A Group Consensus Measure That Takes into Account the Relative Importance of the Decision-Makers
Abstract
:1. Introduction
- Heterogeneous GDM situations cover the homogeneous ones as a special case, i.e., with each decision-maker’s weight being equal to the others;
- Heterogeneous GDM tasks frequently occur because, in real-life situations, the differences in knowledge, expertise, experience, position, etc., among the decision-makers are often taken into account (e.g., in a corporate environment, the weight of a decision-maker’s opinion is determined by the number or portion of shares he or she holds).
- In case A, the opinion of each expert has the same importance, i.e., all the input weights are equal (, ).
- In case B, the first expert has a much higher weight value () than the other decision-makers. The relatively high value of may indicate that the first decision-maker has a higher number of shares, professional expertise, etc., than the other decision-makers.
2. Preliminaries
2.1. Fuzziness Measures
- P1
- For any , holds if and only if μ is sharp almost everywhere in X. That is, either or holds for almost every .
- P2
- has a unique maximum value if and only if holds almost for every .
- P3
- For any , holds whenever if , and if .
- P4
- , where is the ‘complement’ of μ, i.e., the function is given as , where .
- (a)
- F is continuous function on .
- (b)
- and .
- (c)
- F is a strictly increasing function on and F is a strictly decreasing function on .
- (d)
- has a unique maximum at , and .
- (e)
- holds for any .
2.2. Strong Negations
2.3. Consensus Measures
- (C1)
- (Unanimity) For any , .
- (C2)
- (Minimum consensus for ) For the special case of two inputs, it holds that .
- (C3)
- (Symmetry) For any permutation and input vector , it holds that .
- (C4)
- (Maximum dissension) For , if k of the inputs are equal to zero and k of the inputs are equal to 1, then for all permutations of the input vector.
- (C5)
- (Reciprocity) For any input vector , it holds that , where is the standard fuzzy negation and .
- (C6)
- (Replication invariance) For any input vector , replicating the inputs does not alter the degree of consensus, i.e., .
- (C7)
- (Monotonicity with respect to the majority) For , let half of the inputs be equal and be denoted by , where . Furthermore, let and be two input vectors, where . If for all ; then, holds for any permutation of the inputs.
3. Weighted Consensus Measures
- (cw1)
- (Unanimity) For any , .
- (cw2)
- (Symmetry) For any permutation and input vector , it holds that , where .
- (cw3)
- (Maximum dissension) If
- (a)
- for , and
- (b)
- for all , and
- (c)
- for all , ,
then . - (cw4)
- (Reciprocity) For any input vector , it holds that , where is the standard fuzzy negation and .
- (cw5)
- (Replication invariance) For any input vector , replicating the inputs along with re-normalizing the weights to 1 does not alter the degree of weighted consensus; i.e., for any , ,whereand
- (cw6)
- (Monotonicity with respect to the majority) Let , and let and be two input vectors, where . If
- (a)
- for , and
- (b)
- for all , and
- (c)
- for all , ,
then .
- (cw1)
- (Unanimity) The original requirement (C1) states that if all the decision-makers have the same opinion, then the level of consensus should be maximal. This requirement does not need to be modified as the same opinion shared by all the group members results in a maximal consensus, independent of the actual weight values.
- (cw2)
- (Symmetry) This requirement is related to the order of inputs. The original criterion of symmetry (i.e., (C3)) states that if the inputs are permuted, the level of consensus should not change. We can adapt it to the weighted case by demanding the same permutation of the weights and inputs.
- (cw3)
- (Maximum dissension) The original criterion concerns the maximal possible dispersion of the inputs and the lowest possible level of consensus in this case. The introductory example in Table 1 suggests that, in the weighted case, it is not the number of decision-makers but their total weight that counts. Consequently, the original (C4) criterion (a special case of which is (C2)) should be modified such that not half of the decision-makers but some of them representing half of the total weights shall produce zeros as inputs, and all the others shall produce ones as inputs to obtain the lowest possible level of consensus.
- (cw4)
- (Reciprocity) The (C5) criterion is about reversing each decision-maker’s opinion (the level of consensus is independent of which end of the evaluation scale the inputs come from [9]). As this criterion is independent of the number of decision-makers, it need not be modified.
- (cw5)
- (Replication invariance) The original criterion (C6) in [43] states that replicating the inputs should not alter the degree of consensus. In other words, if the proportion of each evaluation remains the same, the level of consensus should not change. In the weighted case, the constant proportion of each input can be guaranteed by re-normalizing the weights.
- (cw6)
- (Monotonicity with respect to the majority) The original requirement (C7) states that if the majority of the decision-makers have the same input value and the minority is approaching, in absolute terms in its inputs, to the constant input of the majority, then the level of consensus should not decrease. We can adapt this criterion to the weighted case using the fact that in the weighted case, it is not the number of decision-makers, but their total weight that really counts. Consequently, the modified criterion states that if each input of the weight minority is approaching the constant input of weight majority, the level of consensus should not decrease.At this point, we refer to the introductory example given in Table 1. In case A, the third and fourth decision-makers form a weight-majority as . At the same time, their inputs are identical . Hence, in this case, if expert 1 or 2 modifies their evaluation such that it becomes closer to than it is now, then the level of consensus should not decrease. Similarly, in case B, decision-maker 1 constitutes the weight majority, and so if any other decision-maker is closer to with their evaluation, then the level of consensus should not decrease.
4. Weighted Consensus Measures Based on Fuzziness Measure
4.1. The Decumulative Distribution Function of an Input Vector with Respect to the Input Weights
- (a)
- and are non-increasing functions on .
- (b)
- is right-continuous on , and is left-continuous on .
- (c)
- If , then , and if , then , where π is a permutation on satisfying Equation (8).
- (d)
- For any strong negation , if the negated input vector is given by , then, for any , it holds that
- (e)
- For any ,where and π is a permutation on satisfying Equation (8).
- (f)
- The areas under the curves of and on the interval are both equal to the weighted arithmetic mean of the inputs. That is,
4.2. The Fuzziness Degree of the Decumulative Distribution Function Viewed as a Degree of Dissension
- When the consensus among the decision-makers is maximal, and hence, the value of the weighted group consensus measure is expected to be 1, the fuzziness measure value of the corresponding DDF with respect to the weights is 0.
- When the dissension (which takes into account the input weights) among the group members is maximal, and hence, the value of the group consensus measure should be 0, the fuzziness measure value of the corresponding DDF with respect to the weights is 1.
- (i)
- If , then for any , .
- (ii)
- If , then for any , .
- (iii)
- If , then
- (a)
- for , and
- (b)
- for all , and
- (c)
- for all , ,
- (a)
- for , and
- (b)
- for all , and
- (c)
- for all , .
4.3. Weighted Consensus Measures Induced by Fuzzy Entropies Derived from Quasi-Arithmetic Means
5. Numerical Examples
- From the comparison of case 1 and 2, as well as that of case 3 and 4, we see that and both have the Reciprocity () property.
- Cases 3 and 4 highlight the Maximum dissension () property of these measures. Namely, if the most extreme evaluations (0 and 1) are distributed such that not necessarily half of the decision-makers use zeros as inputs and the other half of them use ones as inputs, but all the inputs corresponding to the half of the weight totals are zeros and all the inputs corresponding to the other half of the weight totals are ones, then the degree of consensus is minimal; i.e., it is equal to zero.
- Noting case 5, we see that if all the decision-makers have the same opinion, i.e., there is unanimous agreement in the group, the consensus is maximal, independent of the weight values assigned to the decision-makers. This means that and both satisfy the Unanimity () requirement.
- Comparing case 6 with case 1, we note the Monotonicity with respect to the majority () property of and . Here, decision-maker 1 is in the weight majority () with the input . In case 6, the evaluation of decision-maker 2 is closer to than in case 1 (), while all the other inputs remain unchanged. That is, the opinion of the weight minority becomes more ‘similar’ to that of the weight majority, and it is reflected in the higher values of the and measures ( increases from to and increases from to ).Similarly, based on cases 6 and 7, we find that as the inputs of decision-makers 3 and 4 approach the input of the weight majority ( and ), while all the other inputs remain unchanged, the values of both weighted consensus measures increase ( increases from to and increases from to ).Cases 8 and 9 provide us with another demonstration of the Monotonicity with respect to the majority property of and . Here, decision-makers 2, 3, and 4 form a weight majority () with a constant input value . We see that the input of decision-maker 1 is closer to in case 9 than in case 8 (, and this is reflected in the increase in the and values (both increase from to ).
6. Conclusions and Plans for Future Research
Author Contributions
Funding
Data Availability Statement
Conflicts of Interest
References
- Herrera-Viedma, E.; Cabrerizo, F.J.; Kacprzyk, J.; Pedrycz, W. A review of soft consensus models in a fuzzy environment. Inf. Fusion 2014, 17, 4–13. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dombi, J.; Jónás, T. Consensus measures based on a fuzzy concept. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2024, 315, 642–653. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- González-Arteaga, T.; de Andrés Calle, R.; Chiclana, F. A new measure of consensus with reciprocal preference relations: The correlation consensus degree. Knowl. Based Syst. 2016, 107, 104–116. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- González-Arteaga, T.; Alcantud, J.C.R.; de Andrés Calle, R. A cardinal dissensus measure based on the Mahalanobis distance. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2016, 251, 575–585. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Tastle, W.J.; Wierman, M.J.; Dumdum, U.R. Ranking ordinal scales using the consensus measure. Issues Inf. Syst. 2005, 6, 96–102. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Alcalde-Unzu, J.; Vorsatz, M. Measuring consensus: Concepts, comparisons, and properties. Consensual Process. 2011, 267, 195–211. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Alcalde-Unzu, J.; Vorsatz, M. Measuring the cohesiveness of preferences: An axiomatic analysis. Soc. Choice Welf. 2013, 41, 965–988. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Erdamar, B.; García-Lapresta, J.L.; Pérez-Román, D.; Sanver, M.R. Measuring consensus in a preference-approval context. Inf. Fusion 2014, 17, 14–21. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Beliakov, G.; Calvo, T.; James, S. Consensus measures constructed from aggregation functions and fuzzy implications. Knowl. Based Syst. 2014, 55, 1–8. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Alcantud, J.C.R.; de Andrés Calle, R.; Cascón, J.M. On measures of cohesiveness under dichotomous opinions: Some characterizations of approval consensus measures. Inf. Sci. 2013, 240, 45–55. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Alcantud, J.C.R.; de Andrés Calle, R.; Cascón, J. Pairwise dichotomous cohesiveness measures. Group Decis. Negot. 2015, 24, 833–854. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Alcantud, J.C.R.; Torrecillas, M.J.M. Consensus measures for various informational bases. Three new proposals and two case studies from political science. Qual. Quant. 2017, 51, 285–306. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dombi, J.; Fáró, J.; Jónás, T. A Fuzzy Entropy-Based Group Consensus Measure for Financial Investments. Mathematics 2023, 12, 4. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Herrera-Viedma, E.; Herrera, F.; Chiclana, F. A consensus model for multiperson decision making with different preference structures. IEEE Trans. Syst. Man Cybern.-Part A Syst. Humans 2002, 32, 394–402. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Herrera-Viedma, E.; Martínez, L.; Mata, F.; Chiclana, F. A consensus support system model for group decision-making problems with multigranular linguistic preference relations. IEEE Trans. Fuzzy Syst. 2005, 13, 644–658. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Herrera-Viedma, E.; Alonso, S.; Chiclana, F.; Herrera, F. A consensus model for group decision making with incomplete fuzzy preference relations. IEEE Trans. Fuzzy Syst. 2007, 15, 863–877. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cabrerizo, F.J.; Alonso, S.; Herrera-Viedma, E. A consensus model for group decision making problems with unbalanced fuzzy linguistic information. Int. J. Inf. Technol. Decis. Mak. 2009, 8, 109–131. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Chiclana, F.; García, J.T.; del Moral, M.J.; Herrera-Viedma, E. A statistical comparative study of different similarity measures of consensus in group decision making. Inf. Sci. 2013, 221, 110–123. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- del Moral, M.J.; Chiclana, F.; Tapia, J.M.; Herrera-Viedma, E. A comparative study on consensus measures in group decision making. Int. J. Intell. Syst. 2018, 33, 1624–1638. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhang, H.; Dong, Y.; Chiclana, F.; Yu, S. Consensus efficiency in group decision making: A comprehensive comparative study and its optimal design. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2019, 275, 580–598. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dong, Y.; Zha, Q.; Zhang, H.; Kou, G.; Fujita, H.; Chiclana, F.; Herrera-Viedma, E. Consensus reaching in social network group decision making: Research paradigms and challenges. Knowl.-Based Syst. 2018, 162, 3–13. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wang, S.; Wu, J.; Chiclana, F.; Ji, F.; Fujita, H. Global feedback mechanism by explicit and implicit power for group consensus in social network. Inf. Fusion 2024, 104, 102205. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wu, J.; Chiclana, F.; Fujita, H.; Herrera-Viedma, E. A visual interaction consensus model for social network group decision making with trust propagation. Knowl. Based Syst. 2017, 122, 39–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yao, X.; Xu, Z. A survey of consensus in group decision making under the CWW environment. Appl. Soft Comput. 2023, 144, 110557. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Tran, T.N.T.; Felfernig, A.; Le, V.M. An overview of consensus models for group decision-making and group recommender systems. User Model. User-Adapt. Interact. 2023, 34, 489–547. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhou, M.; Zhou, Y.J.; Liu, X.B.; Wu, J.; Fujita, H.; Herrera-Viedma, E. An adaptive two-stage consensus reaching process based on heterogeneous judgments and social relations for large-scale group decision making. Inf. Sci. 2023, 644, 119280. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Chiclana, F.; Herrera-Viedma, E.; Herrera, F.; Alonso, S. Some induced ordered weighted averaging operators and their use for solving group decision-making problems based on fuzzy preference relations. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2007, 182, 383–399. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yager, R.R. Quantifier guided aggregation using OWA operators. Int. J. Intell. Syst. 1996, 11, 49–73. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yan, H.B.; Ma, T.; Huynh, V.N. On qualitative multi-attribute group decision making and its consensus measure: A probability based perspective. Omega 2017, 70, 94–117. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Xu, J.; Wu, Z.; Zhang, Y. A consensus based method for multi-criteria group decision making under uncertain linguistic setting. Group Decis. Negot. 2014, 23, 127–148. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Pang, J.; Liang, J. Evaluation of the results of multi-attribute group decision-making with linguistic information. Omega 2012, 40, 294–301. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sun, B.; Ma, W. An approach to consensus measurement of linguistic preference relations in multi-attribute group decision making and application. Omega 2015, 51, 83–92. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- De Luca, A.; Termini, S. A definition of a nonprobabilistic entropy in the setting of fuzzy sets theory. Inf. Control 1972, 20, 301–312. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Knopfmacher, J. On measures of fuzziness. J. Math. Anal. Appl. 1975, 49, 529–534. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dombi, J.; Jónás, T. On a Parametric Measure of Vagueness. IEEE Trans. Fuzzy Syst. 2022, 31, 343–347. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dombi, J. A General Class of Fuzzy Operators, the De Morgan Class of Fuzzy Operators and Fuzziness Measures Included by Fuzzy Operators. Fuzzy Sets Syst. 1982, 8, 149–168. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dombi, J. Fuzziness measure in the Pliant system: The vagueness measure. Acta Tech. Jaurinensis 2011, 4, 3–11. [Google Scholar]
- Fodor, J.C.; Roubens, M. Fuzzy Preference Modelling and Multicriteria Decision Support; Springer Science & Business Media: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 1994; Volume 14. [Google Scholar]
- Klement, E.; Mesiar, R.; Pap, E. Triangular Norms; Trends in Logic; Springer: Dordrecht, The Netherlands, 2013. [Google Scholar]
- Trillas, E. Sobre functiones de negacion en la teoria de conjuntas difusos. Stochastica 1979, 3, 47–60. [Google Scholar]
- Dombi, J. De Morgan systems with an infinitely many negations in the strict monotone operator case. Inf. Sci. 2011, 181, 1440–1453. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dombi, J.; Jónás, T. Remarks on two representations of strong negations and a connection between nilpotent and strict triangular norms. Fuzzy Sets Syst. 2022, 448, 173–177. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Beliakov, G.; James, S.; Calvo, T. Aggregating fuzzy implications to measure group consensus. In Proceedings of the 2013 Joint IFSA World Congress and NAFIPS Annual Meeting (IFSA/NAFIPS), Edmonton, AB, Canada, 24–28 June 2013; IEEE: Piscataway, NJ, USA, 2013; pp. 1016–1021. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Grabisch, M.; Marichal, J.L.; Mesiar, R.; Pap, E. Aggregation functions: Means. Inf. Sci. 2011, 181, 1–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dombi, J.; Jónás, T. Weighted aggregation systems and an expectation level-based weighting and scoring procedure. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2022, 299, 580–588. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Porcu, E.; Mateu, J.; Christakos, G. Quasi-arithmetic means of covariance functions with potential applications to space–time data. J. Multivar. Anal. 2009, 100, 1830–1844. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hou, B.; Wang, D.; Xia, T.; Wang, Y.; Zhao, Y.; Tsui, K.L. Investigations on quasi-arithmetic means for machine condition monitoring. Mech. Syst. Signal Process. 2021, 151, 107451. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Aczél, J. On mean values. Bull. Am. Math. Soc. 1948, 54, 392–400. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bullen, P.S.; Mitrinovic, D.S.; Vasic, M. Means and Their Inequalities, Mathematics and Its Applications (East European Series); D. Reidel Publishing Co.: Dordrecht, The Netherlands, 1998; Volume 31. [Google Scholar]
- Dong, J.; Hu, J.; Zhao, Y.; Peng, Y. Opinion formation analysis for Expressed and Private Opinions (EPOs) models: Reasoning private opinions from behaviors in group decision-making systems. Expert Syst. Appl. 2024, 236, 121292. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
1 | 2 | 3 | 4 | ||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
0.9 | 0.3 | 0.2 | 0.2 | ||
Case A | 0.25 | 0.25 | 0.25 | 0.25 | |
Case B | 0.5 | 0.167 | 0.167 | 0.167 |
i: | 1 | 2 | 3 | 4 | Property | |||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Case | 0.5 | 0.167 | 0.167 | 0.167 | ||||
1 | : | 0.9 | 0.3 | 0.2 | 0.2 | 0.311 | 0.306 | |
2 | : | 0.1 | 0.7 | 0.8 | 0.8 | 0.311 | 0.306 | |
3 | : | 1 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0.000 | 0.000 | |
4 | : | 0 | 1 | 1 | 1 | 0.000 | 0.000 | |
5 | : | 0.7 | 0.7 | 0.7 | 0.7 | 1.000 | 1.000 | |
6 | : | 0.9 | 0.6 | 0.2 | 0.2 | 0.344 | 0.323 | |
7 | : | 0.9 | 0.6 | 0.3 | 0.3 | 0.433 | 0.417 | |
8 | : | 0.9 | 0.3 | 0.3 | 0.3 | 0.400 | 0.400 | |
9 | : | 0.5 | 0.3 | 0.3 | 0.3 | 0.800 | 0.800 |
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content. |
© 2025 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Dombi, J.; Fáró, J.; Jónás, T. A Group Consensus Measure That Takes into Account the Relative Importance of the Decision-Makers. Mathematics 2025, 13, 526. https://doi.org/10.3390/math13030526
Dombi J, Fáró J, Jónás T. A Group Consensus Measure That Takes into Account the Relative Importance of the Decision-Makers. Mathematics. 2025; 13(3):526. https://doi.org/10.3390/math13030526
Chicago/Turabian StyleDombi, József, Jenő Fáró, and Tamás Jónás. 2025. "A Group Consensus Measure That Takes into Account the Relative Importance of the Decision-Makers" Mathematics 13, no. 3: 526. https://doi.org/10.3390/math13030526
APA StyleDombi, J., Fáró, J., & Jónás, T. (2025). A Group Consensus Measure That Takes into Account the Relative Importance of the Decision-Makers. Mathematics, 13(3), 526. https://doi.org/10.3390/math13030526