides of (27) and using (31) and the fact that the two processes and remain uniformly integrable -martingales under (due the boundedness of and ), we write
3.3. -Optimal Stopping Times Versus -Optimal Stopping Times
- (a)
- The optimal stopping problem for has a solution if and only if the optimal stopping problem for has a solution. Furthermore, if one of these solutions exists, then the minimal optimal stopping times, and , for and , respectively, exist, and .
- (b)
- The maximal optimal stopping time, , for exists if and only if the maximal optimal stopping time, , for also exists, and they satisfy .
- Part 1. This part proves the following fact:
- Part 2. Here, we prove assertion (a). Thanks to part 1, it is clear that if and only if . Thus, on the one hand, this proves the first statement in assertion (a). On the other hand, by again combining this statement with Lemma 5 and part 1, the second statement of assertion (a) follows immediately.
- Part 3. If the maximal optimal stopping time, , for exists, then , and for any , we have P-a.s. Hence, for any , there exists , satisfying
4. Conclusions
Author Contributions
Funding
Institutional Review Board Statement
Informed Consent Statement
Data Availability Statement
Conflicts of Interest
Appendix A. Proofs of Lemmas 3 and 4
- (2)
- This part proves assertion (b). To this end, by virtue of Lemma 1, we note that , where is defined in (13) and satisfies
References
- Neveu, J. Discrete Parameter Martingales; Elsevier: Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 1975. [Google Scholar]
- Arai, T.; Takenaka, M. Constrained optimal stopping under regime switching model. arXiv 2022, arXiv:2204.07914v1. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- El Karoui, N. Les aspects probabilistes du control stochastiques. In Ninth Saint Flour Probability Summer School-1979 (Saint Flour, 1979), 73-238, Lecture Notes in Math. 876; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 1979. [Google Scholar]
- Kobylanski, M.; Quenez, M.C. Optimal stopping time problem in a general framework. Electron. J. Probab. 2012, 17, 1–28. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Peksir, G.; Shiryaev, A. Optimal stopping and free boundary problems. In Lectures in Mathematics ETH Zürich; Birkhauser: Basel, Switzerland, 2006. [Google Scholar]
- Shiryaev, A. Optimal Stopping Rules; Aries, A.B., Translator; Springer: New York, NY, USA, 1978. [Google Scholar]
- Alsheyab, S.; Choulli, T. Reflected backward stochastic differential equations under stopping with an arbitrary random time. arXiv 2021, arXiv:2107.11896. [Google Scholar]
- Di Nunno, G.; Khedher, A.; Vanmaele, M. Robustness of quadratic hedging strategies in finance via backward stochastic differential equations with jumps. Appl. Math. Optim. 2015, 72, 353–389. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- El Karoui, N.; Peng, S.G.; Quenez, M.C. Backward stochastic differential equations in finance. Math. Financ. 1997, 7, 1–71. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hamadène, S.; Lepeltier, J.P.; Zhen, W. Infinite Horizon Reflected BSDE and its applications in Mixed Control and Game Problems. Probab. Math. Stat. 1999, 19, 211–234. [Google Scholar]
- Hamadène, S.; Lepeltier, J.P. Backward equations, stochastic control and zero-sum stochastic differential games. Stoch. Stoch. Rep. 1995, 54, 221–231. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Khedher, A.; Vanmaele, M. Discretisation of FBSDEs driven by càdlàg martingales. J. Math. Anal. Appl. 2016, 435, 508–531. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Quenez, M.-C.; Sulem, A. Refelcted BSDEs and robust optimal stopping for dynamic risk measures with jumps. Stoch. Processes Their Appl. 2014, 124, 3031–3054. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- El Karoui, N.; Kapoudjian, C.; Pardoux, E.; Peng, S.; Quenez, M.C. Reflected Solutions of Backward SDE and Related Obstacle Problems for PDEs. Ann. Probab. 1997, 25, 702–737. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- ∅ksendal, B.; Zhang, T. Backward stochastic differential equations with respect to general filtrations and applications to insider finance. Commun. Stoch. Anal. 2012, 6, 703–722. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dellacherie, C.; Meyer, P.-A. Probabilités et Potentiel, Théorie des martingales. Chapter V to VIII; Hermann: Paris, France, 1980. [Google Scholar]
- He, S.W.; Wang, J.G.; Yan, J.A. Semimartingale Theory and Stochastic Calculus; Science Press: Beijing, China; CRC Press: New York, NY, USA, 1992. [Google Scholar]
- Jacod, J.; Shiryaev, A. Limit Theorems for Stochastic Processes, 2nd ed.; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 2003. [Google Scholar]
- Dellacherie, C.; Meyer, P.-A. Probabilities and Potential B: Theory of Martingales; North-Holland: New York, NY, USA, 1982. [Google Scholar]
- Choulli, T.; Yansori, S. Explicit description of all deflators for markets under random horizon with application to NFLVR. Stoch. Processes Their Appl. 2022, 151, 230–264. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Choulli, T.; Daveloose, C.; Vanmaele, M. A martingale representation theorem and valuation of defaultable securities. Math. Financ. 2020, 30, 1–38. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Aksamit, A.; Choulli, T.; Deng, J.; Jeanblanc, M. No-arbitrage up to random horizon for quasi-left-continuous models. Finance Stoch. 2017, 21, 1103–1139. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Jeulin, T. Semi-Martingales et Grossissement d’Une Filtration; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 1980. [Google Scholar]
- Dellacherie, C.; Maisonneuve, B.; Meyer, P.-A. Probabilités et Potentiel: Tome V, Processus de Markov (fin), Compléments de Calcul Stochastique, Chapitres XVII-XXIV; Hermann: Paris, France, 1992. [Google Scholar]
- Chakrabarty, A.; Guo, X. Optimal stopping times with different information levels with time uncertainty. Stoch. Anal. Appl. Financ. 2012, 13, 19–38. [Google Scholar]
- Agram, N.; Haadem, S.; ∅ksendal, B.; Proske, F. Optimal stopping, randomized stopping and singular control with general information flow. Theory Probab. Appli. 2022, 66, 601–612. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- ∅ksendal, B. Optimal stopping with delayed information. Stoch. Dyn. 2005, 5, 271–280. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content. |
© 2024 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Choulli, T.; Alsheyab, S. The Optimal Stopping Problem under a Random Horizon. Mathematics 2024, 12, 1273. https://doi.org/10.3390/math12091273
Choulli T, Alsheyab S. The Optimal Stopping Problem under a Random Horizon. Mathematics. 2024; 12(9):1273. https://doi.org/10.3390/math12091273
Chicago/Turabian StyleChoulli, Tahir, and Safa’ Alsheyab. 2024. "The Optimal Stopping Problem under a Random Horizon" Mathematics 12, no. 9: 1273. https://doi.org/10.3390/math12091273
APA StyleChoulli, T., & Alsheyab, S. (2024). The Optimal Stopping Problem under a Random Horizon. Mathematics, 12(9), 1273. https://doi.org/10.3390/math12091273