1. Introduction
Over the last few years, several
dynamic risk measures, i.e., risk measures based on ruin-theoretic quantities, have been studied. For example, in the classical compound Poisson risk model,
Trufin et al. (
2011) considered a VaR-type risk measure defined as the smallest initial capital needed to ensure a certain probability of solvency throughout the lifetime of the surplus process. This risk measure has been extended by
Mitric and Trufin (
2016) who defined a risk measure taking into account both the probability of ruin and the expected deficit at ruin. In addition,
Loisel and Trufin (
2014) used the expected area below the solvency threshold as a risk indicator to introduce a new risk measure with some interesting properties.
Very recently, implementation delays in the recognition of ruin and occupation times of the surplus process have been used as alternative risk management tools to assess the quality of an insurance portfolio. In this direction,
Guérin and Renaud (
2017) introduced the concept of cumulative Parisian ruin, which is based on the
time spent in the red by the underlying surplus process. The time of cumulative Parisian ruin is the first time the surplus process stays cumulatively below a critical level longer than a pre-determined grace period. Inspired by the risk measure of
Trufin et al. (
2011), they defined a VaR-type risk measure based on cumulative Parisian ruin. It is also defined as the smallest amount of capital for which the associated cumulative Parisian ruin probability is less than or equal to a tolerable level.
In this paper, we study this VaR-type risk measure based on cumulative Parisian ruin. In
Guérin and Renaud (
2017), this risk measure is proposed as a motivational reason to study the concept of cumulative Parisian ruin; the risk measure itself is neither analyzed nor used for any particular application. We derive some of its properties and compare it to the risk measures of
Trufin et al. (
2011) and
Loisel and Trufin (
2014).
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In
Section 2, we recall some background on the Cramér–Lundberg model, also known as the classical risk model, and define the concept of cumulative Parisian ruin. In
Section 3, we introduce our risk measure and we give some of its properties. Finally, in
Section 4, we study our risk measure in the special case of a Cramér–Lundberg process with exponential claims.
2. Insurance Risk Model
The Cramér–Lundberg model was proposed by
Lundberg (
1903) and further developed by
Cramér (
1930). In this model, the surplus process of an insurance company is modelled by
where
and
, and where
is a compound Poisson process with
a Poisson process of intensity
and with
positive random variables following a common cumulative distribution function
. Recall that in this setup the claim sizes
are mutually independent and are also independent of the number-of-claim process
N. The process
is known as the aggregate claim amount process. We call
x the initial capital and
c the premium rate.
We use the following equivalent notations to emphasize that the process X starts at level x. The notation corresponds to . When , we drop the index. In this model, the premium rate c is chosen usually to satisfy the net profit condition , which means that we can define the safety loading factor by .
The time of classical ruin associated to
X is defined as
We denote the corresponding finite-time probability of ruin, for
and
, by
and the infinite-time probability of ruin by
Of course, we have .
In
Trufin et al. (
2011), assuming that the safety loading
is fixed, the following ruin-consistent VaR-type risk measure is defined and analyzed: for a tolerance level
, set
It is well known that we can compute
using the Pollaczeck–Khinchine formula (also known in the actuarial literature as the Beekman’s convolution formula, see
Beekman (
1985)) which states that the probability of classical ruin is equal to the tail distribution function of a compound geometric random variable. First, let us define the aggregate loss at time
t by
and the maximal aggregate loss of the process by
. The random variable
L can be expressed as
where
M is the number of record highs, which has a geometric distribution with success probability
, and where
are the ladder heights with common distribution
. The Pollaczeck–Khinchine formula for the probability of ruin is then given by
where
denotes the
-th convolution of the distribution
. Therefore, this risk measure can also be written as follows:
In some sense, the focus of this risk measure is shifted from the surplus process
X to the distribution of the maximal aggregate loss
L. This important relationship is at the core of the analysis done in
Trufin et al. (
2011). However, this relationship with the maximal aggregate loss
L does not exist for the finite-time ruin probability. Note that this is also the case for the VaR-type risk measure defined and analyzed in
Mitric and Trufin (
2016).
Cumulative Parisian Ruin
Recently,
Guérin and Renaud (
2017) introduced a new definition of actuarial ruin based on the occupation-time process (below 0) associated with the surplus process
X. The occupation-time process
is defined as
Then, the time of cumulative Parisian ruin, with delay
, is given by
In the definition of cumulative Parisian ruin, we aggregate the duration of all periods of financial distress until we accumulate
r units of time spent in that red zone. Consequently, ruin is not declared as soon as
X goes below zero: for
,
and
, we have
Cumulative Parisian ruin is somehow a generalization of classical ruin and, when
, we recover the classical definition (see
Guérin and Renaud (
2017) for the details and see
Figure 1 for a graphical comparison).
We denote the finite-time probability of cumulative Parisian ruin by
and the infinite-time version by
Of course, we have
. With this new notation in hand, we can re-write the inequality in Equation (
7) as follows: for
,
and
, we have
3. A VaR-type Risk Measure Derived from Cumulative Parisian Ruin
Using the definition of cumulative Parisian ruin,
Guérin and Renaud (
2017) defined the following VaR-type risk measure: for a time horizon of length
t and delay
r, and for a given tolerance level
, set
It gives the amount of initial capital needed in order to bound the finite-time probability of cumulative Parisian ruin with delay
r by
. Since
, we can also write
Consequently, this risk measure is based on the distribution of
. This is the analog of the random variable
L for the risk measure in Equation (
6). A major improvement is that we can now vary both the time horizon and the implementation delay by changing the values of
t and
r, respectively. The trade-off is that we need the distribution of a strongly path-dependent random variable, namely
.
For the rest of this paper, we focus on the properties of this VaR-type cumulative Parisian risk measure. In addition, we compare the infinite-time version to the infinite-time risk measure defined in
Trufin et al. (
2011). Then, we also study the finite-time version as this is possible as soon as the distribution of
is available.
Before going any further, let us give some background material on stochastic dominance.
3.1. Stochastic Dominance
Consider two random variables
X and
Y, and let
and
be their survival functions. We say that
X is smaller than
Y in the stochastic dominance order, which is denoted by
, if
Equivalently, for all non-decreasing functions
, we have
Theorem 1. - (i)
Let and be two finite sets of independent random variables such that , for each . Then, for any increasing function , we have - (ii)
Consider two sequences of random variables and and two random variables X and Y such thatwhere denotes convergence in distribution. If for each n, then . - (iii)
Let the positive integer-valued random variable N be independent of the family of random variables and define . Define similarly .
If and for each i, then
Finally, if
and
are stochastic processes, then we write
if, for each
, we have
3.2. Properties of the Risk Measure
In the following, let
L and
be two aggregate loss amount processes associated with two aggregate claim amount processes
S and
, themselves from two Cramér–Lundberg risk processes
X and
as defined in v(
1).
Theorem 2. For , and , we have:
- (i)
Invariance by translation:For , - (ii)
Positive homogeneity:For , - (iii)
Monotonicity:If , then
Proof. This proves Equation (
14).
Similarly, if we note that
then Equation (
15) follows.
To prove the third property, we fix
and we show that, if
for all
, then
First, let us define a sequence of discretized versions of the occupation-time process
. For each
, choose
such that
, as
, and define
We define
in the obvious way, i.e., when
S is replaced by
. We can re-write
as follows:
where
Since
for all
, then we have
for each
i. Then, since
we have that
for each
i. From Equation (
12), we obtain
or equivalently
Since
and
, by the second part of Theorem 1, we get
The property in Equation (
16) follows. ☐
The monotonicity property in Equation (
16) says that the risk measure
is increasing with respect to the stochastic dominance order. Note that, if
for all
, then we can also prove that
If we put together the monotonicity property in Equations (
16) and (
13), then we can deduce the following intuitive relationship: a smaller frequency and a smaller severity yield less occupation time in the red zone and thus a smaller probability of cumulative Parisian ruin. For example, by the third part of Theorem 1, if
C and
are exponentially distributed random variables with parameters
and
, respectively, and if
,
and
, then, for a given common premium rate
c, the initial capital needed at a given tolerance level
is larger for
X than for
.
It is worth mentioning that, as an immediate consequence of Proposition 1, Theorem 2 is also satisfied for the infinite-time horizon risk measure
. Thus, we have recovered some of the results in Properties 3.1 and 3.2 of
Trufin et al. (
2011). In addition, an important consequence of Proposition 1 is the stochastic ordering for the finite-time ruin probability
.
3.3. Relationship with Other Risk Measures
Recall that our main object of study is the following VaR-type risk measure: for
,
and
,
When , we write .
We are also interested in the risk measure based on the finite-time probability of classical ruin:
Using the inequality in Equation (
9) and the discussions in the previous section, we deduce the following first proposition:
Proposition 1. For a given time horizon and an acceptance level , the risk measure is less conservative than the risk measure , i.e.,and, when , it converges to , i.e., When the implementation delay
r is replaced by copies of an exponentially distributed random variable
with rate
, then, for
, we have
In addition, in this case, cumulative Parisian ruin corresponds to Parisian ruin with exponential delays, that is
where
is is the last time before
t when the process was non-negative.
We can then define the following VaR-type risk measure: for
,
and
,
The risk measure
satisfies the properties in Theorem 2. For example, we proved that, if
, we have
. Then, using Equation (
12), we obtain
where
Hence, using Equation (
11), we get
and then
In addition, as an improvement of the finite-time version of the (infinite-horizon) risk measure defined by
Loisel and Trufin (
2014), we can define
where
is a tolerance level for the expected
area in the red defined as
where
. Furthermore, we can use Theorem 1 of
Loisel (
2005) and then write
Consequently, if we suppose that
, then
and then, from Equations (
10) and (
24), we have
Remark 1. Note that, with the distribution in Theorem 3, it is possible to compute the finite-time version of this risk measure based on the area in the red in the case of a Cramér–Lundberg process with exponential claims.
4. Example: Cramér–Lundberg Model with Exponential Claims
In this section, we want to see how reacts to changes in the value of its parameters. In other words, we want to perform a sensitivity analysis.
In general, we could use Monte Carlo simulations to compute values for . However, if we consider a Cramér–Lundberg process with exponentially distributed claims with rate parameter , then there exists an explicit expression for the distribution of the occupation time for a finite-time horizon. Unfortunately, such formulas are not available for most claim distributions.
Theorem 3 (
Guérin and Renaud (
2017)).
For , we havewithandwhere represents the modified Bessel function of the first kind of order ν. In Theorem 3,
is the survival ruin probability over
, that is
For an infinite-time horizon, we have the well-known expression:
From Corollary 2 in
Renaud (
2014), we can deduce the following expression for the distribution of
, when the claims are exponentially distributed.
Corollary 1. For any , we havewhere is the incomplete gamma function. The explicit formula in Theorem 3 allows for a sensitivity analysis of the value of the probability of cumulative Parisian ruin, when claims are exponentially distributed, with respect to the delay parameter
r and the time horizon
t. In
Figure 2, we observe that for a fixed delay parameter
r, the probability of cumulative Parisian ruin increases when the time horizon
t increases. This is because we accumulate more occupation time. On the other hand, it decreases when the delay
r increases. For a fixed value of the time horizon
t, increasing the initial capital
x decreases the probability of cumulative Parisian ruin, as expected.
For the corresponding risk measures,
Figure 3 illustrates the relationships in Equations (
19) and in (
20) between
and
. As
, i.e., as the grace period gets smaller, the initial capital needed with
increases toward that needed with
, both at a tolerance level of
. When the time horizon
t increases, both risk measures increase the initial capital needed for that tolerance level.