1. Introduction
The financial industry is a dynamic world filled with uncertainties. Risk management is the main concern for individuals, corporations, and institutions. Therefore, the use of hedging for pricing is prevalent in financial mathematics to protect against movements in future outcomes. The standard approach of hedging is to construct a portfolio of financial instruments that replicates the cash flow corresponding to the hedged item. The primary objective of hedging through the replication of the cash flow of a contingent claim is to protect against potential losses. Therefore, a contingent claim priced though this approach does not allow for profit.
The theory of quantile hedging, developed by Follmer and Leukert (1999) [
1] (see also [
2]), provides an approach that maximizes the probability of a successful hedge with reduced initial capital. Alternatively, one can define a bound
for the probability of unsuccessful hedging and minimize the initial capital required such that the probability of successful hedging is at least
. The quantile hedging concept does not allow for the selection of the probability of shortfall. Novikov (1999) [
3] proposed the approach of hedging with a given probability in a complete market with one risky and one risk-free asset. This paper will extend the approach of hedging with a given probability to the two-dimensional case and in terms of both diffusion and jump diffusion models. Furthermore, in recent years, the problem of partial hedging has been considered and studied in terms of different risk measures. For instance, the problem has been studied with the help of a class of two-parametric risk measures, the Range of VaR, which includes the risk measures of VaR and CVaR.
Equity-linked life insurance contracts combine life insurance protection with investment options tied to the performance of specific equity or investment funds. They pay stochastic benefits linked to the movement in a financial market while providing guaranteed benefits. The benefits are paid only if conditions are met, such as the death or survival of the policyholders. Therefore, equity-linked insurance contract pricing is much more complicated.
As mortality cannot be traded in any market, it is not possible to hedge mortality risk. Hence, the insurance market is incomplete and perfect hedging is impossible. Applying quantile hedging to equity-linked insurance contracts allows for the separation of financial risk and mortality risk. Brennan and Schwartz (1976) [
4] and Boyle and Schwartz (1977) [
5] were the first to discuss the hedging of equity-linked insurance contracts. The approach of reducing equity-linked insurance contracts to a call or applying perfect hedging is widely used today. This paper adopts the approach developed by Brennan and Schwartz to integrate hedging with a predefined probability to hedge and price an equity-linked insurance contract.
This paper focuses on an equity-linked pure endowment contract, where the benefit payout is linked to the equity performance and is received only if the policyholder survives to the contract’s maturity date. The analysis assumes a financial market comprising one risk-free asset and two risky assets. In this paper, two models are considered: a diffusion model that incorporates two Wiener processes and their correlation coefficient
, as in Margrabe (1978) [
6] and Fischer (1978) [
7], and a jump diffusion model with a single Wiener process generating both risky assets’ prices.
In summary, this paper introduces an approach to partial hedging with a predefined probability for both two-factor diffusion and jump diffusion models, as well as introducing an efficient hedging method. Furthermore, these developed hedging strategies are applied to price equity-linked insurance contracts. Thus, we provide a practical framework for the management of combined financial and actuarial risks in hybrid insurance products.
The layout of this paper is as follows.
Section 2 introduces the financial setting. This is followed by
Section 3, illustrating Novikov’s approach of hedging with a given probability in two dimensions for the diffusion model. In
Section 4, the hedging technique is applied in the setting of the jump diffusion model. In
Section 5, we extend the approach to efficient hedging with a given shortfall.
Section 6 is devoted to the application of hedging with a given probability to equity-linked insurance contracts. Following
Section 6,
Section 7 illustrates our results with real-world data. The paper is concluded with
Section 8, which discusses the practical application of the developed method, possible future research areas, and its limitations and shortcomings.
2. Financial Background Setting
Consider an arbitrage-free two-factor diffusion model within a complete market defined on the stochastic basis
, for
. Assume that
, where
is a family of probability distributions and the processes are adapted to the filtration
, generated by the independent Wiener process
W and Poisson process
. The investor’s wealth at time
t is represented by the following equation
where
is the process of the risk-free asset’s price with
, and
are the processes of the risky assets. For simplicity, here, we assume
= 1, implying a 0 interest rate (
). Additionally, let
represent a predictable trading strategy (hedge). By definition, in an arbitrage-free complete market, there exists a unique local martingale measure
under which the processes
are local martingales with respect to measure
. Likewise, the process
is a local martingale with respect to measure
for self-financing strategies. A trading strategy is considered self-financing
(self-financing) if the investor’s capital or portfolio value
is realized without any external inflow or outflow of cash or assets. This condition is expressed as follows:
Let
T represent the maturity date, and let
H denote the pay-off of a contingent claim. The traditional method of pricing a European option involves identifying a hedge
that satisfies
The calculated risk-neutral price of the contingent claim is defined as the minimal initial investor capital () that is sufficient for (3) to hold.
Definition 1. Let represent a set of self-financing strategies where and Equation (3) holds. The risk-neutral price of the contingent claim H is defined as There exists a hedge or strategy such that . The hedge is called a perfect hedge.
The traditional method of option pricing often results in minimal returns for investors. Specifically, for European options, the gain is practically zero due to the construction of the perfect hedge. To address this limitation, we can relax condition (3), allowing investors to hedge the contingent claim while accepting a certain level of risk. In other words, instead of achieving a perfect hedge with a probability equal to one, as required by condition (3), investors can hedge the contingent claim with a probability of less than one. This adjustment can be expressed mathematically as follows:
where
is the given significance level (risk level). This method was previously studied in a market consisting of one risk-free and one risky asset by Novikov (1999) [
3]. In this paper, we extend this approach and apply it to the context of life insurance contracts.
3. Methodologies of Partial Hedging with Shortfall Risk Constraints
The second fundamental theorem of asset pricing states that, in a complete and arbitrage-free market, there exists a unique martingale probability measure
. Building on this concept, we introduce and define a new class of hedges, denoted as
. This represents a set of self-financing hedging strategies subject to a shortfall constraint determined by a specified constant
A.
where
A is a non-negative constant, and
H is the pay-off of the contingent claim. As outlined in the previous section, achieving a perfectly hedged position requires the portfolio value at maturity,
, to be at least equal to the pay-off
H. In the class
, this requirement is relaxed by adding a non-negative constant
A. This expands the set of admissible self-financing hedges by reducing the pay-off at maturity from
H to
. In this paper, we focus exclusively on hedging strategies within the
class. Using this framework and class
, we derive a lower bound for the initial capital required by the investor. This lower bound is established in the following lemma.
The lower bound for the initial investment is equal to the expected value of the pay-off minus A if the hedge is lower than the pay-off.
Proof. By assumption of the class
, we have
, a.s. We can apply the Chebyshev inequality and find that
□
We further refine the set of hedges under consideration by introducing additional constraints. This subset is constructed from the class
and is defined in relation to the initial capital
x, the pay-off
H, the significance level
, and the non-negative constant
A. These parameters collectively establish the set of admissible self-financing hedging strategies, as described below.
The risk-neutral or fair price of a European option, based on the newly defined set of hedges, is defined as follows:
is the fair price of a European option, which is the minimal initial investor capital considering the parameters introduced previously. Under general assumptions, it can be observed that a hedge
exists, characterized by the initial capital and given as
The second equality is derived from the definition of the class of hedges
. Furthermore, the third equality is obtained using general statistic properties. From the equality in Equation (
10), we can derive the following observation. Lemma 1 establishes that
serves as the lower bound for the initial capital
x. At the same time, the fair price is defined as the infimum of all possible initial capital values. Consequently, by
Lemma 1, the fair price can be expressed as
The hedge
defined above is derived using statistical techniques based on the Neyman–Pearson Lemma; see Lehmann (1986) [
8]. This lemma provides a solution to the problem of constructing a test and a decision rule that maximizes the power of the test subject to a given level of significance. Statistical power is the probability of correctly rejecting the null hypothesis when the alternative hypothesis is true. The given significance level controls the probability of type I error, usually denoted as
.
Assume that there exists an event
such that
The worst-case measure is the measure
that minimizes the probability of successful hedging. In other words, it is the measure that makes it the most difficult to meet the constraint
. The worst-case measure in this case is the risk-neutral measure
. In mathematical terms, the comparison of the likelihood ratios under the two hypotheses is expressed as follows. Define
which represents a Radon–Nikodym derivative. This derivative serves as the likelihood ratio associated with some measure
. The perfect hedging set then can be considered as the event.
Consider a test with hypotheses : and : Q, and let the rejection region be . The Neyman–Pearson Lemma states that the most powerful test satisfies the following: for some ,
the observation (sample) belongs to R;
the observation (sample) belongs to ;
(the observation (sample) belongs to R) = , where is a pre-fixed significance level.
The event E ensures that the hedging strategy satisfies the condition that the probability of covering the pay-off is at least . It identifies the scenarios where the likelihood ratio equals a critical level . In this context, the null hypothesis implies that achieving a perfect hedge is not possible, while the alternative hypothesis suggests that it is feasible to hedge the pay-off H.
Let
be the perfect hedge or risk-neutral hedge in the classical pricing problem (when
). Let
, which is a martingale under measure
, and
We express
using the martingale representation theorem. Given the assumption of a complete market, there exists a predictable process
such that
Having established all the necessary constructions, we proceed to present the final result in the form of a theorem.
Theorem 1. Let hedge be defined by the following equations: Proof. According to the definition of the hedge
, we have
Since
and
,
Under the martingale measure
, the probability of under-hedging, which is failing to meet the pay-off
H, is exactly
. Thus,
and
, defined by (8). By the results in
Lemma 1 and the construction of
, the initial capital
is minimized and satisfies (11). □
By construction, is equivalent to the changes in the significance level with respect to the movements in asset prices ( and ) in addition to . The changes in the probability , represented by and , can be considered as the correction terms to the hedges for . In the theorem, represents the risk-neutral hedges obtained in the classical approach of pricing. A is considered to be the shortfall amount that investors are willing to compromise. The partial hedges and are defined as the risk-neutral hedges adjusted for shortfall amount A with the correction terms.
5. Efficient Hedging with a Given Expected Loss
Partial hedging with a given probability provides the investor with a higher profit by allowing some probability of potential loss. However, the amount of loss cannot be known beforehand or controlled. Considering this problem, we can develop an approach that allows for hedging with a given expected loss based on Novikov’s approach. The goal of this problem is to find an optimal strategy in which the shortfall amount is given and equal to
c, illustrated by the equation below.
Assume that is the loss function and equal to , where (linear loss function), and the optimal strategy is represented by . In this particular setup of the loss function, the investor is risk-indifferent, and the risk of losing capital is neither magnified nor unconcerned.
Follmer and Leukert [
15] (see also [
16]) developed an approach that minimizes the expected shortfall amount under the constraint of smaller initial capital. The minimization problem is equivalent to the optimization problem of a modified contingent claim. In other words, the efficient hedge
coincides with the perfect hedge of a modified contingent claim
.
where
is the likelihood ratio or the Radon–Nikodym derivative and
is a variable that can be solved based on the expected shortfall amount. By combining the approaches of Foellmer and Leukert and Novikov, we can construct an efficient hedging price and an efficient hedging strategy. From the Novikov approach, we introduce a non-negative constant
c, which would be the expected capital loss. Similarly, we restrict the possible efficient hedging strategies to the following self-financing hedges set with respect to
c.
In the above set of hedging strategies, we utilize Foellmer and Leukert’s approach, replacing the pay-off
H with the modified contingent claim pay-off
.
By Novikov’s approach, the efficient hedging price is equivalent to the sum of the expected shortfall amount and the expected value of the modified contingent claim.
where
and
6. Partial Hedging with a Given Probability and Application to Life Insurance
We can extend partial hedging with a specified probability to risk management for insurance products, specifically in the case of equity-linked insurance contracts. Compared to traditional life or property insurance products, equity-linked insurance contracts are fairly new products. The premiums from equity-linked insurance contracts are invested partially or entirely in ordinary financial shares. The pay-off at maturity depends on the performance of the financial market, thus transferring the investment risk to the policyholder. We will use an equity-linked pure endowment insurance contract to construct the risk-neutral premium. In this type of insurance contract, the policyholder receives a payment if they survive to maturity; otherwise, the policyholder would not receive any benefit payment.
Let represent the remaining lifetime of an individual whose current age is X at the beginning of the contract. is defined on the stochastic basis , where the two probability measures P and are independent. By the standard assumption, the investment risks and mortality risks are independent of each other.
By using the previous work on exchange options, we can determine the risk-neutral premium. At maturity, the pay-off for an equity-linked pure endowment insurance contract is expressed by the following equation.
where
T is the maturity time of the contract. The chance of survival is illustrated by the addition of the indicator function. The indicator function is equal to 1 if the individual survives to or past the end of the contract and equal to 0 if the individual passes away before the contract ends. The risk-neutral premium of this type of insurance contract is given as
T is the standard actuarial notation of the survival probability of
T years for an individual currently at age
x. Note that the insurance market is incomplete, as mortality is not traded in a market, where a portfolio can be constructed to replicate the underlying asset’s cash flows. Brennand and Schwartz (see also [
17,
18]) determined an equilibrium price for an equity-linked insurance contract. In the equilibrium value, the investor will neither lose nor gain money. Following the approaches of Brennan and Schwartz (1976) [
4] and Melnikov and Nosrati (2017) [
19], we have the following equality:
The equality above provides a connection between the mortality risks from insurance and the investment risks from finance. The ratio of the partial hedging price and the risk-neutral price is the survival rate, as the partial hedging price is lower. From the survival rate with life tables, we can determine the age needed to attain the survival rate. This allows the insurance to tailor the contract to individuals at a specific age to reach the equilibrium between mortality risks and investment risks. In other words, the insurance company can balance out the investment risk and the mortality risk. The following sections include numerical examples to illustrate this concept.
8. Discussion
From the perspective of the prior study by Novikov, the present research advances the concept of controlled partial hedging by offering practical ways to manage the risk–reward balance. The application of partial hedging to life insurance, particularly equity-linked pure endowment contracts, demonstrates an approach to blending financial and mortality risks.
In the insurance industry, partial hedging introduces a way to integrate actuarial and financial risk management effectively. By linking survival probabilities with hedging costs, insurance companies can adjust their policyholder age requirements and policy terms to balance mortality risks with financial market exposure. This integration represents a shift from traditional actuarial approaches, where mortality and financial risks were often considered separately. The model presented here enables insurance companies to structure equity-linked contracts with tailored risk–reward profiles, making them more appealing to clients and financially sustainable for providers.
A possible future consideration is the application of partial hedging in multi-asset portfolios, which could involve more complex models that account for additional correlation structures and stochastic dependencies. Investigating such models may reveal further insights into the optimal hedging strategies across diverse asset classes, expanding the utility of these methods beyond equity-linked insurance products to other structured financial instruments. Furthermore, the age of selection is determined using Statistic Canada life tables. A future consideration would be to use stochastic mortalities (see [
22]) to determine the selection age of the equity-linked insurance policy.
While this approach works in theory, its application in real-world financial markets faces limitations. The market conditions often deviate from the assumptions of completeness, constant parameters, and frictionless trading, leading to challenges in implementation. Additionally, the partial hedging framework may be sensitive to the accuracy of the input data, such as volatility or correlation estimates, which are subject to estimation errors. The practical applicability is further constrained by the need for advanced computational resources, which may limit its adoption in the current fast-paced financial environment.