A Generalised Model of Ground Lease Pricing
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Perpetual Usufruct—The Case of Poland
- (1)
- The ownership of land, buildings, and facilities. The owner of buildings or facilities is the lessee of the land under a long-term agreement and holds it as its owner without having to buy. In case the lease agreement expires or is canceled between the termination date, the lessee receives compensation equal to the value of their investment in the land. This solution is used in most of the analyzed countries (except for England Air Force Base, Louisiana, U.S., and Finland, but it refers only to industrial land).
- (2)
- The duration and the possibility of extending the lease contract. Agreements usually cover the period of between 50 and 99 years, e.g., Canberra in Australia, or an indefinite period, as seen in the Netherlands. Contracts that concern residential properties are generally longer than those for land used for commercial or industrial purposes. For example, in Sweden, residential lease agreements are signed for a period of at least 60 years, whereas those for other purposes cover a period of a minimum 20 years. In Finland, residential lease contracts are signed for a period of 50–60 years, whereas industrial lease contracts are 20–30 years. Sometimes, land lease agreements are created for shorter periods (20–30 years). This refers to the lease of land earmarked for some commercial uses (e.g., restaurants, smaller shopping and service centers, or car showrooms). Lease contracts can cover a much longer period, i.e., 200 or even 999 years. They are created with an extension option if, for example, the owner needs land for public purposes (e.g., Finland). They can also be extended automatically (the Netherlands, Israel, Austria, or Sweden) by the same number of years, half of the years of the original contract, or by another period.
- (3)
- Settlements for the investments in land. The landowner is usually not interested in the investment in it. They receive income in the form of a lease fee. In turn, the investment made by the lessee (user) should pay for itself before the termination of the contract. When the landowner takes over the buildings built by the lessee, the basis of settlement may be a compensation for the investment made calculated according to the market value or replacement value. Buildings may also be taken over without any compensation. For example, in Finland, in case of industrial buildings built by the land lessee. In Sweden, the lessor does not pay any compensation if a lease agreement concerns non-residential use and it contains a provision that no compensation is paid. In Israel, although buildings and other improvements cannot be the subject of separate ownership, most agreements specify that, in case a contract expires or is canceled before its termination date, the lessee has to receive compensation for the improvements. If the owner disclaims the lease before the termination date, they are usually obliged to pay compensation for taking over buildings and facilities prematurely. For example, the amount of compensation may be calculated as the difference between the market value of the developed property and the market value of the land.
- (4)
- The level and updating of a lease fee. Regulations in this respect vary across countries. For example, in Sweden, a lease fee is paid in the form of annual land rent. The fee is adjusted every 10 or 20 years. In Finland, a lessee pays a fee of 4–5% of the estimated market value of the land. The fee is updated every 30 years according to the increase in the market value of the land, whereas, in the following years, changes in the maintenance cost index are considered. Lease fees are usually paid on a quarterly basis. Lease contracts in which a lessee pays an initial fee are rare. In some countries (e.g., Israel, Australia, and New Zealand), there are both agreements with an initial fee and the ones without it. In Israel and the Netherlands, one may obtain a right of perpetual usufruct for the amount of the annual capitalized lease fee, but a lease fee may also be paid on a yearly basis.
3. Literature Review
4. Mandell’s Model
5. The Generalized Model
5.1. Owner’s Perspective
5.2. User’s Perspective
5.3. Range of Acceptable Leasing Rates
5.4. Perpetual Usufruct Payments
6. Simulations
- (1)
- expected average increase of the property’s price: 1 or 2% (i.e., );
- (2)
- duration of the contract: 15, 20, 25, 30, 35, 40, or 99 years (i.e., );
- (3)
- duration of the period, where the annual payments are fixed: 5 or 10 years (i.e., );
- (4)
- expected average increase in the lease rate and perpetual usufruct annual payment rate is equal to the increase in the property’s value (i.e., );
- (5)
- loan’s duration: 30 years (i.e., );
- (6)
- share of equity: from 0% (the whole financed by a loan), by 25, 50, 75, to 100% (no loan), i.e., ;
- (7)
- expected discount rate: 3.5 or 5% (i.e., );
- (8)
- annual effective interest rate for the loan: discount rate plus 0.5 pp. (i.e., , depending on );
- (9)
- initial payment rate for perpetual usufruct: 25% (i.e., ); and
- (10)
- annual payment rate for perpetual usufruct: 1% (i.e., ).
7. Conclusions
Author Contributions
Funding
Conflicts of Interest
Appendix A
Appendix A.1. Owner’s Perspective
Appendix A.2. User’s Perspective
Appendix A.3. Simulations Results
Lease Rate | Rate of Equity | Lease Duration (Years) | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
15 | 20 | 25 | 30 | 35 | 40 | 99 | ||
Min. (sale) | arbitrary | 2.55% | 2.55% | 2.55% | 2.55% | 2.55% | 2.55% | 2.55% |
Max. (purchase) | 0% | 8.91% | 7.07% | 5.98% | 5.26% | 4.76% | 4.38% | 3.00% |
25% | 8.76% | 6.95% | 5.88% | 5.17% | 4.68% | 4.31% | 2.95% | |
50% | 8.61% | 6.83% | 5.78% | 5.08% | 4.59% | 4.23% | 2.90% | |
75% | 8.45% | 6.71% | 5.68% | 4.99% | 4.51% | 4.16% | 2.85% | |
100% | 8.30% | 6.59% | 5.57% | 4.90% | 4.43% | 4.08% | 2.80% | |
Min. (p.u.) 1 | arbitrary | 3.08% | 2.65% | 2.39% | 2.23% | 2.11% | 2.02% | 1.70% |
Max. (p.u.) | arbitrary | 3.23% | 2.77% | 2.50% | 2.32% | 2.19% | 2.10% | 1.75% |
Lease Rate | Rate of Equity | Lease Duration (Years) | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
15 | 20 | 25 | 30 | 35 | 40 | 99 | ||
Min. (sale) | arbitrary | 2.59% | 2.61% | 2.60% | 2.61% | 2.60% | 2.61% | 2.61% |
Max. (purchase) | 0% | 9.06% | 7.24% | 6.10% | 5.39% | 4.86% | 4.49% | 3.07% |
25% | 8.90% | 7.11% | 5.99% | 5.29% | 4.77% | 4.41% | 3.02% | |
50% | 8.75% | 6.99% | 5.89% | 5.20% | 4.69% | 4.33% | 2.97% | |
75% | 8.59% | 6.87% | 5.79% | 5.11% | 4.61% | 4.26% | 2.91% | |
100% | 8.44% | 6.74% | 5.68% | 5.02% | 4.53% | 4.18% | 2.86% | |
Min. (p.u.) | arbitrary | 3.11% | 2.69% | 2.42% | 2.25% | 2.13% | 2.05% | 1.72% |
Max. (p.u.) | arbitrary | 3.26% | 2.81% | 2.52% | 2.35% | 2.21% | 2.12% | 1.77% |
Lease Rate | Rate of Equity | Lease Duration (Years) | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
15 | 20 | 25 | 30 | 35 | 40 | 99 | ||
Min. (sale) | arbitrary | 1.56% | 1.56% | 1.56% | 1.56% | 1.56% | 1.56% | 1.56% |
Max. (purchase) | 0% | 8.51% | 6.61% | 5.47% | 4.72% | 4.18% | 3.78% | 2.19% |
25% | 8.36% | 6.50% | 5.38% | 4.64% | 4.11% | 3.72% | 2.15% | |
50% | 8.22% | 6.38% | 5.29% | 4.56% | 4.04% | 3.65% | 2.11% | |
75% | 8.07% | 6.27% | 5.19% | 4.48% | 3.97% | 3.59% | 2.08% | |
100% | 7.93% | 6.16% | 5.10% | 4.40% | 3.90% | 3.52% | 2.04% | |
Min. (p.u.) | arbitrary | 2.98% | 2.54% | 2.27% | 2.10% | 1.97% | 1.88% | 1.51% |
Max. (p.u.) | arbitrary | 3.13% | 2.65% | 2.37% | 2.18% | 2.05% | 1.95% | 1.55% |
Lease Rate | Rate of Equity | Lease Duration (Years) | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
15 | 20 | 25 | 30 | 35 | 40 | 99 | ||
Min. (sale) | arbitrary | 1.61% | 1.63% | 1.62% | 1.63% | 1.62% | 1.63% | 1.63% |
Max. (purchase) | 0% | 8.78% | 6.92% | 5.69% | 4.94% | 4.36% | 3.96% | 2.29% |
25% | 8.63% | 6.80% | 5.59% | 4.86% | 4.28% | 3.90% | 2.25% | |
50% | 8.48% | 6.69% | 5.49% | 4.77% | 4.21% | 3.83% | 2.21% | |
75% | 8.33% | 6.57% | 5.40% | 4.69% | 4.13% | 3.76% | 2.18% | |
100% | 8.18% | 6.45% | 5.30% | 4.61% | 4.06% | 3.69% | 2.14% | |
Min. (p.u.) | arbitrary | 3.05% | 2.61% | 2.32% | 2.15% | 2.02% | 1.92% | 1.53% |
Max. (p.u.) | arbitrary | 3.20% | 2.73% | 2.42% | 2.24% | 2.09% | 1.99% | 1.57% |
Lease Rate | Rate of Equity | Lease Duration (Years) | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
15 | 20 | 25 | 30 | 35 | 40 | 99 | ||
Min. (sale) | arbitrary | 4.08% | 4.08% | 4.08% | 4.08% | 4.08% | 4.08% | 4.08% |
Max. (purchase) | 0% | 9.90% | 8.09% | 7.04% | 6.35% | 5.88% | 5.54% | 4.47% |
25% | 9.73% | 7.96% | 6.92% | 6.25% | 5.78% | 5.45% | 4.39% | |
50% | 9.57% | 7.82% | 6.80% | 6.14% | 5.68% | 5.36% | 4.32% | |
75% | 9.40% | 7.68% | 6.68% | 6.03% | 5.58% | 5.26% | 4.24% | |
100% | 9.23% | 7.55% | 6.56% | 5.92% | 5.49% | 5.17% | 4.17% | |
Min. (p.u.) | arbitrary | 3.31% | 2.89% | 2.64% | 2.48% | 2.37% | 2.29% | 2.04% |
Max. (p.u.) | arbitrary | 3.47% | 3.02% | 2.76% | 2.59% | 2.47% | 2.39% | 2.12% |
Lease Rate | Rate of Equity | Lease Duration (Years) | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
15 | 20 | 25 | 30 | 35 | 40 | 99 | ||
Min. (sale) | arbitrary | 4.14% | 4.17% | 4.16% | 4.17% | 4.16% | 4.17% | 4.17% |
Max. (purchase) | 0% | 10.06% | 8.27% | 7.17% | 6.49% | 6.00% | 5.67% | 4.57% |
25% | 9.89% | 8.14% | 7.05% | 6.39% | 5.90% | 5.57% | 4.49% | |
50% | 9.72% | 8.00% | 6.93% | 6.28% | 5.80% | 5.48% | 4.41% | |
75% | 9.55% | 7.86% | 6.81% | 6.17% | 5.70% | 5.38% | 4.34% | |
100% | 9.38% | 7.72% | 6.69% | 6.06% | 5.60% | 5.29% | 4.26% | |
Min. (p.u.) | arbitrary | 3.35% | 2.93% | 2.67% | 2.51% | 2.40% | 2.32% | 2.06% |
Max. (p.u.) | arbitrary | 3.52% | 3.07% | 2.79% | 2.62% | 2.50% | 2.42% | 2.14% |
Lease Rate | Rate of Equity | Lease Duration (Years) | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
15 | 20 | 25 | 30 | 35 | 40 | 99 | ||
Min. (sale) | arbitrary | 3.12% | 3.12% | 3.12% | 3.12% | 3.12% | 3.12% | 3.12% |
Max. (purchase) | 0% | 9.48% | 7.59% | 6.48% | 5.75% | 5.24% | 4.87% | 3.54% |
25% | 9.32% | 7.47% | 6.37% | 5.66% | 5.15% | 4.79% | 3.48% | |
50% | 9.16% | 7.34% | 6.26% | 5.56% | 5.07% | 4.70% | 3.42% | |
75% | 9.00% | 7.21% | 6.15% | 5.46% | 4.98% | 4.62% | 3.36% | |
100% | 8.84% | 7.08% | 6.05% | 5.36% | 4.89% | 4.54% | 3.30% | |
Min. (p.u.) | arbitrary | 3.21% | 2.77% | 2.51% | 2.34% | 2.22% | 2.14% | 1.83% |
Max. (p.u.) | arbitrary | 3.37% | 2.90% | 2.62% | 2.44% | 2.31% | 2.22% | 1.89% |
Lease Rate | Rate of Equity | Lease Duration (Years) | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
15 | 20 | 25 | 30 | 35 | 40 | 99 | ||
Min. (sale) | arbitrary | 3.22% | 3.26% | 3.24% | 3.26% | 3.25% | 3.26% | 3.26% |
Max. (purchase) | 0% | 9.78% | 7.94% | 6.73% | 6.02% | 5.46% | 5.09% | 3.70% |
25% | 9.62% | 7.81% | 6.62% | 5.91% | 5.37% | 5.01% | 3.64% | |
50% | 9.45% | 7.67% | 6.51% | 5.81% | 5.28% | 4.92% | 3.58% | |
75% | 9.29% | 7.54% | 6.39% | 5.71% | 5.18% | 4.83% | 3.52% | |
100% | 9.12% | 7.41% | 6.28% | 5.61% | 5.09% | 4.75% | 3.45% | |
Min. (p.u.) | arbitrary | 3.28% | 2.85% | 2.57% | 2.40% | 2.27% | 2.19% | 1.86% |
Max. (p.u.) | arbitrary | 3.45% | 2.99% | 2.68% | 2.50% | 2.36% | 2.27% | 1.93% |
References
- Gross, M.; Źróbek, R. Good governance in some public real estate management systems. Land Use Policy 2015, 49, 352–364. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Trojanek, M. Strategic municipal real estate management. J. Int. Stud. 2015, 8, 9–17. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Bilan, Y.; Zos-Kior, M.; Nitsenko, V.; Sinelnikau, U.; Ilin, V. Social component in sustainable management of land resources. J. Secur. Sustain. Issues 2017, 7, 489–499. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ploeger, H.; Bounjouh, H. The Dutch urban ground lease: A valuable tool for land policy? Land Use Policy 2017, 63, 78–85. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kaganova, O.; Telgarsky, J. Management of capital assets by local governments: An assessment and benchmarking survey. Int. J. Strateg. Prop. Manag. 2018, 22, 143–156. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yang, Z.; Ren, R.; Liu, H.; Zhang, H. Land leasing and local government behaviour in China: Evidence from Beijing. Urban Stud. 2015, 52, 841–856. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Adeniyi, O.; Perera, S.; Collins, A. Review of finance and investment in disaster resilience in the built environment. Int. J. Strateg. Prop. Manag. 2016, 20, 224–238. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gerber, J.D.; Nahrath, S.; Hartmann, T. The strategic use of time-limited property rights in land-use planning: Evidence from Switzerland. Environ. Plan. A 2017, 49, 1684–1703. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Löhr, D. Sustainable housing: A ground lease partnership model. Land Use Policy 2017, 60, 281–286. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Tyvimaa, T.; Gibler, K.M.; Zahirovic-Herbert, V. The effect of ground leases on house prices in Helsinki. J. Hous. Built Environ. 2015, 30, 451–470. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Trojanek, M. Gospodarowanie Nieruchomościami w Gminach w Aspekcie Ich Dochodowości; Wydawnictwo Uniwersytetu Ekonomicznego w Poznaniu: Poznań, Poland, 2015; ISBN 9788374178556. [Google Scholar]
- Mandell, S. Ground Lease & Local Property Taxes. Ph.D. Thesis, Royal Institute of Technology, Stockholm, Sweden, 2001. [Google Scholar]
- Sejm Rzyczypospolitej Polskiej. Real Estate Management Act; University of Warsaw Journal of Comparative Law: Warsaw, Poland, 1997. [Google Scholar]
- Sejm Rzyczypospolitej Polskiej. Civil Code; University of Warsaw Journal of Comparative Law: Warsaw, Poland, 1964. [Google Scholar]
- Sejm Rzyczypospolitej Polskiej. Law on the Economy of Land in Cities and Settlements; University of Warsaw Journal of Comparative Law: Warsaw, Poland, 1961. [Google Scholar]
- Winiarz, J. Użytkowanie Wieczyste; Instytut Nauk Prawniczych PAN: Warszawa, Poland, 1967. [Google Scholar]
- Truszkiewicz, Z. Użytkowanie Wieczyste. Zagadnienia Konstrukcyjne; Zakamycze Kantor Wydawniczy: Kraków, Poland, 2006. [Google Scholar]
- Głuszak, M. Użytkowanie wieczyste w kontekście rozwiązań stosowanych w wybranych krajach europejskich. Świat Nieruchomości 2008, 68, 28–31. [Google Scholar]
- Nystrom, S.L. Risk and time in a land lease economy. In Proceedings of the XXX FIG General Assembly; Hong Kong, 13–17 May 2007; pp. 1–27. [Google Scholar]
- Kokot, S. Ekonomiczne Zagadnienia Użytkowania Wieczystego w Gospodarce Nieruchomościami Gmin. Studium Diagnostyczno-Statystyczne na Przykładzie Gmin Województwa Zachodniopomorskiego; Wydawnictwo Uniwersytetu Szczecińskiego: Szczecin, Poland, 2009; ISBN 978-83-7241-741-1. [Google Scholar]
- Balawejder, M.; Buśko, M.; Cellmer, R.; Juchniewicz-Piotrowska, K.; Leń, P.; Mika, M.; Szczepankowska, K.; Wójciak, E.; Wójcik-Leń, J.; Źróbek, S.; et al. Aktualne Problemy Gospodarki Nieruchomościami w Polsce na tle Przemian Organizacyjno-Prawnych; Wyższa Szk. Inżynieryjno-Ekonomiczna: Rzeszów, Poland, 2014; ISBN 978-83-60507-20-9. [Google Scholar]
- Long, M.S. Leasing and the cost of capital. J. Financ. Quant. Anal. 1977, 12, 579–586. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Lewis, C.M.; Schallheim, J.S. Are debt and leases substitutes? J. Financ. 1992, 27, 497–511. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yan, A. Leasing and debt financing: Substututes or complements? J. Financ. Quant. Anal. 2006, 41, 709–731. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Liu, C.H.; Liu, P.; Zhang, Z. Real assets, liquidation value and choice of financing. Real Estate Econ. 2016, 1–31. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Clapham, E.; Gunnelin, Å. Rental Expectations and the term structure of lease rates. Real Estate Econ. 2003, 31, 647–670. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Lally, M.; Randal, J. Ground rental rates and ratchet clauses. Account. Financ. 2004, 44, 187–202. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Fallis, G. Rent control: The citizen, the market, and the state. J. Real Estate Financ. Econ. 1988, 1, 309–320. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mooradian, R.M.; Yang, S.X. Commercial real estate valuation, development and occupancy. Real Estate Econ. 2002, 30, 293–315. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Özdilek, Ü. Property price separation between land and building components. J. Real Estate Res. 2016, 38, 205–228. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Pope, A.; Gallimore, P.; Shi, S. Leasehold Property and Investor Risk Misestimation. In Proceedings of the 22nd Annual PRRES Conference, Sunshine Coast, Queensland, Australia, 17–20 January 2016. [Google Scholar]
- Rabbani, M.; Shadab, S.G.; Gaeini, Z.; Rafiei, H.; Dolatkhah, M. Rent pricing decision support mathematical model for finance leases under effective risks. J. Eng. Manag. Compet. 2015, 5, 3–11. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sevelka, T. Ground leases: Rent reset valuation issues. Appraisal J. 2011, 79, 314–326. [Google Scholar]
- Yoshida, J.; Seko, M.; Sumita, K. The rent term premium for cancellable leases. J. Real Estate Financ. Econ. 2016, 52, 480–511. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Benjamin, J.D.; Chinloy, P. The structure of a retail lease. J. Real Estate Res. 2004, 26, 223–236. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Capozza, D.R.; Sick, G.A. Valuing long-term leases: The option to redevelop. J. Real Estate Financ. Econ. 1991, 4, 209–223. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dale-Johnson, D. Long-term ground leases, the redevelopment option and contract incentives. Real Estate Econ. 2001, 29, 451–484. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Halim, N.A. A Validation of profit sharing ratio determination mathematical model for Islamic hire-purchase contract. Appl. Math. Sci. 2013, 7, 2035–2046. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- McCann, P.; Ward, C. Real estate rental payments: Application of stock-inventory modeling. J. Real Estate Financ. Econ. 2004, 28, 273–292. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Stanton, R.; Wallace, N. An empirical test of a contingent claims lease valuation model. J. Real Estate Res. 2009, 31, 1–26. [Google Scholar]
- Steele, A. Difference equation solutions to the valuation of lease. J. Financ. Quant. Anal. 1984, 19, 311–328. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wheaton, W.C. Percentage rent in retail leasing: The alignment of landlord—Tenant interests. Real Estate Econ. 2000, 28, 185–204. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Walters, M.; Kent, P. Institutional economics and property strata title—A survey and case study. J. Prop. Res. 2000, 17, 221–240. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Guntermann, K.L.; Thomas, G. Parcel size, location and commercial land values. J. Real Estate Res. 2005, 27, 343–354. [Google Scholar]
- Tian, L. Impacts of transport projects on residential property values in China: Evidence from two projects in Guangzhou. J. Prop. Res. 2006, 23, 347–365. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kaganova, O.; Akmatov, A.; Undeland, C. Introducing more transparent and efficient land management in post-socialist cities: Lessons from Kyrgyzstan. Int. J. Strateg. Prop. Manag. 2008, 12, 161–181. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gholipour, H.; Lean, H. Ripple effect in regional housing and land markets in Iran: Implications for portfolio diversification. Int. J. Strateg. Prop. Manag. 2017, 21, 331–345. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Guarino, D.; Chehrazi, C.; Bohl, B.A. Ground lease provisions—A case study for leasehold valuation. Apprais. J. 2014, 82, 123–132. [Google Scholar]
- Irumba, R. An empirical examination of the effects of land tenure on housing values in Kampala, Uganda. Int. J. Hous. Mark. Anal. 2015, 8, 359–374. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Jefferies, R.L. Valuing ground rentals—Modelling the land value percentage rate. In Proceedings of the 11th Annual Conference of the Pacific Rim Real Estate Society, The University of Melbourne, Victoria, Australia, 23–26 January 2005. [Google Scholar]
- Jefferies, R.L. Developing a Ground Rental ‘Indifference’ Valuation Model; Commerce Division, Discussion Paper No 102; Lincoln University: Canterbury, New Zealand, 2005. [Google Scholar]
- Mandell, S. Lessor and lessee perspectives on ground lease pricing. J. Prop. Res. 2002, 19, 145–157. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Trybusz, A. Wartościowy wymiar dzierżawy wieloletniej terenów zurbanizowanych. Acta Acad. Agric. Tech. Olstenensis Geodaesia Ruris Regul. 1993, 24, 81–91. [Google Scholar]
- Jefferies, R.L. An equilibrium ground rental valuation model. In Proceedings of the European Real-Estate Association/American Real-Estate and Urban Economics Association Annual Summer Meeting, Maastricht, The Netherlands, 10–13 June 1998. [Google Scholar]
- Brown, G.R. Estimating effective rents. J. Prop. Financ. 1995, 6, 33–42. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Feature | Perpetual Usufruct | Perpetual Lease | Long-Term Lease |
---|---|---|---|
Ownership of buildings | Perpetual usufructor | Lessee | Lessor (If the lessee built the building, they could claim for reimbursement) |
Duration | 40–99 years | Depending on the country, e.g., 20–30 years, 50–99 years, 200 or 999 years | No longer than 30 years |
Possibility of extension | For the next 40–99 years | Various possibilities, depending on the contract | Various possibilities, depending on the contract. A lease concluded for a period longer than 30 years is treated as a lease concluded for an indefinite period, then termination at any moment is possible. |
Method of the settlement of expenditures incurred on the ground | Remuneration defined as the market value of buildings and other equipment, and if, due to the type of real estate, market value cannot be determined, the replacement value is determined. | Compensation calculated as the difference between the market value of developed land and the value of the land without buildings | By default, without reimbursement of expenditure on the subject of the lease. Other arrangements must be included in the contract. |
The rules of setting the fee/rent | First fee Annual fees as a fixed percentage of the market value of the land. | There are contracts in which the first fee is established. Most usually the rent is a constant percentage of the current market value of the land. Additional fees are often added to the basic rent. | Based on the rental rates of similar land properties in a parametric way as the percentage of market value through negotiations (arrangements) between the owner and the lessee. |
The amount of the fee/rent | Differentiation according to the purpose | Differentiation according to purpose, location, form of the ownership (public or private) | Differentiation according to purpose, location, form of the ownership (public or private) |
Adjusting the fee/rent | Not more often than once every three years provided that the market value of the property has increased. | Periodically update every 3 to 4 years to adjust to market rent. | As claimed in the contract, e.g., in correspondence with the CPI. |
Preemption | For perpetual usufructor | To the lessee | Not present |
Determining the way of using the land and the duration of development | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Law established on land owned by | State Treasury or local government units | Any private or public subject | Any private or public subject |
© 2018 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Trojanek, M.; Anholcer, M.; Banaitis, A.; Trojanek, R. A Generalised Model of Ground Lease Pricing. Sustainability 2018, 10, 3203. https://doi.org/10.3390/su10093203
Trojanek M, Anholcer M, Banaitis A, Trojanek R. A Generalised Model of Ground Lease Pricing. Sustainability. 2018; 10(9):3203. https://doi.org/10.3390/su10093203
Chicago/Turabian StyleTrojanek, Maria, Marcin Anholcer, Audrius Banaitis, and Radoslaw Trojanek. 2018. "A Generalised Model of Ground Lease Pricing" Sustainability 10, no. 9: 3203. https://doi.org/10.3390/su10093203
APA StyleTrojanek, M., Anholcer, M., Banaitis, A., & Trojanek, R. (2018). A Generalised Model of Ground Lease Pricing. Sustainability, 10(9), 3203. https://doi.org/10.3390/su10093203