Next Article in Journal
Ballistic Impact Resistance of UHPC Plates Made with Hybrid Fibers and Low Binder Content
Previous Article in Journal
Unpacking B Corps’ Impact on Sustainable Development: An Analysis from Structuration Theory
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Review

Key Issues and Technical Applications in the Study of Power Markets as the System Adapts to the New Power System in China

1
Beijing Key Laboratory of New Energy and Low-Carbon Development, School of Economics and Management, North China Electric Power University, Beijing 102206, China
2
The State Key Laboratory of Power Transmission Equipment & System Security and New Technology, School of Electrical Engineering, Chongqing University, Chongqing 400044, China
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2021, 13(23), 13409; https://doi.org/10.3390/su132313409
Submission received: 19 October 2021 / Revised: 30 November 2021 / Accepted: 1 December 2021 / Published: 3 December 2021
(This article belongs to the Topic Artificial Intelligence and Sustainable Energy Systems)

Abstract

:
To reach the “30·60” decarbonization target (where carbon emissions start declining in 2030 and reach net zero in 2060), China is restructuring its power system to a new energy-based one. Given this new situation, this paper reviews previous studies on the power market and highlights key issues for future research as we seek to adapt to the new power system (NPS). Based on a systematic literature review, papers on the operational efficiency of the power market, participants’ bidding strategies and market supervision were identified. In a further step, papers with high relevance were analyzed in more detail. Then, key studies that focused on market trading under China’s new power system were picked out for further discussion. New studies were searched for that pertained to new energy mechanisms and bidding, the transition from coal-fired power, flexible resources and the technical applications of simulations. The quantitative analysis supports the construction of a basic paradigm for the study of power markets that is suitable for the new power system. Finally, the theoretical basis and application suggestions for power market simulations are introduced. This study summarized the existing research on the power market and further explored the key issues relating to the power market as it adapts to the NPS, hoping to inspire better research into China’s power sector, and promote safe, low-carbon, and sustainable development in China’s power industry.

1. Introduction

The reform of a power system is a major measure and an important part of China’s energy restructuring. Since the second round of the electricity reform that was launched in 2015, China’s power market has been further liberalized [1]. Meanwhile, the Chinese government has pledged to halt further CO2 emissions by 2030 and become carbon neutral by 2060 [2]. This requires higher levels of sustainable development in the power system. In recent years, China has been accelerating the replacement of fossil fuels. The proportion of new energy in primary energy consumption continues to rise. Renewable energy power output reached 2.2 trillion kilowatt-hours in 2020, accounting for 29.5% of national electricity consumption. China has fulfilled its commitment that non-fossil energy consumption must account for at least 15% of the primary energy consumption by 2020 as scheduled [3]. In March 2021, China’s Central Financial and Economic Affairs Commission called for the building of a new power system (NPS) with new energy as the main source. This government directive is vital to the power industry’s direction of development. Against this background, it is particularly important to study the new power system and the power market trading systems that feature a high proportion of renewable energy.
The new power system, compared with traditional power systems, functions in new industrial models. Every part of the power system, including power generation, grid operation, and power load control and energy storage, is changing. On the power supply side, renewable energy will gradually become the main source of electricity generation. On the consumption side, many prosumers are emerging. With regard to grid operation, large-sized grids still dominate, while multiple forms of grids will coexist. From the perspective of the whole system, the operating mechanism and balancing mode will undergo profound changes. The new power system is a clean and low-carbon, safe and controllable, flexible and efficient, intelligent and friendly, open and interactive system. The change of the power market will follow these trends.
At present, China’s power market is based on the provincial power market, and power trading is based on medium- and long-term contracts. A spot trading pilot for power is being promoted in the provincial market. New energy power generation enterprises have priority clearance rights in some provinces. That means that they are allowed to sell electricity directly at the volume that they bid, or that they can even sell power without applying for trading volume and prices before the transaction. Their power output will be bought at market prices without any quoting before the trade. Meanwhile, researchers are accelerating the search for strategies to promote regional power markets, which can prompt new energy companies to participate further in the market.
In terms of thermal power, the utilization hours of traditional coal power units are declining as the proportion of new energy is rising [4]. Government requirements for carbon emission reduction are also squeezing the living space of thermal power, as burning clean coal will surely make it more expensive. At present, China’s coal-electric installation accounts for about 50% of the power system. Its survival is not only related to the development of the power system, but also related to the social economy and people’s livelihoods. We need to pay enough attention to the survival of thermal power. Problems also exist for new energy and the flexible resources that are participating in the power market. The value of flexible resources has not been clarified, and there is no corresponding market mechanism to ensure that large quantities of electricity generated from renewable energy resources can be consumed at market prices. The market mechanisms of auxiliary services also needs to be improved urgently.
Due to the two-track characteristics of China’s power market, with both government planning and active markets, a series of issues concerning market operation and convergence are emerging, including the disposal of imbalanced funds [5,6], power market supervision/market power testing [7,8,9], demand response [10], renewable energy participating in the electricity market [11], the synergy between the electricity market and the carbon market, and the construction of future financial markets for power and market mechanisms for standby capacity. There is no mature international experience that can be drawn on that would help solve these problems.
The goal of this systematic review is to find solutions to develop the Chinese power market, combining China’s actual situation with successful foreign experience in power market construction and operation. Therefore, a basic paradigm for the study of power markets is identified by analyzing primary studies that are related to issues on market entities and operational mechanisms. Then, key issues pertaining to power market construction as it relates to China’s new power system (NPS) are discussed. To achieve these objectives, we conducted the research guided by the following questions:
1
What are the hot topics in primary studies regarding the construction and operation of power markets, and how do these topics interconnect with each other?
2
What are the key issues in the study of power markets as the system seeks to adapt to the NPS, which will feature a high proportion of new energy?
3
What is the basic paradigm for the study of power markets that would be suitable for the NPS?
4
Which theoretical basis can help simulate the power market to further research into power market mechanisms under the NPS?
5
From which dimensions should simulation modeling be established and how should researchers set related parameters?
The review is structured as follows. Section 2 describes the methodology. Section 3 introduces the analysis of general issues that concern researchers in the study of power markets according to primary research. Section 4 and Section 5 discuss key points related to the NPS power market from both theoretical and practical perspectives. In Section 4, key issues and basic paradigm for studying the power market under the NPS are presented, while specific suggestions for the applications of power market simulations are provided in Section 5. Section 6 gives the conclusions and implications.

2. Methodology

The systematic literature review (SLR) framework [12] is adopted in this work to identify, evaluate, interpret and describe the existing body of knowledge on power markets. We focus especially on the operation and supervision of the power market and the bidding strategies adopted by market participants that have caught the most attention. This study follows PRISMA guidance [13] for articles so that we can formulate robust and reproducible research. Figure 1 illustrates the design and logical framework of the respective literature review. The research questions have been outlined in Section 1.
We carried out the search process in five steps, including identifying the information sources, defining the eligibility criteria, composing the search strategy and selection processes, which aims to present unbiased, rigorous, and auditable results.
Step 1: Classify the search strings groups and identify the information sources.
This review has searched for both previous studies of the power market and new studies that show how research is adapting to the NPS, focusing on the research objectives and main research questions. Older studies on the power market were searched for with three groups of strings, including “power marker operation”, “bidding strategy” and “power market supervision”. New studies were searched for with four groups of strings with terms that include “high renewable energy”, “coal-fired power units”, “flexible resources” and “technical application”. The search criteria groups are shown in Figure 2.
Meanwhile, relevant databases that could be searched were also determined in this stage. We collected literature primarily from Web of Science, Elsevier, Google Scholar and CNKI (China National Knowledge Infrastructure). Other websites of authoritative research institutions that we used included the National Renewable Energy Laboratory and the Lawrence Berkeley National Laboratory. Collectively, these databases covered the main published papers/reports, unpublished manuscripts and conference papers (full-text access) that focused on the power markets of China and foreign countries.
Step 2: Set eligibility criteria for inclusion and exclusion of identified papers.
Eligibility criteria were determined in this phase to exclude ineligible studies from this review. There were several standards for studies to be included or excluded:
  • Papers should be in social sciences, business and economics, energy, or relative fields.
  • The title or subject must be strictly matched with the search strings. For example, papers that focused on storage efficiency in the power market [14] could be found when we searched for “power market operation efficiency”. Alternatively, articles that used experimental methods with neural networks [15] could also be found when we searched for “experimental economics”. These kinds of articles should be excluded.
  • Papers or reports must be written in English or Chinese. Literature in other languages was excluded in this review.
  • English articles must be published between 1980 and 2021 (access in July 2021) and Chinese articles must be published between 2000 and 2021.
  • Articles must have at least one keyword in the title or abstract, or cover the topic in the full article.
Step 3: Search and export the studies on power markets.
Based on the search criteria groups in Figure 2, suitable combinations of Boolean variables, such as “AND”, “OR”, and “NOT”, were employed to find the suitable literature. Because there are a range of topics that pertain to the power market, which has been studied extensively, “precise search” was used during the search process. The rankings of the literature were based on their relevance to the strings, which is helpful for further selection. Then, the identified studies were exported for deduplication in Step 4. The detailed search processes are as follows:
Firstly, papers published in refereed journals were searched for using the “Power Market Operation” criteria, which resulted in 1023 primary papers being selected from the business and economics fields from the Web of Science. With the same search strings, 411 papers were found in Elsevier, and 307 papers were found in the CNKI.
Secondly, the term “Bidding strategy”, searched for in Web of Science, resulted in 896 papers that were indexed in the fields of business and economics. A further 1460 papers were found in the field of economics and energy in Elsevier, while 177 papers were identified in the CNKI, which was much lower than the number of that in the English databases.
Thirdly, studies on “power market supervision” were searched for using the strings. In this step, 180 papers were found in Web of Science, and, of these, 176 papers satisfied the inclusion criteria. Only three of 72 papers were selected from Elsevier, however. We found 121 articles that were published in the Chinese database.
Then, new studies regarding renewable energy, coal-fired power units, and flexible resources and “technical applications” were searched for using the same method. As a result, 187, 54, 132 and 51 of them were identified in Web of Science, respectively, while 13, 2, 2 and 48 of them were selected in Elsevier, and 18, 5, 5 and 66 of them were identified in CNKI. All eligible papers were exported for further deduplication.
Step 4: Remove duplicates of searched papers.
Because the search process was carried out using different groups of strings, Citespace [16] was used to remove the duplicates in this review. We removed 189 previous studies in this phase according to the names of the exported .txt files of all of the suitable literature.
Step 5: Choosing eligible and relevant studies.
With the assistance of the relevance ranking function in the databases, the last pages with less relevant articles were excluded from further selection. After selecting the most relevant articles, we screened their titles, abstracts, and keywords. The illegible papers were excluded based on the inclusion and exclusion criteria. Then, we further read the conclusion and implications to identify the most important pieces of literature. Finally, through careful reading of the full text, we used the “snowballing” method to find articles that were not identified in the search. This meant that we found a wide range of literature. We removed 194 articles that were duplicates. The screening led to the exclusion of 4256 publications that did not meet the eligibility criteria. There were 893 old studies and 232 new studies that were further analyzed. Finally, a total of 170 studies were included in the review. To express the search process more clearly, the search strategy flow is shown in Figure 3.
After reviewing research hotspots and solutions of power markets around the world, general issues in the study of power markets were summarized. Then key issues in the study of power markets as it pertains NPS were put forward. This involves mechanisms and strategies for renewable energy, the survival and transformation of coal-fired power plants, and the value realization for flexible resources. After theoretical analysis, technical applications of experimental economics and agent-based computational economics in the study of NPS as it relates to the power market are presented. Further, simulation and parameters in terms of power system, power market and market participants are implemented.

3. Key Issues and the Basic Paradigm of Research into New Power Systems in the Power Market

After merging and splitting the spot sales and future trading markets [17], the Nordic power market finally grew into a situation where financial markets for power and spot trading complemented each other. Following the NETA [18] (New Electricity Trading Arrangements) and the BETTA [18] (British Electricity Trading and Transmission Arrangements), the UK has gradually liberalized the market for large and small industrial users and achieved efficient cross-border trading of electricity. With a high proportion of nuclear power and relatively low standard electricity prices, France has relevant experience in regulating the market pricing mechanisms that are adapted to a high proportion of nuclear power. In addition, issues related to electricity markets in Australia [19], California [20], Brazil [21], New Zealand [22] and Germany [23], have also been hotly debated in academia. It can be seen that the construction of electric power markets varies from country to country, due to the unique characteristics of power systems that results from different national conditions.
At present, China’s power market is constructed around the provincial electricity energy market, with power transactions relying on medium- and long-term contracts. Research on China’s power market is focused on the spot trading of electricity, and mainly revolves around the design of spot market price mechanisms, the bidding games of market subjects, and the interface mechanism between spot trading, medium- and long-term contracts, and auxiliary services. The further development of the power selling side, with energy storage equipment operators and other emerging entities participating in the electric sector and auxiliary services market, is also attracting the attention of scholars. Some other emerging hot research issues include demand response prices or incentives, power financial markets, electricity retail market prices and package design, as well as market risk and market assessment.

3.1. General Issues in the Study of Power Markets

A healthy power market depends on sound market mechanisms, competitive market subjects and strong market supervision. A large amount of research and practice has therefore been carried out on the operational efficiency of the power market, market subject strategies and market supervision and evaluation. Detailed research issues are shown in Figure 4.

3.1.1. Operational Efficiency of the Power Market

This part reviewed literature which studied market mechanisms or operational efficiency. Therefore, such papers that studied energy efficiency [24] or the operational efficiency of power plants [25] in a market were excluded. After the selection and evaluation of search results with “power market operation efficiency” strings, only 70 papers in the databases corresponded tightly with this topic. In addition, five reports were added into the pool for further analysis.
Around the time of the first power system reform in China, the operational efficiency of the power market was mainly analyzed theoretically and empirically from the perspective of market power [26]. Some scholars also studied the key problems facing the operational efficiency of the power market from a market structure perspective [27]. Other scholars put forward systemic theories and evaluation methods for the operational efficiency of the power market [28].
Apart from evaluating market efficiency [19] based on actual market operation data, foreign scholars have also studied the factors affecting the efficiency of market operations, such as price mechanism design, market structure design, market power, demand response, power system investment and environmental policies, as shown in Table 1. These studies provide a powerful reference for designing new market systems or behaviors.
Pricing mechanisms are the core of market operation design. A lot of practice and research on the applicability and effect of pricing mechanisms has been carried out by the industrial sector and in academia. For example, the original pricing mechanism of the Texas power market in the US was based on regional marginal pricing in the early stage of market construction, but it changed to a node marginal pricing mechanism [30] in 2010 as the market operating efficiency decreased with the deepening of power system congestion in the region. Focusing on the redispatching market in Europe, some scholars have quantitatively assessed the impact of regional pricing and node tariff mechanisms on the operational efficiency of the power system in a market environment where there is incomplete competition [60]. Such studies provide useful references for the design of electricity pricing mechanisms. According to other investigations, pricing mechanisms in China vary from province to province. Gansu and Jiangsu implement the regional marginal price [29], and the clearing price in the province is the same. Shanxi, Zhejiang and Guangdong, on the other hand, implement the locational marginal price, meaning that the clearing prices in different nodes fluctuate. Based on a full development of the electric energy market, PJM, California and other power markets in the Americas began to explore the key role [31,32,33,34] that capacity pricing mechanisms play in balancing between strengthening the reliability of power systems and increasing income for power producers. In addition, because distributed power supply has developed rapidly, reaching a large scale in recent years, its trading mechanisms [37] have also aroused wide concern.
Demand response is the process whereby end users adjust their own electricity consumption behavior in response to time-based rates. End users are provided with compensation [61] for reducing power usage when wholesale market prices are high or the reliability of power systems is threatened. At present, foreign research on demand response is focused on resident demand response strategies [62,63], business user demand response models and optimization methods [54], as well as on microgrids. Some other emerging flexible resources are also seen as key elements [64] of demand response, including flexible loads [65,66,67], as well as resource aggregators (RA) [54] that combine distributed power supplies, energy storage systems, and controlled loads.
The optimization of investment planning in power systems is the subject of power trading research at the macro level. Investment is also an important means of building a new power system in stages. However, most research on investment planning in power systems is focused on the physical characteristics of the electricity system, while influences from market factors are ignored by most studies. Typical simulation software for investment planning for power systems include Energy Plan [68], SWITCH [69,70,71], NEPLAN [72] and PLEXOS [73]. Only PLEXOS takes into account market factors (including recent and real-time market price movements, changes in demand, market risks, etc.), ancillary services and system flexibility. It can also simulate carbon trading management, showing the near-real re-emergence of multi-market coupling and system-to-market coupling. However, other investment planning simulation software are based on the technical and economic characteristics of the power system. They take into account environmental or policy impact, rather than the impact of inner-market factors on system investment planning. Such software specializes in long-term planning and optimization of the energy structure of the system.

3.1.2. Bidding Strategy of Market Participants

The quotation strategy is where the feedback from market participants corresponds to the power market mechanism, and it is also an effective test of the market mechanism. In early research, most scholars focused on power producers. They judged their winning probability by predicting the market clearance price [74], or their competitor’s strategy [75], and drew their own bidding strategy based on the probability theory method. The game theory revenue matrix and incomplete competition game models were also the tools that they used to form their own bidding strategies.
During the first round of power system reform in China, a power generation side competition model was formed because the state-owned power grid company is the only buyer. Around 2002, many scholars studied the bidding strategies of power generation enterprises that were based on coal and other fossil fuels, and obtained rich research results. The quotation strategies that were used in those studies were mainly based on cost analysis [76], electricity price forecasts [77], optimal methods [78] and game theory [79]. After that, some scholars used power market simulation experiments to study the bidding strategies and bidding trading systems of power producers based on EWA algorithms [80], Repast algorithms [81], Agents [82,83], and MAS [84]. However, those strategies only served traditional thermal power plants, and the target market was limited to provincial electricity energy markets. The market is changing as China pushes ahead with a new round of power system reform. The power selling side of the market is opening. The types of market participant are increasing, and trading variety is growing. The focus of current research has moved to the portfolio strategies of market participants (represented by power producers, electricity sellers and large users) to cope with medium- and long-term contracts (physical and financial), spot trading, ancillary services and carbon markets. With the progress of technology, research on new market subjects has gradually increased. The bidding strategies of virtual power plants or hybrid power plants [85], microgrids, load aggregators [86], prosumers, energy storage and electric vehicles are becoming hot issues. Some studies have identified trading strategies for a certain type of market, and some researchers have proposed joint optimization strategies for multiple types of markets. Common research methods include two-stage robust optimization, which takes into account risks, and the Markov decision process [87]. Typical references are as shown in Table 2.
As can be seen from the table above, most of this research is focused on the electric energy market. The joint strategy for real-time markets and ancillary services is an especially hot research issue. There is little research that focuses on a single secondary service and capacity market strategy. It is worth noting that the market participation strategy for new thermal power units with flexible regulation capabilities has not yet been studied. However, the right strategy is crucial for thermal power units to survive during market reforms. Under new situations, when developing trading strategies, thermal power units should consider not only the income from selling electricity, but also potential benefits from providing ancillary services or spare capacity through flexible resources. Risk aversion through financial contracts [104,105,106], arbitrage and linkage strategies with the carbon market should also be taken into account. For instance, Bjorgan analyzed the impacts of resources constraints when utilizing a portfolio of contracts to manage adverse markets risks [104]. Furthermore, T. S. Chung introduced a new electricity forward contract that included a bilateral financial contract that allows both the seller and buyer to cope with market price fluctuations [105]. Focusing on the forward risk premia, Spodniak studied the differences between the trading price of electricity in forward contracts and the spot prices to hedge transmission risks [106]. In addition, the feasibility of trading strategies that combine new energy, thermal power, gas and energy storage and other sources is also worth exploring.

3.1.3. Power Market Regulation

A sound electricity market requires regulation. Power market regulators around the world perform nearly the same functions, including detecting potential risks to the healthy operation of the market (usually to detect whether market participants behave in accordance with market rules, standards and processes), judging whether market participants use market power appropriately, looking for defects in market rules and detecting how regional transmission organizations (RTO) influence market operations [107]. Market regulators usually exist in four major forms: (1) a single regulation department that is embedded in the system scheduling operational structure, (2) a single regulatory body that is independent of the system scheduling agency, (3) a single regulatory body that is controlled by the government, and (4) a dual regulatory body, one that belongs to the system scheduling agency, and the other which is independent. Typical regulators include the Office of Gas and Electricity Markets (Ofgem) in the UK, the European Securities and Markets Authority (ESMA), the Australian Energy Market Commission (AEMC) and the Australian Energy Regulator (AER), as well as the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) in the US.
A variety of operational risks within the power market have been studied by academics, including supply-side market structure risks, mechanism design risks, the credit risks of market participants, power system security risks and external environmental risks. As an important index of market supervision, market power has attracted much attention from researchers.
In research outside of China, S. Prabhakar Karthikeyan [108] and his team comprehensively expounded a range of market power assessment indicators, common simulation tools, as well as common theories and algorithms. After analyzing typical cases in different countries, they proposed measures to control market power. Common indicators of market power assessment include the Herfindahl–Hirschman index (HHI) [39], the Lerner index (LI) [40,41], the must-run ratio (MRR) [42] and the residual supply index [43]. In addition, the system interchange capacity (SIC) [44], the location privilege (LP) surplus deviation index [45], the contribution congestion factor matrix [46] and other indicators have been put forward and applied by some scholars. Some other scholars claim that HHI evaluation has shortcomings, and have thus put forward a method to evaluate market power in the electricity sector based on oil market simulation [109]. In terms of regions, electricity markets in California of US [110,111], Wales (UK) [112], Germany [113], India [114], and Iran [114] has been surveyed to evaluate their market power.
The research on market power by Chinese scholars can be divided into three major types. For the first type, researchers presented a review of market power regulation and mitigation measures in foreign electricity markets, such as North America and northern Europe. For the second type, which is based on market power indicators, researchers carried out market efficiency assessments and proposed risk warnings for power producers. This research was conducted before the second round of power reform. Some were based on principal component analysis [47], and some were based on game theory [48,49]. Only Zhang Fuqiang [50] and his team considered the strategic behavior of power producers and used intelligent simulations to evaluate market power in different settlement modes. A third type of research has emerged since China deregulated its retail power market in the second round of power reform. This type focuses on the market power of various participants [115], including electricity producers [116], retailers and users. Some of the recent studies help electricity producers discover spot markets using support vector machines (SVM). Some other research has been conducted on the breakdown of medium- and long-term contracts, taking into account the market power of the parties to the contracts [117].
In order to help market participants avoid risks, market designers provide financial instruments based on the operating boundaries of power systems when designing price mechanisms, such as contracts for differences (CFD), transmission congestion contracts (TCCs), and financial transmission rights (FTRs). In addition, some scholars have proposed the concept of an operational health degree for power markets [118], which can be used to measure the electricity market so as to help government departments, system operators (e.g., independent system operators, ISOs) and market management committees monitor market conditions in a timely manner and take appropriate measures if necessary.

3.2. Key Issues in the Study of Power Markets as the System Adapts to the New Power System

As a major measure for reaching China’s carbon reduction targets, constructing a new power system based on renewable energy is a complex systematic project that involves various sides in the electricity sector, including electricity producers, grids and load control sources. There will be new requirements for every part of the power system. Electricity generation units should be more flexible and capable of coordinating with the grid. The grid should be optimized for the configuration of clean energy. End users are expected to interact flexibly with the grid to help ensure power security. The market mechanism is the basic guarantee when constructing a new power system. Furthermore, the operation of new energy sources and thermal power units with regulatory capabilities and flexible loads [119], needs to be reinterpreted under the new situation. Therefore, research on how the power market needs to adapt to the new power system should be focused on building market mechanisms to promote the participation of new energy in the market, helping thermal power units survive during periods of market reform and discovering flexible resources.

3.2.1. Mechanisms and Strategies for Renewable Energy Producers Participating in the Power Market

Governments in different countries have introduced price mechanisms [120,121,122] and incentive policies [123] to encourage renewable energy producers to produce more. The fixed electricity prices and tradable green certification mechanisms [124] that were introduced by the EU have been successful at stimulating renewable power generation. Germany has introduced a fixed feed-in tariff mechanism, a market premium mechanism and a bidding system for the different stages of renewable energy development. The German government can adjust its fiscal incentives flexibly considering the downward trend of renewable energy costs. With these policies, Germany is seeing a rapid growth in renewable energy production. The United States and Australia promote new energy through renewable energy quota systems and renewable energy certification mechanisms. They guarantee the trading volume of wind and photovoltaic power through power purchase agreements (PPAs), and encourage renewable energy companies to directly participate in the wholesale electricity market based on contracts for difference (CFDs).
Problems appear when renewable energy producers participate in the electricity market. Firstly, the wholesale price in the power market has fallen as the scale of new energy generation has rapidly expanded. Falling prices have suppressed investment from conventional power suppliers, and this may harm the safety and stability of the whole power system. Secondly, the unstable output from new energy generation makes the markets’ clearing prices more volatile. The gap between clearing prices in day-ahead markets and real-time markets widens, adding to the uncertainty regarding the returns gained by conventional thermal power plants. Thirdly, the climbing market share of renewable energy poses challenges to the design of market mechanisms.
Research into the power market is currently focusing on how to innovate the spot market price mechanism, auxiliary service price mechanism and capacity price mechanism to adapt to the new market, which now features a high proportion of new energy. Many scholars are proposing new market mechanisms for auxiliary services that are adapted to the new situation [125]. Godoy and his team are among these researchers. They designed a cost-based ancillary services market mechanism and verified its technical and economic feasibility through a simulation of the Chilean [126] electricity market. Some scholars studied the joint clearance of the electricity spot market and the auxiliary services market [127,128,129], while some others have proposed mechanisms to prompt flexible resource providers, including energy storage [130] and distributed power supply [131], to participate in the secondary services market.
The optimization of the power system and microgrid structure in the green power market [132] is also attracting the attention of researchers. S. Arango Aramburo [133] has studied the impact of the access to new energy on the investment cycle of power system capacity. A. Hasankhani [134] compared the differences between the scale of renewable energy in smart microgrids before and after participating in the power market, and optimized the energy management of microgrids. The issue of how demand response contributes to promoting new energy electricity connections to the grid [135] has also been explored, and researchers weighed the relationship between the scale of demand response and social welfare.

3.2.2. The Survival and Transformation of Coal-Fired Power Units

The rapid expansion of new energy power generation is squeezing out traditional coal-fired power plants. Firstly, coal-fired power generators have to keep their overall utilization hours at low levels because large quantities of electricity generated from renewable energy sources must be consumed before thermal power. Meanwhile, coal power plants have to adjust their own output to make up for new energy generation and maintain the stable operation of the grid. When electricity generated by renewable resources is sufficient, thermal power units need to reduce their output. When renewable power plants are unable to support power consumption at peak times, thermal electric plants need to increase their generation. Thus, the operational cost of coal-fired power plants is rising. Secondly, the wholesale price of electricity is falling as a result of the rapid expansion of renewable power generation. Coal-fired power plants are losing competitiveness due to falling electricity prices. Some thermal power plants even report severe losses in regions with high prices of coal. Thirdly, the environmental cost of coal-fired power plants is also rising because China is promoting green and low-carbon development through the carbon trading market, which further cuts the competitiveness of thermal power plants. Fourthly, the complexity and cost of decision making is surging as coal-fired power plants adapt to the power and carbon market linkage system. It is a new challenge for traditional power suppliers which have just become accustomed to the market environment in the past few years.
However, thermal power accounts for more than 60% [136] of China’s total installed power capacity, with nearly 50% generated by coal-fired power plants. Therefore, the thermal power sector plays an important role in China’s power security. Meanwhile, China is limited to just relying on energy storage and demand-side resources to provide auxiliary services for the new power system. Flexible thermal power units’ capacity for adjusting electricity consuming load and frequency is worth exploring, especially with the target of transforming 200 million KW of coal-fired power units into flexible resources during China’s 14th five-year plan period [137]. In addition, the survival and development of coal-fired power units is also worth an in-depth discussion from the perspective of people’s livelihood. Therefore, whether coal-fired power plants can be successfully transformed through technological improvements and reasonable market mechanisms is a key issue for the construction of the new power system.

3.2.3. Value Realization and Supporting Mechanism for Flexible Resources

The value of flexible resources in the new power system is expected to be realized using market mechanisms. More and more attention is being paid to the value of flexible resources, including energy storage, electric vehicles, demand-side resources and thermal power plants with flexible regulation capabilities. However, current research on flexible resources is generally limited to optimization planning or resource allocation within power systems, discussing, for example, the system optimization of flexible resources for power supply, grid operation and load management. Another limited research issue is studying how to optimize the configuration of flexible resources for adequate demand response [138]. Only a few studies have explored the value [139,140] of flexible resources in the electricity market, which lack systematic quantitative analysis. Significantly, there are no studies on value modeling, market system design, and simulation deduction and decision analysis when it comes to flexible resources that will operate under market conditions within the new power system. To fill in this gap, we need to recognize the value of flexible resources and design a market mechanism that can clearly reflect price signals, so as to help renewable energy resources participate in the electricity market.

3.3. Basic Paradigm for the Study of Power Markets under the New Situation

A power market is a complex economic system, with branches forming where the system couples with others. To simplify this study, we built a framework with three dimensions, including market operations, market player strategies and market supervision, to outline a basic paradigm for power market research under the new situation. As shown in Figure 5a, the power market operates through the interaction of different sub-markets. Depending on its different functions, transaction times and spaces, the power market can also be divided into different submarkets. Market players make strategic decisions in different scenarios based on the market mechanisms, which leads to diverse market results. The interaction between market participants and the market operation mechanisms affects the health of the power market. Connecting all kinds of market players, the power trading center is responsible for publishing market information, organizing transactions of different types, managing the credit of market participants and assessing market risk. The dispatch center checks the safety of the power system according to the clearing information of the trading center, and forms the final clearing and dispatch orders. The market supervision department supervises the credit of market players, information disclosure, market force detection and risk warning. As shown in Figure 5b, the power system, market mechanisms and strategies of market participants are key factors that help us understand market systems. These three aspects will be further discussed in the following part of this paper.
Typical types of power markets include the electric energy market, the auxiliary services market, the capacity market, the power financial market and the transmission rights market. The electric energy market can be further divided into the wholesale market and the retail market according to the trading volume. In the wholesale market, participants can trade through the trading center, or they are allowed to make direct transactions through bilateral negotiations.
From the perspective of the time dimension, the electric energy market can be divided into the medium- and long-term market, and the spot trading market. The medium- and long-term power market is designed to avoid market risks and maintain the safety of power systems. Transactions in the medium- and long-term market can be made either physically or in a financial manner. From the perspective of the spatial dimension, power markets can be classified as provincial markets, regional markets, national markets and transnational markets, according to the different structures of the power grids. Different countries choose different trading modes according to the unique structures of their grids.
Auxiliary services are helpful for maintaining the reliable operations of the grid and ensuring the quality of electricity transmission. The ancillary services market is an important complement to the spot market. As China advances the reform of the power market, a key issue is how it can determine the supply boundaries [141] and supply costs of auxiliary services within the auxiliary services market. Another hot issues is how the supply costs would change [142] with different operational strategies.
One study [141] is a review of the international research results from studies of auxiliary service standby mechanisms that are based on the actual operations of regional power markets, covering the types of auxiliary service standby mechanisms, the coordination and optimization mechanisms of the standby power market, and methods for assessing backup demand. If the auxiliary services market is regarded as the safety mechanism to ensure the stability of power system in real time, then the capacity market is the mechanism that ensures the stable supply of electricity over the medium and long term. The key issue when studying the capacity market is how to encourage market participants to build effective power generation units, improve investment efficiency and ensure the stable supply of electricity [143] under the premise of reducing investment costs. Financial derivatives are important tools for risk management in the power market. In the power markets of typical countries, market participants use contracts for difference (CFDs), power futures and power options products and other financial derivatives [144,145] to suppress the risks from fluctuating spot prices.
With the urgent need to build a new power system and market trading system, it is especially necessary to explore the market mechanisms, capacity mechanisms or capacity markets [146], and market interface mechanisms that can be adapted to China’s own conditions. Under China’s new power system, based as it is on renewable energy, the important value of flexible resources, an emerging market resource, needs not only to be quantified, but also to be realized under the market mechanisms. Therefore, whether to design a new market mechanism for renewable energy and flexible resources, how to design and connect the mechanisms, what effect the new mechanism could bring, and other questions are issues worth exploring. Further, the research on the portfolio and bidding strategies of market participants, including traditional thermal power capacities and emerging renewable energy and flexible resources, is of great significance to help market players integrate into the new market conditions and to promote the healthy development of the market.

4. The Theoretical Basis and Technical Applications of Power Market Simulations to Help Markets Adapt to the New Power System

The effects of designing market mechanisms and conducting research into market participants’ strategies need to be verified under specific market circumstances. Power market simulation technology is an effective means of avoiding the loss of benefits that the strategy’s design may cause to the actual system. The power market is an open and dynamic, complex and adaptive system with parallel interactions and nonlinear dynamics. Each market participant is independent but can interact with any other. Traditional simulation tools that are based on unified decision making are not suitable for complex power systems with decentralized decision making as the basic feature [147]. The simulation of power markets based on experimental economics and computational economics not only considers the rational and irrational behavior that may occur in the real environment, but can also simulate people’s limited rational decision making and realize complex computations using intelligent agent technology. Therefore, it is an effective tool for studying market mechanisms and the strategies of market participants.

4.1. The Theoretical Basis of Power Market Simulation

4.1.1. Principles and Applications of Experimental Economics

Experimental economics (EE) is a branch of economics that uses data from experiments to address economic questions. Experimental economics was developed in the second half of the 20th century and matured during the 1960s and 1980s. Drawing on the experimental methods that are used in the natural sciences, EE simulates the actual decision making that goes into market transactions according to the strategy of selected subjects. Experimental economics is used to prove the theoretical hypotheses of economics and test the effects of specific rules in the economic system through controlled experiments. The research issues of experimental economics have developed from simple theoretical tests to summarizing regularities and forming new theories using systematic experiments. The design process of economic experiments has also changed from simply copying the scenes in classic models to designing “tailor-made” experiments [148] for new research issues.
With the development of computer technology, experimental methods have become diversified, which makes large-scale experiments and remote interactive experiments feasible. The scope of research has been extended from microscopic and purely theoretical topics to macro [149], financial [150,151,152,153] and social networks [154]. Many government agencies use the results from experimental economics research to guide practice [155] in auctions and central bank policy making. Through systematic reviewing-related research, some scholars divide experimental economics into seven branches [148]: individual preference and decision making, game theory, industrial organization, labor economics, public economics, finance, and macroeconomics. Power market simulations that are based on experimental economics can help verify the theoretical value of the above theories when studying multi-subject interactions in markets and market dynamics, providing a key basis for understanding the competitive behavior and theoretical modeling of market participants. Through power market simulation, we can also research the influence of different trading mechanisms that consider the rational and irrational behavior of real market participants on the efficiency of resource allocation.

4.1.2. Principles and Applications of Agent-Based Computational Economics

Only a limited number of market players can be considered to be the ‘rational economic men’ of classical economics. Market participants’ behavior is not universal, and it is therefore difficult to interpret using traditional mathematical models. With the convergence of technologies in multiple fields and the progress of research and development technologies, agent-based computational economics (ACE) has become an effective tool for overcoming the shortcoming of traditional economics.
Through artificial intelligence and computer modeling and simulation technology, ACE can be used to study complex phenomena in economic systems. Based on the system evolution model, which constitutes a large number of independent market players, the decision-making methods and intelligence levels of different market participants can be calculated using a series of calculations. The simulation system based on agent-based computational economics (ACE) can not only verify some existing economic theories, but also address problems that cannot be well explained through other branches of economics. For example, in the real market environment, even if there is no top-down government/management influence, why do some market participants still follow behavior patterns that are beneficial to the overall development of the market system? Such a problem can be explained using agent-based computational economics (ACE).
In addition, the ACE model can help researchers understand the impact of different systems on the social efficiency and individual welfare of economic systems, and solve the problems of long-term games and individual psychological behavior, which are weak points in existing economic research. In power market simulations, each agent is given different capabilities in their initial state. During the trial cycle, individual agents predict potential changes in the market and give feedback based on their own characteristics. All agents in the system compete with each other and influence each other, together constituting a complex, dynamic, evolutionary system.
Major application scenarios of the existing research based on ACE are as follows. The first type of research is the simulation of individual learning mechanisms, of which the complex network evolution game, based on individual learning abilities, is a cutting-edge problem [156]. This simulation method is mainly based on genetic algorithm and neural network technology.
The second type is to depict behavior patterns. Typical research in earlier periods concentrated on the impact of cultural communication on economic globalization. After introducing the concept of open innovation, Chinese scholars combined computational economics with open innovation problems, and gave market players different equity preference attributes, so as to build a multi-intelligence simulation model. Then, market subjects’ preferred strategies, based on their different preference types in different innovation modes, are deduced. Such research provides a useful point of reference [157] for studying open innovation alliances and enterprise innovation development from the micro perspective.
Thirdly, the ACE model is also applied in the study of trading networks in economic systems, focusing mainly on the formation and evolution of networks, as well as the optimization of network organization. Social problems, such as the seasonal migration of shepherds, are typical issues at the heart of this research.
The fourth is to study the market model based on ACE. The evolutionary process and institutional influences on various kinds of markets attract the most researchers. The simulation of the securities market conducted by SFI(Santa Fe Institute) [158] is a typical scenario where ACE is applied.

4.2. Simulation Applications and Parameter Settings for the Power Market as It Adapts to the NPS

The power market simulation system is a comprehensive system that uses specific rules and design processes to simulate the real power market based on the characteristics of real power systems and real markets. The core modules of power market simulation cover power system modeling, power market rules and the characteristics of market participants. Based on the core modules, new scenarios can be designed by adding, deleting and changing parameters, so as to study key issues and test hypotheses pertaining to market constructions under the new power system.

4.2.1. Parameter Settings for the Modeling and Simulation of Power Systems

The modeling and simulation of power systems is based on the physical properties [159,160,161] of power systems, such as the structure of regional power supply, load, grid nodes and the limit of power transmission lines. As China expects to embrace a new power system with a large amount of renewable energy, the value of all kinds of electricity generation units (especially flexible resources) needs to be verified for the new market situation [162]. In order to simulate the market to study specific issues, a variable scenario for modeling power systems can be constructed by adding the types and proportions of electricity generation units. The types of units covered by the simulation include new energy sources, energy storage (usually in form of electrochemical, hydrogen storage, and flywheel), distributed power supplies and thermal power units with flexible regulation capabilities. Common parameters of power system simulation that are based on electric power system theory and prediction theory are shown in Table 3. In addition, under the construction of the new power system, the market share occupied by new energy, the rate of new energy penetration, and other indicators can be added. By adding such indicators, other issues [163], such as testing paths towards the dual carbon emission target, discovering the value of diverse resources and improving the strategies of market participants, can be researched under the simulation with extended parameters.

4.2.2. Parameter Settings to Simulate the Rules and Conditions of the Power Market

The simulation of market rules and conditions is focused on market mechanisms and related policies. Through setting different parameters, diverse market scenarios can be simulated. Market rules are reflected by a range of parameters, such as the entry and exit of market players, symbols of trade, and rules of clearance and settlement. Market conditions are simulated by the ratio of supply and demand, market forces and policy-related indicators. Common parameter settings that are based on power market trading, theory and industrial economics theory are shown in Table 4.
To study the key issues relating to the market trading system under the new power system, the access of emerging market participants can be modified through the module of participant characteristics. When designing market mechanisms to stimulate flexible resources, it is necessary to make explicit the value and price conduction mechanism of the flexible resources. Simultaneously, some parameters, including the price declaration mode, the upper and lower limits of the price, the clearing method and the settlement method, can be modified so as to check market feedback.
In addition, whether the symbols are sufficient to meet market demand can be verified through combining multiple symbols and trading methods, with the actual situation in the simulation area taken into consideration. To verify the settlement rules, the model, content and the method of settlement that is used by different users can be combined and simulated through power market simulation. Thus, the settlement rules, with their regional characteristics, such as deviation assessment and double rule assessment, can be included in the study.

4.2.3. Market Participant Characteristic Parameters

As the most basic units of the power market, market participants affect the construction of the trading mechanism to a certain extent. The market subject module is focused on the characteristics of transaction behaviors and the strategies of market participants. In the simulation system, the subject that is making decisions can be intelligent or real people. Therefore, parameters are designed to simulate the characteristics of human-machine decision making, including the type, quantity, distribution, feedback behavior and learning ability of market participants. The parameters that are commonly used to simulate market participants characteristic, which are based on power market theory, behavioral economics theory and forecasting techniques, are shown in Table 5.
To better study the key issues relating to the market trading system under the new power system, on the one hand, we should expand the research to cover a diversity of market subjects. A range of participants, such as different renewable energy resources, energy storage, distributed power supplies, flexible thermal power units, and flexible loads that can respond to power consumption peaks, should be included. On the other hand, stronger decision-making abilities should be developed for market subjects. Training the learning, prediction, portfolio and risk management abilities of the intelligent agents is helpful. By enriching the parameters for the simulation of market transaction behaviors, the effect of different trading mechanisms can be tested, providing beneficial points of reference for market participants for better decision making.

5. Discussion

This paper provided a rigorous systematic review of the study of power markets with clear framework conditions using pertinent literature databases and full-text access for query articles. The disregard of non-English and non-Chinese language publications in the databases and the disregard of conference articles without full-text access could be regarded as limitations of this review. Moreover, the exclusion of the last pages papers in the relevance rankings could also be a limitation.
This review covered existing research on the study of power markets, including market operational efficiency, the bidding strategies of market participants and power market supervision. Based on the search results, it can be concluded that English papers focused more on bidding strategies than on the operational efficiency of markets. However, Chinese papers paid more attention to the operational efficiency of markets and supervision than to bidding strategy.
Previous studies on the operational efficiency of power markets mainly focused on the structure design or evaluation. As illustrated in Section 3.1.1, such studies have three major flaws. Firstly, such empirical analyses were limited to the unilateral bidding market scenario that was formed during the first electric power reforms in China. Secondly, previous researchers ignored the constraints and influences of environmental factors. Thirdly, those studies have not considered the systematic impact of a high proportion of new energy connecting to the power system and power market. Given the different roles of market players, studies on bidding strategies can be sorted according to three aspects, namely, generation companies’ strategies, energy retailers’ strategies, and energy consumers’ strategies. With regard to the development of the power market, studies on the strategies of prosumers [86], virtual power plants [94,95], microgrids [91] and energy storage [91] were given more attention. Furthermore, most of them focused on the spot market, especially the day-ahead market. Moreover, previous studies in the bidding strategy field were implemented using cost analysis, electricity price forecasts, optimization algorithms or game theory. Little research was conducted using a power market trading simulation system, which is based on experimental economics and agent-based computational economics. To some extent, these can provide points of reference for bidding strategy studies that focus on the adaptation to the NPS. However, most of them studied participants as price takers, and only a few publications [166] studied the market strategies of flexible resources in joint energy and flexible product markets. This work emphasized the significance of power market simulation systems for the study of power markets, and proposed parameter setting suggestions for power system simulations, power market rules simulation and market participants characteristics.
This literature review introduced several key issues in Section 3.2 that relate to the adaptation to the NPS. In Section 3.2.1, relatively new studies were discussed, with 42 papers found that were published in Web of Science and 121 papers in Elsevier. However, only two of these papers were published after the NPS was proposed. Only one of them focused on the financial implications for investors in renewable energy [167]. The other one introduced a day-ahead clearing model for the simultaneous energy and ancillary services market with a high penetration of renewable energy sources [127]. Although some papers also talked about market issues with renewable energy resources, most of them focused more on power system operations [168,169] than the power market operations. In conclusion, few studies discussed the mechanisms and strategies for an investor in a market with a high amount of renewable energy.
Only five papers were identified as highly relevant publications based on in the “Coal-fired power transition” search term. Some studies discussed phase-out issues [170,171], rather than the transition strategy for coal-fired plants to adapt to the energy transition. Although one paper [172] proposed that coal-fired power plant could be retired in Australia in the future, it did not discuss the policy implications for coal-fired power plants during this transition. Under the construction of the NPS, one should consider not only the income from selling electricity, but also the potential benefits from providing flexibility using coal-fired units.
As for the study of flexible resources in power markets, Muñoz [173] discussed the current limitations of Chile’s electricity market going forward, which aimed to provide incentives for the efficient resources to give the system more flexibility. Moreover, Das, P. [174] argued that technology, policy and new modeling strategies are needed to expand large-scale renewable energy, which supports the standpoint of this review.

6. Conclusions and Implications

Research on electric power markets are now discussing how the markets can adapt to the new power system, which will be based on renewable energy. Market mechanisms, market participants’ strategies, and market supervision are three key elements for the healthy operation of the power market. This paper provided a rigorous systematic review of the study of power markets given this new situation. The article also provided a comprehensive overview of the key issues in the new studies on power markets and its applications and techniques. After the analysis, a basic paradigm for the study of power markets that is suitable for the new situation was put forward to provide a clear review of the study of power markets and inspire better research on market trading mechanisms under the new power system. The main contributions of our research are as follows:
  • The general issues of power market research were summarized in terms of market operation, bidding strategies of market players, and market supervision. The quantitative analysis shows that China’s previous power market studies paid more attention to the market mechanism design and operation supervision. However, bidding strategies were discussed more than power market supervision in other countries.
  • Key issues related to research on the power market were picked out for further study as the market adapts to the new power system, which features a high proportion of new energy. These issues include market mechanisms to promote the participation of new energy, flexible resource value discovery and supporting mechanisms, as well as the survival of thermal power units. The systematic review indicates that the mechanism and strategies for a new energy-dominated power market were not fully considered in previous studies. Moreover, for the survival of coal-fired power plants in this new environment, most studies focused on the phase out issues rather than the market mechanisms and strategies relating to their transformation. In addition, research on flexible market products is still rare, although more attention is being paid to this issue [174].
  • A basic paradigm for the study of power markets that is suitable for the new power system was established, which provides the basic direction for power market research under the new situation.
  • The theoretical basis of power market simulation was presented in our paper. Meanwhile, the applications of experimental economics and agent-based computational economics in the study of power markets were reviewed. The quantitative analysis shows that although the current studies can provide a point of reference for the study of power markets, there are few pieces of literature on the new power market with the application of EE and ACE. More research is needed in the future to adapt to the construction of the NPS.
  • Specific parameter settings were recommended for simulating power market transactions, which can serve as a theoretical basis and practical guidance for other researchers to better study the power market.
The power market is a complex economic system. To better construct a new power market that is dominated by new energies, more studies on the key issues are needed. Studies on the new power market can be developed using EE and ACE techniques., which can help to reduce the costs of power market construction, promote the low-carbon transformation of the electricity sector, and improve the market trading mechanisms of the new power system.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, J.D. and D.L.; methodology, D.L. and T.M.; validation, D.L., T.M. and X.D.; formal analysis, D.L. and X.D.; investigation, S.L., Y.J. and B.L.; resources, D.L. and B.L.; data curation, D.L. and X.D.; writing—original draft preparation, D.L. and X.D.; writing—review and editing, D.L., B.L., T.M. and X.D; visualization, X.D.; supervision, J.D. and T.M.; project administration, J.D. and T.M.; funding acquisition, J.D. and T.M. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research was funded by the Higher Education Discipline Innovation and Talent Plan—China Green Power Development Research Discipline Innovation and Talent Base (B18021).

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

Not applicable.

Acknowledgments

This study was supported by the Energy Market Research Institute of North China Electric Power University.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Wang, D.; Zhang, Z.; Yang, X.; Zhang, Y.; Li, Y.; Zhao, Y. Multi-Scenario Simulation on the Impact of China’s Electricity Bidding Policy Based on Complex Networks Model. Energy Policy 2021, 158, 112573. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Huo, T.; Xu, L.; Feng, W.; Cai, W.; Liu, B. Dynamic Scenario Simulations of Carbon Emission Peak in China’s City-Scale Urban Residential Building Sector through 2050. Energy Policy 2021, 159, 112612. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. China News. China’s Renewable Energy Power Generation Capacity Reached 2.2 Trillion KWh in 2020. Available online: https://www.chinanewsweb.com/index.php/2021/03/30/chinas-renewable-energy-generation-will-reach-2-2-trillion-kilowatt-hours-by-2020 (accessed on 15 August 2021).
  4. Ma, L.; Fan, M.; Qu, H.; Li, J.; Zhao, Z.; Wu, C.; Chen, K. Construction path and key problems of China’s power market. Electric Power 2020, 53, 1–9. [Google Scholar]
  5. Chen, H. Causes and Countermeasures of “unbalanced funds” in power market. China Electr. Power Enterp. Manag. 2020, 25, 27–30. [Google Scholar]
  6. Zhao, Z.; Gu, W.; Chen, Y.; Li, X.; Jiang, Y.; Gao, D.; Duan, R.; Wu, Y. Analysis of unbalanced capital in power market under dual track system. Electr. Power 2020, 53, 47–54. [Google Scholar]
  7. Chen, Q.; Yang, J.; Huang, Y.; Lu, E.; Wang, Y. Review on Market Power Monitoring and Mitigation Mechanisms in Foreign Electricity Markets. South. Power Syst. Technol. 2018, 12, 9–15+63. [Google Scholar]
  8. Deng, S.; Xu, K.; Liu, L. Review on the Reasons for Formation and Inhibition Mechanism of Market Power in the Electricity Market. Telecom Power Technol. 2018, 35, 129–131. [Google Scholar]
  9. Wu, T.; Ding, Y.; Shang, N.; Bao, M.; Song, Y. Joint decomposition algorithm of medium and long-term contract electricity of multi class units considering market power test. Autom. Electr. Power Syst. 2021, 45, 72–81. [Google Scholar]
  10. Zhang, Q.; Wang, X.; Wang, J.; Feng, C.; Liu, L. Review on demand response research in power market. Autom. Electr. Power Syst. 2008, 3, 97–106. [Google Scholar]
  11. Xiao, Y.; Wang, X.; Wang, X.; Bie, Z. Review on Electricity Market Towards High Proportion of Renewable Energy. Proc. CSEE 2018, 38, 663–674. [Google Scholar]
  12. Keele, S. Guidelines for Performing Systematic Literature Reviews in Software Engineering; EBSE Technical Report: Durham, UK, 2007. [Google Scholar]
  13. PRISMA-P Group; Moher, D.; Shamseer, L.; Clarke, M.; Ghersi, D.; Liberati, A.; Petticrew, M.; Shekelle, P.; Stewart, L.A. Preferred Reporting Items for Systematic Review and Meta-Analysis Protocols (PRISMA-P) 2015 Statement. Syst. Rev. 2015, 4, 1–9. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  14. Shrestha, T.K.; Karki, R. Impact of Market-Driven Energy Storage System Operation on the Operational Adequacy of Wind Integrated Power Systems. J. Energy Storage 2020, 32, 101792. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Bigdeli, N.; Afshar, K.; Fotuhi-Firuzabad, M. Bidding Strategy in Pay-as-Bid Markets Based on Supplier-Market Interaction Analysis. Energy Convers. Manag. 2010, 51, 2419–2430. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Chen, C. Searching for Intellectual Turning Points: Progressive Knowledge Domain Visualization. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2004, 101, 5303–5310. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
  17. Chen, Y.; Qin, Z. Review of Research on Electricity Market Reform. Electrotech. Electr. 2019, 4, 1–6+12. [Google Scholar]
  18. Newbery, D. Electricity Liberalization in Britain and the Evolution of Market Design. In Electricity Market Reform; Elsevier: Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 2006; pp. 109–143. [Google Scholar]
  19. Marshall, L.; Bruce, A.; MacGill, I. Assessing Wholesale Competition in the Australian National Electricity Market. Energy Policy 2021, 149, 112066. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Borenstein, S.; Bushnell, J.B.; Wolak, F.A. Measuring Market Inefficiencies in California’s Restructured Wholesale Electricity Market. Am. Econ. Rev. 2002, 92, 1376–1405. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  21. Daglish, T.; de Bragança, G.G.F.; Owen, S.; Romano, T. Pricing Effects of the Electricity Market Reform in Brazil. Energy Econ. 2021, 105197. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Bertram, G. Weak Regulation, Rising Margins, and Asset Revaluations. In Evolution of Global Electricity Markets; Elsevier: Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 2013; pp. 645–677. [Google Scholar]
  23. Keles, D.; Bublitz, A.; Zimmermann, F.; Genoese, M.; Fichtner, W. Analysis of Design Options for the Electricity Market: The German Case. Appl. Energy 2016, 183, 884–901. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Nilsson, M. Red Light for Green Paper: The EU Policy on Energy Efficiency. Energy Policy 2007, 35, 540–547. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Pérez-Díaz, J.I.; Wilhelmi, J.R.; Arévalo, L.A. Optimal Short-Term Operation Schedule of a Hydropower Plant in a Competitive Electricity Market. Energy Convers. Manag. 2010, 51, 2955–2966. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Xu, D. Research on Operation Efficiency of Power Market; Zhejiang University: Hangzhou, China, 2003. [Google Scholar]
  27. Luan, F. Research on Theory and Application of Economic Efficiency Evaluation of Power Market; North China Electric Power University: Beijing, China, 2007. [Google Scholar]
  28. Wang, W.; Shao, S.; Li, L.; Tang, H.; Zhao, Y.; Xia, Q. Power market efficiency theory and its evaluation method. Power Grid Technol. 2009, 33, 66–71. [Google Scholar]
  29. Ren, Y.; Liu, S.; Bie, Z. Regional Marginal Price Mechanism in the China Northwest Power Grid. In Proceedings of the 2019 IEEE 8th International Conference on Advanced Power System Automation and Protection (APAP), Xi’an, China, 21 October 2019; pp. 1115–1119. [Google Scholar]
  30. Daneshi, H.; Srivastava, A.K. ERCOT Electricity Market: Transition from Zonal to Nodal Market Operation. In Proceedings of the 2011 IEEE Power and Energy Society General Meeting, San Diego, CA, USA, 24–28 July 2011; pp. 1–7. [Google Scholar]
  31. Höschle, H.; De Jonghe, C.; Le Cadre, H.; Belmans, R. Electricity Markets for Energy, Flexibility and Availability—Impact of Capacity Mechanisms on the Remuneration of Generation Technologies. Energy Econ. 2017, 66, 372–383. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. BOWRING, J. Capacity Markets in PJM. Econ. Energy Environ. Policy 2013, 2, 47–64. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  33. Bowring, J.E. The evolution of the PJM capacity market: Does it address the revenue sufficiency problem? In Evolution of Global Electricity Markets; Elsevier: Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 2013; pp. 227–264. [Google Scholar]
  34. Hobbs, B.F.; Hu, M.-C.; Inon, J.G.; Stoft, S.E.; Bhavaraju, M.P. A Dynamic Analysis of a Demand Curve-Based Capacity Market Proposal: The PJM Reliability Pricing Model. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 2007, 22, 3–14. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Song, X.; Zhai, X.; Chen, W.; Xue, J.; Wang, P. Study on Three-Part Pricing Method of Pumped Storage Power Station in China Considering Peak Load Regulation Auxiliary Service. IOP Publ. 2021, 675, 012110. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Wang, J.; Zhong, H.; Yang, Z.; Lai, X.; Xia, Q.; Kang, C. Incentive Mechanism for Clearing Energy and Reserve Markets in Multi-Area Power Systems. IEEE Trans. Sustain. Energy 2020, 11, 2470–2482. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Wang, J.; Zhong, H.; Wu, C.; Du, E.; Xia, Q.; Kang, C. Incentivizing Distributed Energy Resource Aggregation in Energy and Capacity Markets: An Energy Sharing Scheme and Mechanism Design. Appl. Energy 2019, 252, 113471. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Wolak, F.; Patrick, R. The Impact of Market Rules and Market Structure on the Price Determination Process in the England and Wales Electricity Market; National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2001; p. w8248. [Google Scholar]
  39. Tirole, J. The Theory of Industrial Organization; MIT Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 1988. [Google Scholar]
  40. Landes, W.M.; Posner, R.A. Market Power in Antitrust Cases. Harv. Law Rev. 1981, 94, 937. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Visudhiphan, P.; Ilic, M.D. Dependence of Generation Market Power on the Demand/Supply Ratio: Analysis and Modeling. In Proceedings of the 2000 IEEE Power Engineering Society Winter Meeting. Conference Proceedings (Cat. No.00CH37077), Singapore, 23–27 January 2000; Volume 2, pp. 1115–1122. [Google Scholar]
  42. Gan, D.; Bourcier, D.V. Locational Market Power Screening and Congestion Management: Experience and Suggestions. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 2002, 17, 180–185. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Rahimi, A.F.; Sheffrin, A.Y. Effective Market Monitoring in Deregulated Electricity Markets. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 2003, 18, 486–493. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Goncalves, M.J.D.; Vale, Z.A. Evaluation of Transmission Congestion Impact in Market Power. In Proceedings of the 2003 IEEE Bologna Power Tech Conference Proceedings, Bologna, Italy, 23–26 June 2003; Volume 4, pp. 438–443. [Google Scholar]
  45. Bompard, E.; Ma, Y.C.; Napoli, R.; Jiang, C.W. Assessing the Market Power Due to the Network Constraints in Competitive Electricity Markets. Electr. Power Syst. Res. 2006, 76, 953–961. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Moreira e Silva, R.; Terra, L.D.B. Market Power under Transmission Congestion Constraints. In Proceedings of the PowerTech Budapest 99. Abstract Records. (Cat. No.99EX376), Budapest, Hungary, 29 August–2 September 1999; p. 82. [Google Scholar]
  47. Li, H.; Wang, B.; Guo, S. Evaluation on Market Power of Generation Companies in Regional Electricity Market Based on Principal Component Analysis. Mod. Electr. Power 2011, 28, 85–89. [Google Scholar]
  48. Yang, T.; Fu, S.; Wang, B. Analysis of market power in power market based on Game Theory. J. Shandong Electr. Power Coll. 2011, 14, 13–18. [Google Scholar]
  49. Zhang, Z.; Guo, X.; Wang, F. Analysis of financial transmission rights and market power based on oligopoly competition model. Autom. Electr. Power Syst. 2011, 35, 30–33+59. [Google Scholar]
  50. Zhang, F.; Wen, F.; Yan, H.; Yu, Z.; Zhong, Z.; Hunag, J. Analysis of reactive power market power based on agent simulation. Autom. Electr. Power Syst. 2009, 33, 18–24. [Google Scholar]
  51. Ambrosius, M.; Grimm, V.; Sölch, C.; Zöttl, G. Investment Incentives for Flexible Demand Options under Different Market Designs. Energy Policy 2018, 118, 372–389. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Richstein, J.C.; Hosseinioun, S.S. Industrial Demand Response: How Network Tariffs and Regulation (Do Not) Impact Flexibility Provision in Electricity Markets and Reserves. Appl. Energy 2020, 278, 115431. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Spees, K.; Lave, L.B. Demand Response and Electricity Market Efficiency. Electr. J. 2007, 20, 69–85. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Wang, J.; Zhong, H.; Ma, Z.; Xia, Q.; Kang, C. Review and Prospect of Integrated Demand Response in the Multi-Energy System. Appl. Energy 2017, 202, 772–782. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Grimm, V.; Rückel, B.; Sölch, C.; Zöttl, G. The Impact of Market Design on Transmission and Generation Investment in Electricity Markets. Energy Econ. 2021, 93, 104934. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Tómasson, E.; Hesamzadeh, M.R.; Söder, L.; Biggar, D.R. An Incentive Mechanism for Generation Capacity Investment in a Price-Capped Wholesale Power Market. Electr. Power Syst. Res. 2020, 189, 106708. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Barazza, E.; Strachan, N. The Co-Evolution of Climate Policy and Investments in Electricity Markets: Simulating Agent Dynamics in UK, German and Italian Electricity Sectors. Energy Res. Soc. Sci. 2020, 65, 101458. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Feng, T.; Li, R.; Zhang, H.; Gong, X.; Yang, Y. Induction Mechanism and Optimization of Tradable Green Certificates and Carbon Emission Trading Acting on Electricity Market in China. Resour. Conserv. Recycl. 2021, 169, 105487. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Kraan, O.; Kramer, G.J.; Nikolic, I.; Chappin, E.; Koning, V. Why Fully Liberalised Electricity Markets Will Fail to Meet Deep Decarbonisation Targets Even with Strong Carbon Pricing. Energy Policy 2019, 131, 99–110. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Sarfati, M.; Hesamzadeh, M.R.; Holmberg, P. Production Efficiency of Nodal and Zonal Pricing in Imperfectly Competitive Electricity Markets. Energy Strategy Rev. 2019, 24, 193–206. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. U.S. Department of Energy. Benefits of Demand Response in Electricity Markets and Recommendations for Achieving Them; U.S. Department of Energy: Washington, DC, USA, 2006. [Google Scholar]
  62. Davarzani, S.; Pisica, I.; Taylor, G.A.; Munisami, K.J. Residential Demand Response Strategies and Applications in Active Distribution Network Management. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2021, 138, 110567. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  63. Pallonetto, F.; De Rosa, M.; D’Ettorre, F.; Finn, D.P. On the Assessment and Control Optimisation of Demand Response Programs in Residential Buildings. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2020, 127, 109861. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  64. Lu, X.; Li, K.; Xu, H.; Wang, F.; Zhou, Z.; Zhang, Y. Fundamentals and Business Model for Resource Aggregator of Demand Response in Electricity Markets. Energy 2020, 204, 117885. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  65. Yang, S.; Liu, J.; Yao, J.; Ding, H.; Wang, K.; Li, Y. Multi time scale coordinated flexible load interactive response scheduling model and strategy. Proc. CSEE 2014, 34, 3664–3673. [Google Scholar]
  66. Yuan, B.; Yang, Q.; Yan, W. Demand response under real-time price for domestic energy system. J. Mech. Electr. Eng. 2015, 32, 857–862. [Google Scholar]
  67. Jiang, T.; Li, Y.; Ju, P.; Yang, Y.; Zhao, J. Overview of Modeling Method for Flexible Load and its Control. Smart Power 2020, 48, 1–8. [Google Scholar]
  68. Lund, H.; Münster, E.; Tambjerg, L.H. EnergyPlan: Computer Model for Energy System Analysis: Version 6; Technology, Environment and Society, Department of Development and Planning, Aalborg University: Aalborg, Denmark, 2004. [Google Scholar]
  69. He, G.; Avrin, A.-P.; Nelson, J.H.; Johnston, J.; Mileva, A.; Tian, J.; Kammen, D.M. SWITCH-China: A Systems Approach to Decarbonizing China’s Power System. Environ. Sci. Technol. 2016, 50, 5467–5473. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
  70. He, G.; Lin, J.; Sifuentes, F.; Liu, X.; Abhyankar, N.; Phadke, A. Rapid Cost Decrease of Renewables and Storage Accelerates the Decarbonization of China’s Power System. Nat. Commun. 2020, 11, 2486. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  71. Li, B.; Ma, Z.; Hidalgo-Gonzalez, P.; Lathem, A.; Fedorova, N.; He, G.; Zhong, H.; Chen, M.; Kammen, D.M. Modeling the Impact of EVs in the Chinese Power System: Pathways for Implementing Emissions Reduction Commitments in the Power and Transportation Sectors. Energy Policy 2021, 149, 111962. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  72. NEPLAN. Available online: http://ieeexplore.ieee.org/document/1687803/ (accessed on 24 July 2021).
  73. Hungerford, Z.; Bruce, A.; MacGill, I. The Value of Flexible Load in Power Systems with High Renewable Energy Penetration. Energy 2019, 188, 115960. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  74. Ren, Y.; Zou, X.; Zhang, X. Bidding Model of Power Plant Company with Incomplete Information. Autom. Electr. Power Syst. 2003, 9, 11–14. [Google Scholar]
  75. Lei, B.; Wang, X.; Gao, Y.; Wang, X. Analysis on bidding strategy of independent power producer in days-ahead market. Autom. Electr. Power Syst. 2002, 26, 8–14. [Google Scholar]
  76. Wang, X.; Wang, X.; Chen, H. Fundamentals of Electricity Market; Xi’an Jiaotong University Press: Xi’an, China, 2003. [Google Scholar]
  77. Conejo, A.J.; Nogales, F.J.; Arroyo, J.M. Price-Taker Bidding Strategy under Price Uncertainty. IEEE Power Eng. Rev. 2002, 22, 57. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  78. Wen, F.; David, A. Optimal Bidding Strategies and Modeling of Imperfect Information among Competitive Generators. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 2002, 16, 15–21. [Google Scholar]
  79. Kang, D.-J.; Kim, B.H.; Hur, D. Supplier Bidding Strategy Based on Non-Cooperative Game Theory Concepts in Single Auction Power Pools. Electr. Power Syst. Res. 2007, 77, 630–636. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  80. Jing, Z.; Yang, Y. Application of the EWA Algorithm in Electricity Market Simulation. Autom. Electr. Power Syst. 2010, 34, 46–50. [Google Scholar]
  81. Zhu, J. Study on Bidding Strategy of Generation Companies with Evolution Game Theory Based on Repast Platform; North China Electric Power University: Beijing, China, 2010. [Google Scholar]
  82. Zhu, J. Research on Bidding Strategy of Generator Based on Agent; Beijing Jiaotong University: Beijing, China, 2010. [Google Scholar]
  83. Ren, X. A Study on Bidding Behavior of Power Producers Based on Multi-Agent Simulation; North China Electric Power University: Beijing, China, 2009. [Google Scholar]
  84. Liang, Z. Simulation of Generation Side Power Market Bidding Trading System Based on MAS; North China Electric Power University: Beijing, China, 2012. [Google Scholar]
  85. Ghavidel, S.; Ghadi, M.J.; Azizivahed, A.; Aghaei, J.; Li, L.; Zhang, J. Risk-Constrained Bidding Strategy for a Joint Operation of Wind Power and CAES Aggregators. IEEE Trans. Sustain. Energy 2020, 11, 457–466. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  86. Iria, J.; Soares, F.; Matos, M. Optimal Supply and Demand Bidding Strategy for an Aggregator of Small Prosumers. Appl. Energy 2018, 213, 658–669. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  87. Dong, Y.; Dong, Z.; Zhao, T.; Ding, Z. A Strategic Day-Ahead Bidding Strategy and Operation for Battery Energy Storage System by Reinforcement Learning. Electr. Power Syst. Res. 2021, 196, 107229. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  88. Cheng, L.; Liu, G.; Huang, H.; Wang, X.; Chen, Y.; Zhang, J.; Meng, A.; Yang, R.; Yu, T. Equilibrium Analysis of General N-Population Multi-Strategy Games for Generation-Side Long-Term Bidding: An Evolutionary Game Perspective. J. Clean. Prod. 2020, 276, 124123. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  89. Wang, Y.; Wang, J.; Sun, W.; Zhao, M. Optimal Day-Ahead Bidding Strategy for Electricity Retailer with Inner-Outer 2-Layer Model System Based on Stochastic Mixed-Integer Optimization. Math. Probl. Eng. 2019, 2019, 1–14. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  90. Yang, M.; Ai, X.; Tang, L.; Guo, S.; Luo, G. Optimal Trading Strategy in Balancing Market for Electricity Retailer Considering Risk Aversion. Power Syst. Technol. 2016, 40, 3300–3309. [Google Scholar]
  91. Mirzaei, M.A.; Hemmati, M.; Zare, K.; Abapour, M.; Mohammadi-Ivatloo, B.; Marzband, M.; Anvari-Moghaddam, A. A Novel Hybrid Two-Stage Framework for Flexible Bidding Strategy of Reconfigurable Micro-Grid in Day-Ahead and Real-Time Markets. Int. J. Electr. Power Energy Syst. 2020, 123, 106293. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  92. Jia, C.; Du, X. Optimization of power purchase strategy of power selling companies under medium and long-term trading mechanism. Electric Power 2019, 52, 140–147. [Google Scholar]
  93. Sun, B.; Wang, F.; Xie, J.; Sun, X. Electricity Retailer Trading Portfolio Optimization Considering Risk Assessment in Chinese Electricity Market. Electr. Power Syst. Res. 2021, 190, 106833. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  94. Mashhour, E.; Moghaddas-Tafreshi, S.M. Bidding Strategy of Virtual Power Plant for Participating in Energy and Spinning Reserve Markets—Part I: Problem Formulation. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 2011, 26, 949–956. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  95. Sadeghi, S.; Jahangir, H.; Vatandoust, B.; Golkar, M.A.; Ahmadian, A.; Elkamel, A. Optimal Bidding Strategy of a Virtual Power Plant in Day-Ahead Energy and Frequency Regulation Markets: A Deep Learning-Based Approach. Int. J. Electr. Power Energy Syst. 2021, 127, 106646. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  96. Nguyen, D.T.; Le, L.B. Optimal Bidding Strategy for Microgrids Considering Renewable Energy and Building Thermal Dynamics. IEEE Trans. Smart Grid 2014, 5, 1608–1620. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  97. Wang, J.; Zhong, H.; Tang, W.; Rajagopal, R.; Xia, Q.; Kang, C.; Wang, Y. Optimal Bidding Strategy for Microgrids in Joint Energy and Ancillary Service Markets Considering Flexible Ramping Products. Appl. Energy 2017, 205, 294–303. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  98. Fang, Y.; Zhao, S. Look-Ahead Bidding Strategy for Concentrating Solar Power Plants with Wind Farms. Energy 2020, 203, 117895. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  99. Iria, J.; Soares, F.; Matos, M. Optimal Bidding Strategy for an Aggregator of Prosumers in Energy and Secondary Reserve Markets. Appl. Energy 2019, 238, 1361–1372. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  100. Wang, Y.; Dvorkin, Y.; Fernandez-Blanco, R.; Xu, B.; Qiu, T.; Kirschen, D.S. Look-Ahead Bidding Strategy for Energy Storage. IEEE Trans. Sustain. Energy 2017, 8, 1106–1117. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  101. Xie, Y.; Guo, W.; Wu, Q.; Wang, K. Robust MPC-Based Bidding Strategy for Wind Storage Systems in Real-Time Energy and Regulation Markets. Int. J. Electr. Power Energy Syst. 2021, 124, 106361. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  102. Zheng, Y.; Yu, H.; Shao, Z.; Jian, L. Day-Ahead Bidding Strategy for Electric Vehicle Aggregator Enabling Multiple Agent Modes in Uncertain Electricity Markets. Appl. Energy 2020, 280, 115977. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  103. Vagropoulos, S.I.; Bakirtzis, A.G. Optimal Bidding Strategy for Electric Vehicle Aggregators in Electricity Markets. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 2013, 28, 4031–4041. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  104. Bjorgan, R.; Liu, C.-C.; Lawarree, J. Financial Risk Management in a Competitive Electricity Market. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 1999, 14, 1285–1291. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  105. Chung, T.S.; Zhang, S.H.; Yu, C.W.; Wong, K.P. Electricity Market Risk Management Using Forward Contracts with Bilateral Options. IEE Proc. Gener. Transm. Distrib. 2003, 150, 588. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  106. Spodniak, P.; Collan, M. Forward Risk Premia in Long-Term Transmission Rights: The Case of Electricity Price Area Differentials (EPAD) in the Nordic Electricity Market. Util. Policy 2018, 50, 194–206. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  107. Zhong, J.; He, Y.; Wang, D.; Sun, Y.; He, T.; Peng, Y.; Yuan, T.; Luo, X. Review on market power regulation and mitigation measures in power market. Proc. CSEE 2018, 9. Available online: https://kns.cnki.net/KCMS/detail/detail.aspx?dbcode=CPFD&dbname=CPFDLAST2019&filename=JDSD201810001025&v= (accessed on 2 July 2021).
  108. Prabhakar Karthikeyan, S.; Jacob Raglend, I.; Kothari, D.P. A Review on Market Power in Deregulated Electricity Market. Int. J. Electr. Power Energy Syst. 2013, 48, 139–147. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  109. Borenstein, S.; Bushnell, J.; Knittel, C.R. Market Power in Electricity Markets: Beyond Concentration Measures. Energy J. 1999, 20, 65–88. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  110. Borenstein, S.; Bushnell, J.; Kahn, E.; Stoft, S. Market Power in California Electricity Markets. Util. Policy 1995, 5, 219–236. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  111. Wolak, F.A. Measuring Unilateral Market Power in Wholesale Electricity Markets: The California Market, 1998–2000. Am. Econ. Rev. 2003, 93, 425–443. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  112. Sweeting, A. Market Power in the England and Wales Wholesale Electricity Market 1995–2000. Econ. J. 2007, 117, 654–685. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  113. Möst, D.; Genoese, M. Market Power in the German Wholesale Electricity Market. J. Energy Mark. 2009, 2, 47. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  114. Shukla, U.K.; Thampy, A. Analysis of Competition and Market Power in the Wholesale Electricity Market in India. Energy Policy 2011, 39, 2699–2710. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  115. Shang, N. Market Power Risk Assessment of Multi-Type Markets Participants Considering Reliability in Electricity Markets; Zhejiang University: Hangzhou, China, 2019. [Google Scholar]
  116. Dong, L.; Wang, S.; Huang, H.; Guo, H. Identification of Market Power Abuse in Spot Market of Chinese Electric Market. Proc. CSEE 2021, 1–11. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  117. Xu, H.; Cheng, Z.; Zhang, H.; Dong, L.; Hua, H. Market Power Abuse Identification of Power Generation Enterprises Based on Improved Support Vector Machine. J. North China Electr. Power Univ. 2020, 47, 86–95. [Google Scholar]
  118. Dong; Wang; Liu; Ainiwaer; Nie Operation Health Assessment of Power Market Based on Improved Matter-Element Extension Cloud Model. Sustainability 2019, 11, 5470. [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  119. Wang, Z.; Zhang, Y.; Huang, K.; Wang, C. Robust Optimal Scheduling Model of Virtual Power Plant Combined Heat and Power Considering Multiple Flexible Loads. Electr. Power Constr. 2021, 42, 1–10. [Google Scholar]
  120. Abban, A.R.; Hasan, M.Z. Solar Energy Penetration and Volatility Transmission to Electricity Markets—An Australian Perspective. Econ. Anal. Policy 2021, 69, 434–449. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  121. Hu, X.; Jaraitė, J.; Kažukauskas, A. The Effects of Wind Power on Electricity Markets: A Case Study of the Swedish Intraday Market. Energy Econ. 2021, 96, 105159. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  122. Spodniak, P.; Ollikka, K.; Honkapuro, S. The Impact of Wind Power and Electricity Demand on the Relevance of Different Short-Term Electricity Markets: The Nordic Case. Appl. Energy 2021, 283, 116063. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  123. Mays, J. Missing Incentives for Flexibility in Wholesale Electricity Markets. Energy Policy 2021, 149, 112010. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  124. The European Parliament; The Council of the European Union. Directive 2009/28/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 23 April 2009 on the Promotion of the Use of Energy from Renewable Sources and Amending and Subsequently Repealing Directives 2001/77/EC and 2003/30/EC; The European Parliament: Brussels, Belgium; The Council of the European Union: Brussels, Belgium, 2009. [Google Scholar]
  125. Banshwar, A.; Sharma, N.K.; Sood, Y.R.; Shrivastava, R. Renewable Energy Sources as a New Participant in Ancillary Service Markets. Energy Strategy Rev. 2017, 18, 106–120. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  126. Godoy-González, D.; Gil, E.; Gutiérrez-Alcaraz, G. Ramping Ancillary Service for Cost-Based Electricity Markets with High Penetration of Variable Renewable Energy. Energy Econ. 2020, 85, 10455. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  127. Goudarzi, H.; Rayati, M.; Sheikhi, A.; Ranjbar, A.M. A Clearing Mechanism for Joint Energy and Ancillary Services in Non-Convex Markets Considering High Penetration of Renewable Energy Sources. Int. J. Electr. Power Energy Syst. 2021, 129, 106817. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  128. Zarnikau, J.; Tsai, C.H.; Woo, C.K. Determinants of the Wholesale Prices of Energy and Ancillary Services in the U.S. Midcontinent Electricity Market. Energy 2020, 195, 117051. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  129. Banshwar, A.; Sharma, N.K.; Sood, Y.R.; Shrivastava, R. Market Based Procurement of Energy and Ancillary Services from Renewable Energy Sources in Deregulated Environment. Renew. Energy 2017, 101, 1390–1400. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  130. Glass, E.; Glass, V. Enabling Supercapacitors to Compete for Ancillary Services: An Important Step towards 100 % Renewable Energy. Electr. J. 2020, 33, 106763. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  131. Hu, Q.; Zhu, Z.; Bu, S.; Wing Chan, K.; Li, F. A Multi-Market Nanogrid P2P Energy and Ancillary Service Trading Paradigm: Mechanisms and Implementations. Appl. Energy 2021, 293, 116938. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  132. Stürmer, B.; Theuretzbacher, F.; Saracevic, E. Opportunities for the Integration of Existing Biogas Plants into the Austrian Electricity Market. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2021, 138, 110548. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  133. Arango-Aramburo, S.; Bernal-García, S.; Larsen, E.R. Renewable Energy Sources and the Cycles in Deregulated Electricity Markets. Energy 2021, 223, 120058. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  134. Hasankhani, A.; Hakimi, S.M. Stochastic Energy Management of Smart Microgrid with Intermittent Renewable Energy Resources in Electricity Market. Energy 2021, 219, 119668. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  135. Ambec, S.; Crampes, C. Real-Time Electricity Pricing to Balance Green Energy Intermittency. Energy Econ. 2021, 94, 105074. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  136. Lianhe Ratings. Research Report and Prospect of Thermal Power Industry in 2020. Available online: https://pdf.dfcfw.com/pdf/H3_AP202101131450227605_1.pdf?1610555525000.pdf (accessed on 7 June 2021).
  137. National Development and Reform Commission (NDRC). Circular of the National Development and Reform Commission and the National Energy Administration on Carrying out the Transmission and Upgrading of Coal-Fired Power Units Nationwide. Available online: www.gov.cn/zhengce/zhengceku/2021-11/03/content_5648562.htm (accessed on 7 November 2021).
  138. Jian, Q.; Liu, X.; Yang, J.; Liu, C.; Wang, X.; Liu, D. Optimal Allocation of Power System Flexible Resources Considering Demand Response. Mod. Electr. Power 2021, 38, 286–296. [Google Scholar]
  139. Kazempour, J.; Hobbs, B.F. Value of Flexible Resources, Virtual Bidding, and Self-Scheduling in Two-Settlement Electricity Markets with Wind Generation—Part I: Principles and Competitive Model. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 2018, 33, 749–775. [Google Scholar]
  140. Huang, B.; Hu, J.; Jiang, L.; Li, Q.; Feng, K.; Yuan, B. Application Value Assessment of Grid Side Energy Storage Under Typical Scenarios in China. Electr. Power 2021, 54, 158–165. [Google Scholar]
  141. Shi, J.; Guo, Y.; Sun, H.; Wu, C. Review of Research and Practice on Reserve Market. Proc. CSEE 2021, 41, 123–134+403. [Google Scholar]
  142. Willis, L.; Finney, J.; Ramon, G. Computing the Cost of Unbundled Services [Power Transmission]. IEEE Comput. Appl. Power 1996, 9, 16–21. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  143. Sun, S.; Chi, D.; Yu, B.; Zhou, M. Building a new power market system and electricity price mechanism. Macroecon. Manag. 2021, 3, 71–77. [Google Scholar]
  144. Leng, Y.; Gu, W. Operating Mechanism of Australian Electric Financial Derivatives Market and Its Implications for Electricity Market Construction in China. Electr. Power 2021, 54, 36–43. [Google Scholar]
  145. van Koten, S. The Forward Premium in Electricity Markets: An Experimental Study. Energy Econ. 2021, 94, 105059. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  146. Fang, X.; Hu, Q.; Bo, R.; Li, F. Redesigning Capacity Market to Include Flexibility via Ramp Constraints in High-Renewable Penetrated System. Int. J. Electr. Power Energy Syst. 2021, 128, 106677. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  147. Liu, M.; Yang, L.; Gan, D. A survey on agent based electricity market simulation. Power Syst. Technol. 2005, 29, 76–80. [Google Scholar]
  148. Bao, T.; Wang, G.; Dai, Y. Future oriented experimental economics: Literature review and Prospect. Manag. World 2020, 36, 218–237. [Google Scholar]
  149. Duffy, J. Macroeconomics: A Survey of Laboratory Research. Handb. Exp. Econ. 2016, 2, 1–90. [Google Scholar]
  150. Binmore, K.; Klemperer, P. The Biggest Auction Ever: The Sale of the British 3G Telecom Licences. Econ. J. 2002, 112, C74–C96. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  151. Arifovic, J.; Duffy, J.M.; Jiang, J.H. Adoption of a New Payment Method: Theory and Experimental Evidence; Bank of Canada Staff Working Paper; Bank of Canada: Ottawa, ON, Canada, 2017. [Google Scholar]
  152. Blinder, A.S.; Morgan, J. Do Monetary Policy Committees Need Leaders? A Report on an Experiment. Am. Econ. Rev. 2008, 98, 224–229. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  153. Hommes, C.; Massaro, D.; Weber, M. Monetary Policy under Behavioral Expectations: Theory and Experiment. Eur. Econ. Rev. 2019, 118, 193–212. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  154. Davis, D.D.; Holt, C.A. Experimental Economics; Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ, USA, 1993. [Google Scholar]
  155. List, J.A.; Lucking-Reiley, D. Demand Reduction in Multiunit Auctions: Evidence from a Sportscard Field Experiment. Am. Econ. Rev. 2000, 90, 961–972. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  156. Fan, R.; Ye, Q.; Du, J. Frontier Development of Agent—Based Computational Economics: A Survey. Econ. Rev. 2013, 2, 145–150. [Google Scholar]
  157. Mi, J.; Lin, R. How equity preference affects open innovation: A study based on Computational Economics. Chin. J. Manag. Sci. 2015, 23, 157–166. [Google Scholar]
  158. Arthur, W.B.; Holland, J.H.; Lebaron, B.; Palmer, R.; Taylor, P. Asset Pricing under Endogenous Expectation in an Artificial Stock Market; Working Papers; Santa Fe Institute: Santa Fe, NM, USA, 1996. [Google Scholar]
  159. Barrows, C.; Preston, E.; Staid, A.; Stephen, G.; Watson, J.-P.; Bloom, A.; Ehlen, A.; Ikaheimo, J.; Jorgenson, J.; Krishnamurthy, D.; et al. The IEEE Reliability Test System: A Proposed 2019 Update. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 2020, 35, 119–127. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  160. Gacitua, L.; Gallegos, P.; Henriquez-Auba, R.; Lorca, Á.; Negrete-Pincetic, M.; Olivares, D.; Valenzuela, A.; Wenzel, G. A Comprehensive Review on Expansion Planning: Models and Tools for Energy Policy Analysis. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2018, 98, 346–360. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  161. Xu, Y.; Myhrvold, N.; Sivam, D.; Mueller, K.; Olsen, D.J.; Xia, B.; Livengood, D.; Hunt, V.; d’Orfeuil, B.R.; Muldrew, D.; et al. U.S. Test System with High Spatial and Temporal Resolution for Renewable Integration Studies. In Proceedings of the 2020 IEEE Power & Energy Society General Meeting (PESGM), Montreal, QC, Canada, 2–6 August 2020; pp. 1–5. [Google Scholar]
  162. Denholm, P.; Hand, M. Grid Flexibility and Storage Required to Achieve Very High Penetration of Variable Renewable Electricity. Energy Policy 2011, 39, 1817–1830. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  163. Li, Z.; Chen, S.; Dong, W.; Liu, P.; Du, E.; Ma, L.; He, J. Low Carbon Transition Pathway of Power Sector Under Carbon Emission Constraints. Proc. CSEE 2021, 41, 3987–4001. [Google Scholar]
  164. Wang, B.; Xia, Y.; Xia, Q.; Zhang, H.; Han, H. Model and Methods of Generation and transmission scheduling of Inter-regional Power Grid via HVDC Tie-line. Autom. Electr. Power Syst. 2016, 40, 8–13+26. [Google Scholar]
  165. Li, X.; Zhang, G.; Guo, Z. N-1 principle steady state security restriction on power flow of transmission tie line group. Electr. Power Autom. Equip. 2004, 11, 10–13+17. [Google Scholar]
  166. Khoshjahan, M.; Moeini-Aghtaie, M.; Fotuhi-Firuzabad, M.; Dehghanian, P.; Mazaheri, H. Advanced Bidding Strategy for Participation of Energy Storage Systems in Joint Energy and Flexible Ramping Product Market. IET Gener. Transm. Distrib. 2020, 14, 5202–5210. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  167. Castillo-Ramírez, A.; Mejía-Giraldo, D. Measuring Financial Impacts of the Renewable Energy Based Fiscal Policy in Colombia under Electricity Price Uncertainty. Sustainability 2021, 13, 2010. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  168. Guo, W.; Liu, P.; Shu, X. Optimal Dispatching of Electric-Thermal Interconnected Virtual Power Plant Considering Market Trading Mechanism. J. Clean. Prod. 2021, 279, 123446. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  169. Lasemi, M.A.; Arabkoohsar, A. Optimal Operating Strategy of High-Temperature Heat and Power Storage System Coupled with a Wind Farm in Energy Market. Energy 2020, 210, 118545. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  170. Rentier, G.; Lelieveldt, H.; Kramer, G.J. Varieties of Coal-Fired Power Phase-out across Europe. Energy Policy 2019, 132, 620–632. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  171. Trencher, G.; Healy, N.; Hasegawa, K.; Asuka, J. Discursive Resistance to Phasing out Coal-Fired Electricity: Narratives in Japan’s Coal Regime. Energy Policy 2019, 132, 782–796. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  172. Webb, J.; de Silva, H.N.; Wilson, C. The Future of Coal and Renewable Power Generation in Australia: A Review of Market Trends. Econ. Anal. Policy 2020, 68, 363–378. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  173. Muñoz, F.D.; Suazo-Martínez, C.; Pereira, E.; Moreno, R. Electricity Market Design for Low-Carbon and Flexible Systems: Room for Improvement in Chile. Energy Policy 2021, 148, 111997. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  174. Das, P.; Mathuria, P.; Bhakar, R.; Mathur, J.; Kanudia, A.; Singh, A. Flexibility Requirement for Large-Scale Renewable Energy Integration in Indian Power System: Technology, Policy and Modeling Options. Energy Strategy Rev. 2020, 29, 100482. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Review Design for the Study of Power Markets as Researchers Adapt to the NPS in China.
Figure 1. Review Design for the Study of Power Markets as Researchers Adapt to the NPS in China.
Sustainability 13 13409 g001
Figure 2. SLR search criteria.
Figure 2. SLR search criteria.
Sustainability 13 13409 g002
Figure 3. Search process.
Figure 3. Search process.
Sustainability 13 13409 g003
Figure 4. General Issues in the Worldwide Study of Power Markets.
Figure 4. General Issues in the Worldwide Study of Power Markets.
Sustainability 13 13409 g004
Figure 5. Basic paradigm for the study of power markets: (a) research dimensions of power market; (b) general process of power transactions.
Figure 5. Basic paradigm for the study of power markets: (a) research dimensions of power market; (b) general process of power transactions.
Sustainability 13 13409 g005
Table 1. The Study of Power Markets: General Issues and References.
Table 1. The Study of Power Markets: General Issues and References.
Research on the Operation of the Power MarketReferences
Price mechanism designRegional marginal pricing[29]
Locational marginal pricing[30]
Capacity pricing mechanism[31,32,33,34]
Ancillary service pricing mechanism[35]
Combined clearing of power energy and ancillary service[36]
Distributed trading mechanism[37]
Market structure design[38]
Market powerEvaluating metrics[19,39,40,41,42,43,44,45,46]
Evaluating methods[47,48,49,50]
Demand response[51,52,53,54]
Market efficiency assessment[19]
Investment in power systems[55,56]
Environmental policy[57,58,59]
Table 2. Typical Literature on Market Players’ Bidding Strategies.
Table 2. Typical Literature on Market Players’ Bidding Strategies.
Market PlayersStrategy TargetReferences
Traditional power producersMedium- and long-term market[88]
Day-ahead market [89]
Real-time market [90]
Day-ahead market and real-time market combined[91]
Electricity retailerDay-ahead market [92,93]
Virtual power plantDay-ahead market and ancillary services[94,95]
MicrogridsDay-ahead market[96]
Day-ahead market and real-time market combined[91]
Electric energy market and ancillary services [97,98]
ProsumerDay-ahead market [86]
Day-ahead market and ancillary services[99]
Energy storageDay-ahead market [100]
Real-time market and ancillary services[101]
Electric vehiclesDay-ahead market [102]
Day-ahead market and ancillary services[103]
Table 3. Power System Simulation Parameters.
Table 3. Power System Simulation Parameters.
ParametersDescription
Structure of the power supplyType, location, installed capacity and other properties.
Forecast of electricity output (accuracy) generated from renewable energy of the systemThe reliability of the system can be verified by setting a proper coefficient of power generation using renewable energy units. Based on weather forecast data, the dispatch center estimates potential output from renewable resources and provides the power generation coefficient of new energy to market participants for reference.
Standby rateThe standby rate is the ratio of the gap between the system’s total available capacity and the peak load. It is an important index to measure the reliability of the power system [164].
Number of nodesThe complexity of the power system can also be reflected by the number of nodes.
The closer the location and number of nodes is set to the actual grid topology, the more effective the power system simulation will be.
Power generation schedule of unitsFactors influencing the power generation schedule of the units include system operation factors and non-system operation factors.
Power flowExcited by the potential of the power supply, electric current flows from the power supply to every load in the power system through distribution components, and thus power is distributed throughout the whole grid.
The constraint of power flow in N-1 transmission sectionWhen grid topology operates normally according to the given constraint, if disconnecting any line in the section, power flow in the rest of the lines is not overloaded. The constraint of power flow in a section is the maximum allowable power current when the section is running normally [165]. If the power flow surpasses the limitation, a nodal price would be formed.
Constraint of active power balanceActive power balance means that active power on the generation side and the consumption side is equal. The frequency of the power system is directly related to the balance of active power, and the auxiliary services of frequency regulation can be referenced.
Constraint of reactive power balance Reactive power balance is the condition that reactive power on the generation side and the consumption side is equal. When the reactive power is insufficient, the reactive compensation is required.
Plans for maintenance of power generation, transmission and transformation equipment Plans for maintenance covers two types of equipment, including power generation equipment, as well as power transmission and transformation equipment. The maintenance plans for power distribution and transformation equipment affect the structure of power transmission for a short time.
System load forecasting (accuracy)The dispatch center predicts the total load of the power system for several days based on data obtained about the system. The accuracy of system load forecasting directly affects the analysis of market supply and the demand of market participants, and then affects market quotation behavior.
Table 4. Power Market Rules and Environment Simulation Parameters.
Table 4. Power Market Rules and Environment Simulation Parameters.
ParametersDescription
Trading methodsMajor trading methods include bilateral consultations, centralized bidding and listing transactions. The spot trading market is divided into the day-ahead market, the intra-day marker and the real-time market. A variety of trading methods can be combined according to the transaction cycle, thus new symbols can be built in to increase the diversity of market symbols.
Trading transactionsDepending on different types of markets, typical symbols include medium- and long-term (yearly, monthly, weekly) transactions, contract power transfer, power generation rights trading, spot trading and ancillary services trading. New trading instruments for renewable energy and flexible resources will be added in order to meet the needs of further construction in the power market.
Limitations on the declared priceBased on the relationship between demand and supply, in order to avoid market manipulation and vicious competition, minimum and maximum declared prices must be set for the direct trading of electricity in different transaction modes. Different ranges for price limitations can be set through power market simulation to verify the market’s capacity.
Rules for clearance Major rules of clearance include high–low matching and unified clearance. High–low matching is the priority match between the highest spread on the demand side and the lowest spread on the supply side. Whether the spread pair matches can be judged by the following formula:
L nSm ≥ 0, match
L nSm < 0, not match
where Ln is the spread pair on the demand side, while Sm represents the spread pair on the supply side.
Unified clearance refers to the selection of the last pair of spread pairs that match successfully according to the principles of high–low matching. The arithmetic average of the selected pair will be designated as the closing spread of all participants. When studying the development degree and diversification of the power market, different rules of clearance and trading methods can be combined to conduct diversified trading. Thus, the market affordability can be tested.
Settlement mechanismsSettlement is reached either at the marginal electricity price or at the actual declared price by power generations units:
min   F m ,   F m = i = 1 I C o m · P i
where Fm represents the cost of power purchases paid by the grid, Pi represents the power generation volume bid by the power producer (or electricity generation unit) i, and i refers to power producer. I is the total number of power producers, and Com represents the marginal electricity price of the system.
Changing rate of the balancing funds accountAs the price fluctuations of electricity bought from the power market by the grid cannot be transmitted to power retail prices in time, a balancing funds account is built to link power sales prices to power purchase prices:
V i = F i F i 1 F i 1
where Vi is the changing rate of the funds in the balancing account, Fi represents the amount of balancing funds this year, while Fi−1 refers to the amount of balancing funds last year.
Market turnover rate Market turnover rate is the ratio representing the number of market participants declaring during the statistical period (which can also be a transaction for one time) divided by the number of market subjects that finally complete the transaction. The turnover rate is used to analyze whether market competition is insufficient or judge collusion by market participants:
V i = F i G i
where V i is the turnover rate, F i refers to the number of market subjects which finally complete the transaction, and Gi is number of market participants declaring during the statistical period.
HHIThe Herfindahl–Hirschman index (HHI) is a composite index that measures industrial concentration. It reflects the changes in market share, i.e., the dispersion of the size of manufacturers in the market:
I H H I = i = 1 N ( 100 S i ) 2
where Si is the market share occupied by market supplier i per trade sequence during the evaluation cycle, while N represents the number of suppliers in the market during the evaluation cycle.
Renewable energy subsidiesAccording to the effectiveness of the market mechanism and the development of new energy, the amount of renewable energy subsidy can be changed to verify the risks brought about by the marketization of renewable energy resources.
Deviation parameters The parameters reflecting the deviation of power generation (more or less) on the generation side include the exemption range and the appraisal price. The parameters measuring the deviation of electricity consumption (more or less) also include the exemption range and the appraisal price.
Table 5. Market Participants Characteristic Parameters.
Table 5. Market Participants Characteristic Parameters.
ParametersDescription
Power producer, asset type and status constraintsThis parameter covers the type of units and operating parameters of the power producer. When the user of the simulation system is the power producer, the power generation enterprise can develop its own strategies by simulating the trading strategy of its competitors based on market conditions.
Cost compositionCost is an important basis for making transaction decisions. Power generation costs primarily cover start-up costs, empty operating costs, fuel costs, environmental costs, and other economic costs. Under China’s dual carbon reduction goal, environmental costs have become an important constraint on the development of thermal power enterprises. Power sales companies need to consider retail contract prices, wholesale prices and other related parameters.
Marginal revenue of the power generation unitThis parameter refers to the income earned through increasing or decreasing the power generation of the unit, and its relationship with the power generation and market price is:
M R i = d ( P G i ) d G i P
where M R i is the marginal revenue of the power generation unit i, Gi refers to the output of unit i, and P is the electricity price in the power market.
Forecasts for market prices and power generationA power plant forecasts its own power generation output based on its installed capacity. Combining this with market price forecasts, the power plant declares reasonable prices and a power generation plan. At the same time, the market price and power generation coefficient can also be set to verify the anti-jamming of the quoting strategy.
Power generation plansPower generation enterprises make production plans based on existing contracts. Power market simulation provides users with a chance to choose the optimal solution from different generation plans so as to avoid market shocks.
Intelligent agent simulationThrough simulating the trading behaviors of competitors, intelligent agent simulation technology helps power producers to formulate their own trading strategies. By simulating the transactions of multiple participants, it can also help verify market results. Intelligent agents can be divided into rational and irrational, or radical and conservative. Commonly used parameters include the number of intelligent agents, learning mechanisms and feedback mechanisms.
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Dong, J.; Liu, D.; Dou, X.; Li, B.; Lv, S.; Jiang, Y.; Ma, T. Key Issues and Technical Applications in the Study of Power Markets as the System Adapts to the New Power System in China. Sustainability 2021, 13, 13409. https://doi.org/10.3390/su132313409

AMA Style

Dong J, Liu D, Dou X, Li B, Lv S, Jiang Y, Ma T. Key Issues and Technical Applications in the Study of Power Markets as the System Adapts to the New Power System in China. Sustainability. 2021; 13(23):13409. https://doi.org/10.3390/su132313409

Chicago/Turabian Style

Dong, Jun, Dongran Liu, Xihao Dou, Bo Li, Shiyao Lv, Yuzheng Jiang, and Tongtao Ma. 2021. "Key Issues and Technical Applications in the Study of Power Markets as the System Adapts to the New Power System in China" Sustainability 13, no. 23: 13409. https://doi.org/10.3390/su132313409

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop