1. Introduction
Given the recent financial crisis of 2008, academic researchers, market practitioners, and regulators are keen to understand better the highly contentious impact of short-sales policies on stability and pricing efficiency within capital markets. Stock exchanges and government supervisory bodies have found it difficult to reach any consensus on a consistent set of short-selling guidelines. As a result, short-sales regulations continue to vary widely across countries and capital markets [
1]. In contrast, researchers have generally found that short-selling constraints (hereafter referred to as SSCs) will lead to a more volatile market [
1,
2,
3,
4,
5,
6,
7,
8,
9,
10] and market inefficiency of SSCs [
11,
12,
13,
14,
15]. In contrast to the argument by Franklin and Gale [
16] and Chang et al. [
17], the reality appears to be an empirical puzzle since most regulators have resorted to imposing SSCs when their markets are drastically volatile. Beber and Pagano [
18] studied the impact of short-sales bans in 30 countries on liquidity, price discovery, and stock prices during the 2007–2009 crisis period and found the bans slowed down price discovery but were not associated with excess returns, except for a positive and significant association in the U.S. Similar results for price inefficiency were found in Korea [
19,
20], in China [
12], and in the U.S. [
9,
21].
To solve this puzzle, we investigate whether SSCs play a role in stabilizing a market when it is fragile. As the ability to short-sell affects liquidity and the adjustment toward new market equilibria, we seek to disentangle the effect of SSCs on price discovery and market efficiency. Miller [
22] and several recent studies [
17,
20,
23,
24,
25,
26] on the relationship between short sales and stock overvaluations [
1,
20,
22,
24,
26,
27,
28,
29] have shown that the SSCs may result in overpriced securities and low subsequent returns. This, unfortunately, may be due to the lack of transaction data or models that were able to characterize the speed of price adjustments in the past and, until recently, had seldom been used to examine price adjustments in response to new information. For example, Chen and Rhee [
20] present empirical evidence to show that short sales on the Hong Kong Exchange contributed to market efficiency by increasing the speed of price adjustment for private or public firm-specific and market-wide information.
In a departure from the existing literature, we examine the effects of SSCs on both the speed of price adjustment to the new equilibrium and market stabilization within a correctly identified threshold error correction model (TECM). By taking advantage of the changes in short-selling policies implemented between 2002 and 2009 in the emerging Taiwanese market, our study provides several empirical insights based on price discovery within a series of “natural social” experiments. The beauty of the model used in the context of different regimes is that we can perform direct counterfactual analysis to assess “what if” scenarios when disentangling the policy effects of SSCs.
From an equilibrium perspective, if the restrictions on short sales hinder price discovery in the underlying spot index, investors can alternatively short-sell, at an even lower cost, by writing puts or shorting calls in the options and futures markets [
2,
18,
23,
30,
31,
32,
33,
34,
35,
36,
37]. Voluminous empirical results have suggested that the options market plays a more informative price discovery role, significantly when short-selling is restricted in the spot market. Therefore, we use the put–call parity-derived index, free from model misspecifications and biased volatility inputs [
38], as a proxy for the virtual price equilibrium. We explore dynamically how mispricing is adjusted towards the new equilibrium through this cointegration linkage between the spot and derivative markets. The analysis of the effects of SSCs on adjustment speed is straightforward and uses a comprehensive TECM approach. More importantly, unlike the extant literature that employs daily or monthly data, our study hinges on the 1 min high-frequency equilibrium deviations to resolve the issue of market efficiency adjustment and issues about market stability under SSCs. These are all highlighted as the significant differences between our study and those in the recent literature.
Our main findings are as follows. First, short-sales constraints in mispricing lead to a less efficient market by creating asymmetry in both the magnitude and the speed of price adjustments. Within our TECM, the convergence rate of upward adjustments is more rapid than that of downward adjustments, even after controlling for market conditions and liquidity. Secondly, the speed of downward adjustments significantly improves after the relaxation of such constraints. Finally, we find that tighter SSCs help to retain investors’ confidence, effectively discouraging the execution of “fire sales” and saving the market from liquidity “droughts”, as verified by our counterfactual analysis of the realized equilibrium adjustments. However, tighter constraints provide little help in stabilizing market fluctuations, which are generally associated with more significant downside risk and higher volatility. Specifically, our robustness check reveals that these results hold, even after controlling for the investor “fear index” or “fear gauge”, which is proxied by the Taiwan volatility index (TVIX) obtained from the Taiwan Futures Exchange (TAIFEX) in our study.
Our empirical results shed practical economic light. The market is fragile during the financial crisis, as the market liquidity critically depends on investor confidence. The consideration of flying to safety or liquidity can further amplify the contraction of funding liquidity through the unwinding and deleveraging of positions among various market participants. Given that a loss of confidence can trigger fire sales and destabilize the financial system, the SSCs, as a policy tool, can be used to protect against these undesired scenarios. Policymakers may then take advantage of the SSCs by optimally striking a nice balance between the cost of obstructing price efficiency and the benefits of restoring investor confidence, mainly when it is scarce during a financial crisis.
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. A description of the data and short-sales policy changes in Taiwan is presented in
Section 2, followed in
Section 3 by developing our hypotheses and empirical design.
Section 4 presents our main empirical results along with a counterfactual analysis. Various robustness checks are provided in
Section 5. Finally, the conclusions drawn from this study are presented in
Section 6.
2. Data and Description of Short-Sales Policies
It can be empirically tricky, if not impossible, to identify the policy impacts of SSCs since the durations of SSCs policies implemented are often too short for meaningful examinations of the policy consequences, even for some specific developed countries. However, the experience of Taiwan provides an interesting avenue for research, as a ban on short-selling in terms of the uptick rule was superimposed in Taiwan over a long period, from 22 September 2008 to 31 December 2008.
The data analyzed in this study are intraday TAIFEX index option prices and their common underlying asset on the Taiwan Stock Exchange Capitalization Weighted Stock Index (TAIEX) from 2002 to 2009, the details of which are available from the TEJ (Taiwan Economic Journal., Ltd., Taipei City, Taiwan) database. We chose the TAIEX index because the institutional factors within the Taiwanese market closely resemble a representative case of an emerging market with its large population of retail investors, heavy government intervention, and regulatory controls. These institutional factors are distinctly different from those in the markets of developed countries. Therefore, the impacts of such SSC policy adjustments toward market efficiency and stability are of practical relevance and informative for many emerging and developing economies.
2.1. Six SSC Policy Regimes from 2000 to 2009
The Taiwan Stock Exchange (hereafter TWSE) initially imposed an uptick rule in September 1998, allowing short-selling at least as high as the closing price for the previous trading day for all stocks eligible for short sales. SSCs, in terms of the uptick rule, are stricter in Taiwan than in the U.S., since the uptick rule in U.S. stock exchanges requires that the short-selling prices not be lower than the best current asking price. In an attempt to improve the efficiency of price discovery, the TWSE relaxed the uptick rule on 30 June 2003 for equities listed in the first exchange-traded fund (ETF), the Taiwan Top50 Tracker Fund (TTT) (ID: 0050). Starting on 16 May 2005, the component stocks of the TTT were allowed to freely short-sell. Among the largest and most actively traded stocks listed on the TWSE, these are less vulnerable to potential price manipulations. Therefore, we have the following three periods: p1, from 2 January 2002 to 29 June 2003; p2, from 30 June 2003 to 15 May 2005; and p3, from 16 May 2005 to 11 November 2007. Starting on 12 November 2007, the constituent stocks of the Taiwan Mid-Cap 100 index and the Technology Index were also exempted from the uptick rule. As a reaction to the global financial crisis, from 22 September 2008 to the end of that year, the TWSE banned the short-selling of 150 companies’ shares below their closing prices on the previous day, which marks our fourth and fifth sub-periods as p4, from 12 November 2007 to 21 September 2008, and p5, from 22 September 2008 to 31 December 2008. It should be noted that the regulators imposed a further ban on the short-selling of all stocks from 1 October to 27 November 2008, prohibiting all short-selling during that period. Finally, p6 denotes the relaxation of all SSCs from 2009 onwards. Beginning 23 September 2013, around 1200 borrowed stocks and ETFs currently eligible for margin trading have been exempted from the uptick rule and can be sold for lower than the closing price on the previous trading day. ETFs are exempt from the uptick rule, except for the short-sales ban of P5 within our data period.
As our sample period runs from January 2002 to December 2009, we divide the entire sample period into six sub-periods according to these short-sales policy changes (see
Figure 1). The strength of the SSCs throughout the various periods, from the highest to lowest, is in the order of p5, p1, p2, p3, p6, and p4. Although SSCs were relaxed after the end of 2008, the basis for calculating securities borrowing and lending balances has been restricted since 22 July 2009. Hence, the weakest SSCs are in p4 rather than in p6. Although no stock or ETF was exempted from the uptick rule in p1, no stocks or ETFs were allowed to short-sell at any price level from 1 October to 27 November 2008 within p5. Hence, the highest intensity of SSCs is p5 rather than p1. Thus, these policy changes provide us with natural proxies for examining the effects of the SSCs on market stability and efficiency.
2.2. SSC Proxies
Most previous empirical studies related to SSCs rely either on various measures to characterize the strength of SSCs or on restricted samples with lending data. The former includes a variety of proxies that have been used for capturing higher SSCs or higher short-sales costs, including the lower lending supply or higher loan fees [
6], lower rebate rates [
4,
5,
37,
38,
39,
40], negative rebate rate spread [
27], and low daily short interest [
26]. Some proxies for relaxed short-sales restrictions are the presence of stock options [
5,
23,
41] the introduction of stock futures [
42], the availability of short-selling [
20], or the percentage of proceeds available to short-sellers [
43]. Another stream uses lending data provided by one or some custodians. Geczy et al. [
39] used one-year rebate data (November 1998 to October 1999) provided by a U.S. custodian bank to study borrowing costs for IPOs, whilst Ofek et al. [
27] relied on the rebate rate from one of the largest dealer–brokers. Saffi and Sigurdsson [
6] once argued that ten custodians obtained the average loan fee for 12,621 firms from 26 countries, representing the average lending price. However, it could be challenging to collect complete data from all custodians, and since we can never know whether custodians have different pricing strategies, such data may not be at the equilibrium lending price.
As suggested by Diether et al. [
26] and Saffi and Sigurdsson [
6], it is difficult to determine whether high short interest reflects either negative sentiment amongst investors regarding the stock or lower SSCs. As Diether et al. [
26] have further argued that short-sellers will quickly cover their positions, the monthly short interest would be inappropriate for addressing the short-term adjustments toward a new equilibrium. These shortcomings can be avoided through the use of better proxies for SSCs. Fortunately, the short-sales policy changes in Taiwan between 2002 and 2009 provided a natural platform for examining how the market equilibrium responds to the various SSC regimes. Our paper addresses how the emerging market reacts to SSC policy changes.
2.3. The Implied Index Price and Equilibrium Deviations
The theoretical index price obtained in this study is based upon put–call parity, a simple no-arbitrage relationship for which there are no superimposed assumptions regarding agents’ preferences or return distributions [
38]. There are advantages in deriving the theoretical index price from put–call parity. First, since the TAIFEX options are European-style, we can avoid the potential effects of early exercise risk on mispricing errors. Thus, the “per minute” synchronously matched data rule out the potential problem of non-synchronicity. Secondly, the options market has fewer transaction limitations than the stock market, and, as shown by Miller [
22], investors prefer to trade in a less limited market where the asset prices immediately reflect new information. In the absence of arbitrage opportunities, the put–call parity suggests that the implied index price be given by:
where
(
) denotes the call (put) price at the time
for an option contract maturing at
with strike price
,
is the synthesized implied price as a proxy for the equilibrium price, and
is the risk-free rate and
represents the strike price.
Given the current index price, we collect seven series of near-month option contracts with different moneyness. To remove the effect of varying moneyness, we then average the seven implied index prices over their moneyness to arrive at the final theoretical index price (
for time t. For example, given the previous trading day’s closing price of 5678, we would round the number to 5700. We then collect option contracts with strike prices ranging from 5400 to 6000 to derive their corresponding implied indices. Each series is matched with the same strike price and the same maturity. We then average the seven implied index prices over moneyness to obtain the final theoretical index price (
) for time t. Intuitively, the logarithmic observed index value and the put–call parity implied theoretical index are cointegrated with their common trend, discernibly depicted in
Figure 2a, and the formal cointegration test results are provided in
Table 1.
It is interesting to explore why the positive deviations between the index price and the theoretical index price became more extensive during the short-sales ban period (as we can see from
Figure 2c and
Figure 3a) and whether the regulators imposed such constraints to stabilize prices while witnessing more significant fluctuations in returns, as illustrated in
Figure 2b.
Figure 2 illustrates the time plot for the index price, the index returns, and the price deviations between 2002 and 2009, during which there was a total of six SSC policy changes (indicated by the vertical red lines).
Figure 3a presents the time plot for price deviations under different SSC pressures,
Figure 3b concentrates on the tail behavior of the price deviations, and
Figure 3c concentrates on the tail behavior of the index returns.
Our sample period runs from 2 January 2002 to 31 December 2009, yielding 1989 days and 539,109 one-minute intraday observations. We use high-frequency data instead of previous empirical studies that employed low-frequency data because the results indicate that short-sellers covered their positions within a few days. Diether et al. [
26] found that short-sellers covered their positions in 5.4 days on the NYSE and in 4.4 days on the NASDAQ, with daily short interest rather than monthly data.
Utilizing data at a lower frequency may fail to resemble the equilibrium adjustment and hinder the price discovery occurring at a higher frequency. In the present study, we find that the average time taken to converge to equilibrium in the examined Taiwanese market between 2002 and 2009 was, on average, 26 min. Secondly, given the high proportion of day-trading activities and high turnover in the Taiwanese market, only high-frequency data may help reveal the nature of equilibrium adjustments and efficiency changes, particularly during exogenous policy changes.
2.4. Other Variables and Control Variables
Using high-frequency data avoids the potential problem of non-synchronous trading confounding the results, while index-level analysis undertaken at a market-wide aggregate level can help prevent idiosyncratic risk and analyst disagreement. Tentative explanations for price deviations include the presence of transaction costs [
27,
44,
45], non-synchronous trading [
46], market illiquidity [
27,
43,
47], idiosyncratic risk [
48], the microstructure effect [
49], analyst disagreement [
50] and SSC costs [
27,
45]. Given the potential link between price movements and other variables, such as liquidity, transaction costs, market conditions, and the microstructure effect, it is essential to control alternative concerns properly.
Saffi and Sigurdsson [
6] provided controls for firm capitalization, liquidity, and transaction costs to avoid such spurious findings when examining how stock pricing efficiency and return distributions were affected by SSCs. The liquidity and transaction cost variables included total share turnover, incidences of zero weekly returns, the annual average of the weekly quoted bid–ask spread, and the Datastream free float measure. Therefore, a total of five measures are employed to control for the effects of market liquidity on price movements: (i) Num_Trades is the number of trades in the previous minute, (ii) Num_Shares denotes the number of trading shares in the previous minute, (iii) TDollar
t−1 denotes the amount of trading in the previous minute (in dollars × 1000), (iv) Daily_Turnover is calculated as the trading volume on the previous day divided by the number of outstanding shares on the previous day, and (v) Daily_Turnover/MV denotes the daily trading dollars divided by the daily market value [
6]. As we can see from
Table 2, the market was more liquid during periods when SSCs were lifted.
We also use four different methodologies to portray the market conditions. The , , , and are the average return, standard deviations, skewness, and kurtosis calculated from the one-minute index returns over the previous three-month period. The variables capture the heavy tail phenomena in the index returns, while , the average market returns over the previous three-month period, captures how bear or bull markets affect price movements.
Jiang et al. [
51] deleted their sample’s first ten-minute data segments, as investors could have been overreacting to overnight news releases. Since the present study focuses on intraday return behavior, an overnight dummy variable (identifying transactions occurring at 9:00 a.m.) is included in our model to control for the overnight effect on price movements. In their analysis of the impact of the short-sales price test pilot plan on market quality in the U.S., Diether et al. [
52] excluded data from 9:30 to 10:00 a.m. to avoid the undue influence of the market opening in their results. Following their merits, we also include open and closed dummies for control in this study, where Open (Close) equals one if the transactions occurred during the 9:01–9:30 (13:01–13:30) period.
3. Hypothesis Development and Empirical Design
Most of the previous theoretical or empirical studies looking at the policy effects of SSCs are concerned with the magnitude of price changes and subsequent reduced returns [
1,
2,
22,
24,
27,
28,
29,
53,
54]. Saffi and Sigurdsson [
6] found price efficiency increases with smaller SSCs [
1,
24,
27,
28,
29,
51,
55,
56,
57,
58], while they find no evidence of the relaxation of SSCs leading to price fluctuations or extreme negative returns. However, few studies, except for that of Chen and Rhee [
20], have examined the speed of adjustment towards the fundamental price. This paper seeks to fill this gap.
To see this, we define the price deviation
as the natural logarithmic difference between the index price
and the theoretical index price
as the error-correction term representing the possible arbitrage opportunities:
The cointegrating vector (the mispricing error or error correction term) is estimated as (1, −0.99) and is simplified to (1, −1) under the cointegration test in
Table 1. Under the assumption of a perfect market, if the index price is too high relative to the fundamental value (i.e.,
), then arbitrageurs will engage in short-selling or sell the spot commodity to mitigate the discrepancy, whereas if the index price is undervalued (
), then the opposite trading strategies will occur. Both actions will ensure adjustment towards the fundamental price (
). In reality, for each SSC policy regime, we average over the unconditional number of minutes, and the price persists in being overpriced (underpriced) until it reverts to its fundamental price with a given threshold. Our preliminary results exhibit a discernible asymmetric pattern between upward and downward adjustments. The analyzed results are available upon request, and we find an overvaluation taking from 27 to 86 min to converge to equilibrium during the period with the strongest SSC, as compared to just 11 to 16 min to equilibrium for an undervaluation during the period with the fewest SSCs, after considering the transaction costs. We use the given threshold as transaction cost by 0.4425% (−0.1425%) since the explicit transaction costs of investors in Taiwan for sales (purchases) of stocks in the TWSE market are 0.4425% (0.1425%).
3.1. Price Adjustment Speed
To illustrate the effects of upward and downward price adjustments, we specifically employ the three-regime threshold error correction model (TECM) with varying upward and downward adjustment rates to identify whether any asymmetric patterns exist in the convergence speed. The TECM model has been used to describe many economic phenomena, such as government intervention in exchange rates when the market price diverges too far from the fair price (where an exchange rate is almost a random walk within thresholds). The TECM specifies the magnitude of the deviation from the theoretical price that will ultimately trigger trading and provides possible estimates for explicit and implicit transaction costs, which may prevent investors from adjusting immediately [
59]. From a financial standpoint, we also care about the extent to which the deviations may be sufficiently large to cover the total costs incurred by investors, including transaction costs and risk. The nonlinear flexibility to estimate the latent decision thresholds in a TECM allows us to capture the market frictions, such as transaction costs, the tax burden, and the market microstructure.
We set out to characterize market friction and price adjustments in terms of a more general three-regime TECM. The threshold values (
,
) are estimated by following the approach of Enders and Siklos [
60] and Balke and Fomby [
61]. Dwyer et al. [
59] showed that the estimated threshold value (c) was similar to actual world transaction costs in analyzing the non-linear dynamic relationship between S&P 500 futures and the cash indices attributable to non-zero transaction costs. The three-regime TECM is estimated using the thresholds
, and
:
where
(
) refers to the speed of downward (upward) adjustments, accounting for all transaction costs (such as
), and
refers to the speed of the adjustment in the interband while the other notations follow the same previous definitions.
is the error correction term, and the coefficient specifies the speed of adjustment towards the theoretical price, which should be negative. Within the model,
is the lag operator determined by the minimum Akaike information criterion (AIC) and Schwarz information criterion (SIC) compromising for white noise in
, with
being set at 21. We include three categories of control variables (
): expressed market liquidity, market condition, and microstructure effect. Since Connolly [
62] noted that the conventional
t-value criterion was inappropriate for large sample sizes, a size-adjusted critical
t-value (3.65) is used to determine significance. We examine Hypothesis 1, which states that the adjustment speed will be more rapid for upward adjustments.
Hypothesis 1: Upward adjustments are more rapid than downward adjustments under general SSCs.
When the SSC binds, assets can be overpriced due to the SSC impeding arbitrage activities by pessimistic traders. As a result, the adjustment period for an overvaluation should be extended. By analogy, the market will exhibit a slower downward adjustment under a tighter SSC. Given the disclosure of a significantly different adjustment period for overvaluations but no significant differences for undervaluations between the weakest and strongest SSC intensity (
and
periods) in our preliminary results, we proceed to examine whether the slower speed of price adjustment is more pronounced at the time in which short sales are prohibited, and whether price efficiency improves during periods of relaxed SSCs, as noted in
Section 2.1.
We define
(and
) as the average downward adjustment speed during strict (and relaxed) SSCs. We go on to extend our three-regime TECM with downward (upward) adjustment speed under the various policy changes to examine the adjustment speed between the weakest (
) and strongest (
) levels of SSC with the estimated thresholds of
and
as follows:
where
(
) is the downward (upward) adjustment speed, taking all transaction costs into account under the various policy changes (
and
). The other notation follows previous definitions.
The three-regime TECM enables us to specify which size deviations from the theoretical price will trigger trading and resolve the puzzle of how SSC affects market efficiency. If the SSCs suppress the realization of lousy news in prices, one would expect market efficiency to improve when the SSCs are relaxed, i.e., the speed of the rigid downward adjustment to new information will be more rapid. Therefore, we construct Hypothesis 2 as follows:
Hypothesis 2: The speed of downward adjustment will increase due to the relaxation of SSCs.
3.2. Price Stabilization Under SSCs: A Counterfactual Analysis
To shed light on the remaining puzzle regarding the short-selling policy and market stabilization, i.e., why the regulators still employ academically vicious SSCs for stabilization, we conduct an informative counterfactual analysis to see what would happen if the SSC policy is not launched (or with a zero-SSC). Recall that the option-implied theoretical price is free from SSCs. Therefore, the theoretical price should be least affected by the short-sales ban, and only the index price should be adjusted in cases of a short-sales ban. We follow Politis and Romano [
63] and Hsu, Hsu, and Kuan [
64] to examine whether the market price may have fallen even further without the short-sales ban based upon a counterfactual simulation and stationary bootstrap method. As the speeds of adjustment across different levels of SSC intensity are well estimated in our adopted TECM model, we simulate the market price without the short-sales ban and then examine whether the price with the short-sales ban could mitigate the price fluctuations.
Hypothesis 3: The price without a short-sales ban may drop more than that with a short-sales ban.
Short-sales activities are arguably an essential element of any discussion of market stabilization. Regulators claim that short-selling is detrimental to price stabilization. However, the academic evidence indicates that stocks with fewer SSCs have lower kurtosis [
6] and lower levels of downside risk and total volatility. The volatility estimated by intraday data is more informative and a good predictor of volatility [
65]. Therefore, we employe 1 min data to obtain daily return characteristics, including daily kurtosis, skewness, extreme negative (positive) return frequency, realized risk, and downside risk, which are the proxy of return volatility. Daily kurtosis captures the frequency of extreme returns, and higher negative skewness indicates a higher probability of extreme negative returns. The realized risk and downside risk capture the whole volatility and negative volatility. Based on the advantage of the market volatility with intraday data, we can test our hypothesis to examine whether higher-intensity SSCs lead to higher total risk and the downside risk, and then go on to provide some suggestions for regulators about short-sales policy.
Hypothesis 4: Tighter SSCs, or a total ban on short sales, will not enhance the price stabilization.
6. Conclusions
The regime shifts in the regulatory uptick rules in Taiwan between 2002 and 2009 provide a sequence of natural experimental environments to examine the stock market efficiency and stability of short-sales policy changes in Taiwan. Our research arrives at three main empirical findings.
First, in the presence of mispricing, SSCs lead to a less efficient market by delivering asymmetries in the magnitudes and speed of price adjustments. Consistent with prior studies, such constraints are generally found to hinder the reflection of negative information in the price; thus, based on the TECM adopted for this study, we document that upward adjustments converge more rapidly than downward adjustments, even when controlling for market conditions and liquidity. Secondly, we find that the speed of downward adjustments is improved in periods characterized by relaxed SSCs. Market efficiency is improved during fewer SSC periods. Finally, the realized equilibrium adjustments identified through our counterfactual analysis also indicate that SSCs can indeed restore investor confidence, thereby discouraging the execution of fire sales and saving the market from further liquidity problems. However, such restrictions are of very little help in stabilizing market fluctuations. In particular, stricter short-sales restrictions are associated with more significant downside risk and higher volatility.
Our results hold, even after controlling for the investor fear gauge, which is proxied by the TVIX in this study. Interestingly, however, our findings support the academic finding that short-sales constraints generally lead to a less efficient market. Even though there is no evidence suggesting that regulators can stabilize prices by restricting short sales, such policy announcements may likely retain or restore investors’ confidence, a valuable yet scarce resource, wildly when markets are plunging. We suggest the regulators utilize the counterfactual analysis to simulate and predict the effects of short-sales policy on price movement, and then adjust the parameters of the model to improve the accuracy of predictions on SSC policy for the emerging market.