1. Introduction
Because of their major contribution to global climate change, there has been increased research to determine the best ways to reduce carbon emissions, which have been exponentially increasing due to the increased demand for energy [
1,
2,
3]. Although renewable energy systems are more environmentally friendly than traditional energy systems, two thirds of the world’s electricity is still generated using fossil fuel-based generation plants [
4,
5]; that is, coal, gas and oil-fired thermal power remain the main sources for electricity generation, especially in developing countries (e.g., China and India) [
6,
7]. Approximately 20% of the global electricity produced in 2016 was supplied by coal-fired power plants (CPP), with some developing countries having an even higher proportion [
8]; for example, coal-fired power plants supply more that 65% of China’s needs [
9]. Therefore, for sustainable social development, it is necessary to mitigate or control CPPs’ carbon emissions.
Research has shown that “hard-path” and “soft-path” approaches can be taken to mitigate carbon emissions [
10,
11]. “Hard-path” methods mainly focus on advanced clean coal technologies (CCT) such as integrated gasification combined cycles (IGCC), carbon capture and storage (CCS), ultra-supercritical technology (USC) and externally-fired combined cycle (EFCC) technologies [
12,
13,
14]. For example, Hoya and Fushimi evaluated the performance of advanced IGCC power generation systems with low-temperature gasifiers and gas cleaning and found that the lowest net thermal efficiency rose to 57.2% and the minimum carbon emission factors fell to 39.7 kg-CO
MWh [
15]. Kayal and Chakraborty designed and developed carbon-based metal organic framework (MOF) composite for CO
capture and concluded that the MAX-MIL composite was able to adsorb a greater quantity of CO
compared with the original methods [
16]. Even though these “hard-path” methods are highly efficient in reducing carbon emissions, commercial-scale applications are still extremely expensive [
17,
18], especially for developing countries, which tend to prefer “soft-path”, less-expensive solutions [
19,
20]. The “soft-path” approach focuses on policy controls or operations management methods for carbon emissions mitigation. For example, Cao and Xu investigated the effects of cap-and-trade policy (CTP) and low carbon subsidy policy (LCSP) on carbon emissions reduction and concluded that carbon emissions reductions were positively correlated with the carbon trading price, but not with low carbon subsidies [
21]. Shih and Frey developed a multi-objective chance-constrained optimization method under certainty to improve emission performance by adjusting coal blending ratios [
22]. Wang et al. proposed a multi-objective unit commitment approach to simulate the impacts of manifold uncertainty on system operation with emission concern and suggested operational insights for mixed generation systems [
23]. Xu et al. developed an equilibrium strategy based on a hydro-wind-thermal complementary system for carbon emission reduction and obtained some useful suggestions [
24]. Although such studies have gone some way to alleviating the human activity caused global climate change effects, the reality is still not satisfactory due to the complexity and uncertainty of human activities; thus, further improvements are necessary.
There has been increased research interest in the carbon emissions allowance allocation (CEAA) method to mitigate carbon emissions [
25,
26]. Cap and trade and carbon taxes have been the two most popular emissions reduction mechanisms to curb CPP carbon emissions [
27]. While cap and trade mechanisms are business friendly, as the trading price is determined by supply and demand, there is increased trading price uncertainty [
28]. While carbon tax mechanisms are simpler and easier to implement and the tax increases financial revenue [
27], which can be used to sponsoring of green projects such as renewable energy, there is no upper limit to the possible emissions reduction [
28]. By combining the advantages of these two mechanisms, a new cap and tax mechanism was developed to mitigate carbon emissions. As a key determinant for the CEAA strategy, the allocation strategy is crucial to ensure carbon emissions mitigation. In this paper, a combination of free and taxable allocation strategies under a carbon emissions cap is adopted for the carbon quota allocations. The free emissions allowances are used to meet the CPP basic operations, and the taxable emissions allowances are employed to meet further CPP development.
Previous CEAA studies have tended to consider only a single CPP participant. However, in actual production activities, carbon emissions mitigation involves both the CPP and the authority, which usually have conflicting targets. For example, the CPP generally has a profit objective, while the authority, as a representative of public benefits, generally has environmental protection as the main starting point; therefore, traditional optimization methods are not effective. The equilibrium strategy, which has been proven to be powerful in addressing such conflicts, has been widely used in many fields. For example, Liu et al. developed a computable general equilibrium (CGE) model to explore the impacts of a carbon tax on the socio-economic system and had some useful results [
29]. Tu et al. employed an equilibrium strategy to solve regional water resource allocation conflicts between different sub-areas under multiple uncertainties [
30]. Kardakos et al. proposed an equilibrium optimization method to address an optimal bidding strategy problem that considered the mutual interactions between the various stakeholders in the electricity market [
31]. The successful application of the equilibrium strategy in these areas motivated the use of this method in this paper to address the conflicts between the authority and CPPs to achieve regional sustainable development. However, as the equilibrium strategy is an abstract concept, a specific, quantitative method is needed to describe the situation. As bi-level programming has been proven to be the most efficient method for expressing equilibrium strategies and describing the interactions between multiple stakeholders, bi-level programming is integrated into the CEAA problem to determine the equilibrium between the authority and the CPPs.
Compared with previous studies, the equilibrium strategy established in this study, which integrates a bi-level multi-objective programming model, a carbon emissions allowance allocation method and uncertainty theory, has the ability to address the equilibrium between the authority and the CPPs, the conflict between economic development and environmental protection and the uncertainties simultaneously. The remainder of this paper is organized as follows.
Section 2 discusses the features of the CEAA problem in preparation for establishing the mathematical model. In
Section 3, a bi-level multi-objective mathematical model is built based on a real situation, after which in
Section 4, a case study is given to demonstrate the practicality and effectiveness of the proposed methodology.
Section 5 gives a detailed results analysis and in-depth discussion, and conclusions and future research are given in
Section 6.
2. Key Problem Statement
With a carbon emissions allowance allocation and a cap and tax mechanism, the CEAA problem is complex for both the authority and the CPPs.
As a public representative, the authority must ensure stable local economic development and mitigate the associated carbon emissions. However, the authority also has the power to develop the policies that must be implemented by the CPP if they wish to keep their power generation rights. However, the authority has an obligation to consider the actual CPP situation when making decisions to avoid non-sustainable CPP development or a cessation of operations, which could be harmful to stable economic development. Therefore, the authority divides the total carbon emissions into free emissions, which allow the CPP to meet its production and operation commitments and ensures fairness, and taxable emissions, which supplement the free emissions and can be used to regulate the market. Therefore, the authority pursues a balance between financial benefits and carbon emissions reduction by satisfying the CPPs’ basic rights and meeting the regional electricity needs.
According to the rational person hypothesis, the primary goal of the CPPs is to maximize profits while also considering emissions performance, boiler conditions, social responsibility and the component coal that can be purchased on the market. Therefore, as higher carbon emissions allowances mean higher production and higher profits, each CPP seeks to obtain as high a carbon emissions allowance as possible. However, as the authority seeks to mitigate carbon emissions, the CPPs that have better emissions performance are more competitive. Therefore, CPPs are allocated higher emissions quotas if they put some effort into improving the CPP emissions performance. This relationship between the authority and the CPPs for the CEAA problem is shown graphically in
Figure 1.
5. Results and Discussion
5.1. Results and Sensitivity Analysis
The collected data were input into the proposed model (i.e., Equation (
17)) and the solution approach run on MATLAB software, from which the optimal carbon emissions allowance allocation for the authority was determined.
5.1.1. Different Free Carbon Emission Levels
As the authority needs to strengthen the control over the free carbon emissions allocations, a single result is unsatisfactory; therefore, several scenarios are considered. To illustrate the practicality and validity of this method, as a representative situation,
Table 5 shows the results of the sensitivity analysis on the free carbon emission levels when
= 0.5 and
= 1. In this situation, for fairness, the authority’s attitude towards allocation satisfaction, was set at 0.5, and the carbon emissions reduction level was set at one, the most relaxed carbon emissions reduction attitude. It can be seen that in this situation, the authority earns 3.436 ×
RMB when
= 0.82, which is the lowest free emissions level.
Figure 3 illustrates the changes to the financial benefits for the authority (i.e.,
), the total carbon emissions (i.e.,
) in the region, each CPP’s profits (i.e.,
), the allocation satisfaction level (i.e.,
), the free emissions allocation allowance (
), the taxable emissions allocation allowance (
) and the carbon emissions allowance (
+
) against changing the free carbon emissions level. The financial benefits for the authority gradually increase, and the profits of each CPP decrease as the free carbon emissions level decreases. Further, to maximize profits, all CPPs strive to obtain a higher market share and finally reach equilibrium, at which point, all CPPs have used all their free carbon emission allowances and are seeking to obtain as high an allowance as possible from the authority. In addition, as the free emissions level decreases, the CPPs have lower free carbon emissions allowances and lower satisfactory degrees. From
Figure 3, it can be seen that the Huarun CPP remained the most profitable CPP under the different free emissions levels and the highest carbon emissions allowance, which included both the free and taxable emissions allowances. In addition, the Yancheng CPP profits were lower than the Xiaguan CPP profits, although they have roughly equivalent carbon emissions quotas. It was concluded that the Yancheng CPP may be detrimental to the sustainable development of the coal-fired power industry in this region. Therefore, suitable free carbon emissions level can achieve both stable economic development and a fair market environment.
5.1.2. Different Carbon Emission Reduction Levels
As the carbon emissions reduction level is an another important factor for carbon emissions mitigation by the authority, several scenarios were again considered under different
. As a representative example,
Table 6 shows the sensitivity analysis results for the carbon emissions reduction levels when
= 0.5 and
= 0.9 to verify the validity of the model. The carbon emissions allowance cap was divided into free and taxable emissions quotas and the free carbon emissions level set at 0.9. The results in
Table 6 show that the authority achieves a minimum of 2.43 ×
RMB when
= 0.82, which was the lowest carbon emissions reduction level.
Figure 4 shows the results for the comparative analysis under different carbon emissions reduction levels. From
Figure 4a, it can be seen that both the financial benefits and total carbon emissions decrease as the environmental protection constraints are tightened (i.e., changing
from one to its lowest level); however, the decrease in the carbon emissions ratio is larger than the decrease in the financial benefits. For example, when
= 0.94 is compared with
= 1, the financial benefit ratio decreases by 5.9% and the carbon emissions ratio decreases by 6.4%. Further, the ratios decrease by 6.4% and 6.8% when
= 0.88 and by 6.8% and 7.3% when
= 0.82 for the two factors. From this analysis, it was concluded that tightening the environmental protection constraints is more beneficial to sustainable development and that more relaxed environmental protection constraints cause more damage to sustainable development. Similar to the different free carbon emissions level scenarios, to maximize economic profits, each CPP is eager to gain a higher market share and eventually reaches equilibrium. In addition, it is clear that the CPP profits decrease with a decrease in the carbon emissions reduction level. The profits and free emissions allowance at the Huarun CPP are still the highest, and the Yancheng CPP is the lowest under the different carbon emissions reduction levels.
5.1.3. Different Allocation Satisfaction Levels
A fair market environment is conducive to regional sustainable development. In this paper, a satisfactory degree method is proposed to measure fairness. Similarly, several scenarios were conducted under different allocation satisfaction levels. As an example,
Table 7 shows the results of the sensitivity analysis for the allocation satisfaction levels when
= 0.9 and
= 1, from which it can be seen that the authority achieves a minimum of 2.96066 ×
RMB when
= 0.8, which is the lowest allocation satisfaction level.
Figure 5 illustrates the changes in the financial benefits (i.e.,
) for the authority and each CPP’s profits (i.e.,
) when the allocation satisfaction level changes. However, as can be seen, the allocation satisfaction does not significantly impact the financial benefits of the authority or the CPP profits. For example, when
= 0.5, the financial benefits are 2.96112 ×
RMB, and as
changes to 0.6, the financial benefits are 2.96081 ×
RMB, a decrease of only 0.011%. When
is set at 0.7 and 0.8, the ratio decreases only slightly by 0.004% and 0.001%. From
Figure 5, similar situations can be seen for each of the CPP profits.
5.2. Discussion
Based on the above results and analysis, the proposed method contributes to research on carbon emissions mitigation in the coal-fired power field and can assist authorities in establishing reasonable carbon emissions allowance allocation policies as the uncertain factors (coal characteristics, emissions factor, coal-power conversion coefficient, carbon emissions factor and procurement costs) are considered. The coal characteristics are uncertain due to the impact of the natural condition and the mining processes, and the uncertain emissions factor depends on the uncertain coal characteristics. The coal-power conversion coefficient and the carbon emissions factor are uncertain because of the uncertain combustion efficiencies. The procurement costs are uncertain because of the impact of price coordination and market fluctuations. At the same time, there are deviations in the collected data; that is, these uncertain parameters are influenced by both subjective and objective factors. There has been significant research conducted in dealing with such uncertainties. For example, Cheng et al. proposed an interval recourse liner programming (IRLP) to mitigate constraint violation problems in resources and environmental systems management (REM) under uncertainties [
42]. Huang et al. developed an inexact fuzzy stochastic chance constrained programming (IFSCCP) method to address various uncertainties in evacuation management problems [
43]. However, based on the actual background and characteristics of the CEAA problem in this paper, fuzzy theory was employed to fit reality and an expected value operator used to transform the fuzzy variables into corresponding expected values. Through this process, the results of the proposed method are more convincing.
In addition, the proposed method was shown to describe the interactive relationship between the authority and the CPPs effectively and to resolve the conflicts between economic development and environmental protection. Such situations are also found in other carbon emissions mitigation fields. For instance, there are similar interactive relationships between the authority and biomass power plants in the biomass power industry, in which there is also economic development and environmental protection conflicts. To mitigate these carbon emissions, authorities need to apply the appropriate CEAA strategy based on cap and tax mechanisms for biomass power plants, and the biomass power plants should have suitable biomass blending plans to achieve their required profits under the carbon quotas imposed by the authority.
5.3. Management Recommendations
Based on the above analysis and discussion, some management recommendations are given.
First, for regions that largely depend on CPP-generated electricity, a new cap and tax mechanism should be established to ensure the required environmental protection. Without such a mechanism, CPPs would arbitrarily emit carbon dioxide as they would lack the motivation to improve their emissions performances. Using the proposed methodology, the cap and tax mechanism is able to motivate CPPs to develop low carbon power generation. Further, under carbon emissions allowance allocation constraints, CPPs may be encouraged to improve their clean-energy technologies to decrease operating costs, which could further mitigate carbon emissions and gain higher profits.
Second, the authority can design suitable carbon emissions allowance allocation plans using the proposed method; that is, the authority can select the desired free carbon emissions levels and carbon emissions reductions levels based on the actual situation. Therefore, when using the proposed model, it is recommended that the authorities in developed regions set the lowest free carbon emissions level and the strictest carbon emissions reduction levels to encourage environmentally-friendly power generation. On the other hand, for developing regions, the authority can set relatively loose emissions reduction goals at the start to ensure steady local economic development. They can then continue to tighten the environmental protection parameter to aim for sustainable development.